Preliminary Version Do Not Cite

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Preliminary Version Do Not Cite PRELIMINARY VERSION: DO NOT CITE The AAAI Digital Library will contain the published version some time after the conference Computing Quantal Stackelberg Equilibrium in Extensive-Form Games Jakub Cernˇ y´1, Viliam Lisy´2, Branislav Bosanskˇ y´2, Bo An1 1 Nanyang Technological University, Singapore 2 AI Center, FEE, Czech Technical University in Prague, Czech Republic [email protected], viliam.lisy, branislav.bosansky @fel.cvut.cz, [email protected] { } Abstract players choose better actions more often than worse actions instead of playing only the best action (McKelvey and Pal- Deployments of game-theoretic solution concepts in the real frey 1995). When facing a human opponent we aim to find world have highlighted the necessity to consider human op- a strategy optimal against QR, termed Quantal Stackelberg ponents’ boundedly rational behavior. If subrationality is not addressed, the system can face significant losses in terms Equilibrium (QSE). Relying on SE is not advisable in such of expected utility. While there exist algorithms for com- situations as the committing player can suffer huge losses puting optimal strategies to commit to when facing subra- when deploying rational strategies against boundedly ratio- tional decision-makers in one-shot interactions, these algo- nal counterparts (Yang et al. 2011). rithms cannot be generalized for solving sequential scenarios QSE was studied extensively in Stackelberg Security because of the inherent curse of strategy-space dimensional- Games (SSGs) (Sinha et al. 2018), and the developed al- ity in sequential games and because humans act subrationally gorithms were used in many real-world applications. SSG in each decision point separately. We study optimal strate- is a widely applicable game model, but it requires formulat- gies to commit to against subrational opponents in sequential games for the first time and make the following key contri- ing the problem in terms of allocating limited resources to butions: (1) we prove the problem is NP-hard in general; (2) a set of targets. To solve real-world problems beyond SSGs, to enable further analysis, we introduce a non-fractional re- QSE was recently introduced also in a more general model formulation of the direct non-concave representation of the of normal-form games (NFGs) (Cernˇ y´ et al. 2020). How- equilibrium; (3) we identify conditions under which the prob- ever, even NFGs model only one-shot interactions. To the lem can be approximated in polynomial time in the size of the best of our knowledge, QSE was never properly analyzed representation; (4) we show how an MILP can approximate for extensive-form (i.e., sequential) games (EFGs), despite the reformulation with a guaranteed bounded error, and (5) the fact that many real-world domains are sequential. we experimentally demonstrate that our algorithm provides higher quality results several orders of magnitude faster than In this paper, we develop methods for finding QSE in a baseline method for general non-linear optimization. EFGs. There are two main challenges that prevent us from using techniques from SSGs or NFGs directly. First, while there is only one decision point for the boundedly ratio- Introduction nal player in NFGs, any non-trivial EFG contains multiple In recent years, game theory has achieved many ground- causally linked decision points where the same player acts. breaking advances both in large games (e.g., super-human The psychological studies show that humans prefer short- AI in poker (Moravcˇ´ık et al. 2017; Brown and Sandholm term, delayed heuristic decisions (Gigerenzer and Gold- 2018)), and practical applications (physical security (Sinha stein 1996) rather than long-term, premeditated decisions. et al. 2018), wildlife protection (Fang et al. 2017), AI for so- This behavior arises especially in in conflicts (Gray 1999) cial good (Yadav et al. 2016)). In deployed two-player real- or when facing information overload caused by large deci- world solutions, the aim is often to compute an optimal strat- sion space (Malhotra 1982). Therefore, a natural assumption egy to commit to while assuming that the other player plays is that a subrational player acts according to a QR model the best response to this commitment – i.e., to find a Stack- in each decision point separately. This behavior cannot be elberg Equilibrium (SE). While the traditional theory (e.g., modeled by an equivalent NFG. Second, contrary to NFGs, the SE) assumes that all players behave entirely rationally, the number of rational player’s pure strategies in EFGs is the real world’s deployments proved that taking into account exponential in the game size. Therefore, even if the QSE the bounded rationality of the human players is necessary to concepts would coincide in NFGs and EFGs, applying the provide higher quality solutions (An et al. 2013; Fang et al. algorithms for NFGs directly would soon ran into scalabil- 2017). One of the most commonly used models of bounded ity problems.We begin our analysis by showing that find- rationality is Quantal Response (QR), which assumes that ing QSE is NP-hard, and the straightforward formulation of QSE in EFGs is a non-concave fractional problem that Copyright c 2021, Association for the Advancement of Artificial is difficult to optimize. Therefore, we derive an equivalent Intelligence (www.aaai.org). All rights reserved. Dinkelbach-type formulation of QSE that does not contain any fraction, and represents the rational player’s strategy of the probabilities of chance actions in history h. The set of linearly in the size of the game. We use the Dinkelbach chance histories is denoted as c. formulation to identify sufficient condition for solving the Imperfect observation of playerH i is modeled via infor- problem in polynomial time. If the conditions are satisfied, mation sets i that form a partition over h i. Player i the optimal solution can be found by gradient ascent. For cannot distinguishI between histories in any information2H set other cases, we formulate a mixed-integer linear program I i. We overload the notation and use (Ii) to denote (MILP) approximating the QSE through QR model’s linear possible2I actions available in each history inA an information relaxation. We provide theoretical guarantees on the solu- set Ii. Each action a uniquely identifies the information set tion quality, depending on the number of segments used to where it is available, referred as (a). We assume perfect re- linearize the QR function and the arising bilinear terms. call, which means that players rememberI the history of their In the experiments, we compare the direct formulation own actions and all information gained during the course of solved by non-linear optimization to our MILP reformula- the game. As a consequence, all histories in any information tion. We show that in 3.5 hours, our algorithm computes set Ii have the same history of actions for player i. solutions that the baseline cannot reach within three days. Pure strategies ⇧i assign one action for each I i and 2I Moreover, the quality of solutions of the our algorithm out- we assume the actions of a strategy ⇡ ⇧i can be enu- matches the baseline’s solutions even for the instances com- merated as a ⇡. We denote the set2 of leafs reachable 2 putable by the baseline. by a strategy ⇡ as (⇡).Abehavioral strategy βi Bi is one probability distributionZ over actions (I) for2 each Related Solution Concepts. Several other solution con- I . For any pair of strategies β B =(BA,B ) we use cepts study bounded rationality in EFGs. Perhaps the most i l f u 2(βI)=u (β ,β ) for the expected2 outcome of the game well-known one is the model of Quantal Response Equilib- i i i i for player i when− players follow strategies β. rium (QRE) (McKelvey and Palfrey 1998). In QRE, all play- Strategies in EFGs with perfect recall can be also com- ers act boundedly rationally, and no player has the ability pactly represented by using the sequence form (Koller, to commit to a strategy. This is in contrast to QSE, where Megiddo, and von Stengel 1996). A sequence σ ⌃ is the entirely-rational leader aims to exploit the boundedly i i an ordered list of actions taken by a single player i2in his- rational opponent. A similar approach for EFGs was taken tory h. stands for the empty sequence (i.e., a sequence in (Basak et al. 2018), where only one of the players was with no; actions). A sequence σ ⌃ can be extended by considered rational. However, their goal was to evaluate the i i a valid action a taken by player i,2 written as σ a = σ .We performance against human participants, and the approach i i0 say that σ is a prefix of σ (σ σ ) if σ is obtained by lacked theoretical foundations. The computed strategies did i i0 i i0 i0 finite number (possibly zero) ofv extensions of σ . We use not correspond to a well-defined solution concept and were i seq(h) to denote the sequence of actions of all players lead- empirically suboptimal. We define and study this concept in ing to h. By using a subscript seq we refer to the subse- our concurrent paper (Milec et al. 2020). Besides rationality, i quence of action of player i. Because of perfect recall we in QSE, the leader also benefits from the power of commit- write seq (I)=seq (h) for I ,h I. We use the func- ment. It is well known that the ability to commit increases i i i tion inf (σ ) to denote the information2I 2 set in which the last the payoffs achievable by the leader (Von Stengel and Za- i i0 action of the sequence σ is taken. For an empty sequence, mir 2010) and it trivially holds also against bounded rational i0 function inf ( ) returns the information set of the root.
Recommended publications
  • Adversarial Search (Game)
    Adversarial Search CE417: Introduction to Artificial Intelligence Sharif University of Technology Spring 2019 Soleymani “Artificial Intelligence: A Modern Approach”, 3rd Edition, Chapter 5 Most slides have been adopted from Klein and Abdeel, CS188, UC Berkeley. Outline } Game as a search problem } Minimax algorithm } �-� Pruning: ignoring a portion of the search tree } Time limit problem } Cut off & Evaluation function 2 Games as search problems } Games } Adversarial search problems (goals are in conflict) } Competitive multi-agent environments } Games in AI are a specialized kind of games (in the game theory) 3 Adversarial Games 4 Types of Games } Many different kinds of games! } Axes: } Deterministic or stochastic? } One, two, or more players? } Zero sum? } Perfect information (can you see the state)? } Want algorithms for calculating a strategy (policy) which recommends a move from each state 5 Zero-Sum Games } Zero-Sum Games } General Games } Agents have opposite utilities } Agents have independent utilities (values on outcomes) (values on outcomes) } Lets us think of a single value that one } Cooperation, indifference, competition, maximizes and the other minimizes and more are all possible } Adversarial, pure competition } More later on non-zero-sum games 6 Primary assumptions } We start with these games: } Two -player } Tu r n taking } agents act alternately } Zero-sum } agents’ goals are in conflict: sum of utility values at the end of the game is zero or constant } Perfect information } fully observable Examples: Tic-tac-toe,
    [Show full text]
  • Best-First Minimax Search Richard E
    Artificial Intelligence ELSEVIER Artificial Intelligence 84 ( 1996) 299-337 Best-first minimax search Richard E. Korf *, David Maxwell Chickering Computer Science Department, University of California, Los Angeles, CA 90024, USA Received September 1994; revised May 1995 Abstract We describe a very simple selective search algorithm for two-player games, called best-first minimax. It always expands next the node at the end of the expected line of play, which determines the minimax value of the root. It uses the same information as alpha-beta minimax, and takes roughly the same time per node generation. We present an implementation of the algorithm that reduces its space complexity from exponential to linear in the search depth, but at significant time cost. Our actual implementation saves the subtree generated for one move that is still relevant after the player and opponent move, pruning subtrees below moves not chosen by either player. We also show how to efficiently generate a class of incremental random game trees. On uniform random game trees, best-first minimax outperforms alpha-beta, when both algorithms are given the same amount of computation. On random trees with random branching factors, best-first outperforms alpha-beta for shallow depths, but eventually loses at greater depths. We obtain similar results in the game of Othello. Finally, we present a hybrid best-first extension algorithm that combines alpha-beta with best-first minimax, and performs significantly better than alpha-beta in both domains, even at greater depths. In Othello, it beats alpha-beta in two out of three games. 1. Introduction and overview The best chess machines, such as Deep-Blue [lo], are competitive with the best humans, but generate billions of positions per move.
    [Show full text]
  • Exploding Offers with Experimental Consumer Goods∗
    Exploding Offers with Experimental Consumer Goods∗ Alexander L. Brown Ajalavat Viriyavipart Department of Economics Department of Economics Texas A&M University Texas A&M University Xiaoyuan Wang Department of Economics Texas A&M University August 29, 2014 Abstract Recent theoretical research indicates that search deterrence strategies are generally opti- mal for sellers in consumer goods markets. Yet search deterrence is not always employed in such markets. To understand this incongruity, we develop an experimental market where profit-maximizing strategy dictates sellers should exercise one form of search deterrence, ex- ploding offers. We find that buyers over-reject exploding offers relative to optimal. Sellers underutilize exploding offers relative to optimal play, even conditional on buyer over-rejection. This tendency dissipates when sellers make offers to computerized buyers, suggesting their persistent behavior with human buyers may be due to a preference rather than a miscalculation. Keywords: exploding offer, search deterrence, experimental economics, quantal response equi- librium JEL: C91 D21 L10 M31 ∗We thank the Texas A&M Humanities and Social Science Enhancement of Research Capacity Program for providing generous financial support for our research. We have benefited from comments by Gary Charness, Catherine Eckel, Silvana Krasteva and seminar participants of the 2013 North American Economic Science Association and Southern Economic Association Meetings. Daniel Stephenson and J. Forrest Williams provided invaluable help in conducting the experimental sessions. 1 Introduction One of the first applications of microeconomic theory is to the consumer goods market: basic supply and demand models can often explain transactions in centralized markets quite well. When markets are decentralized, often additional modeling is required to explain the interactions of consumers and producers.
    [Show full text]
  • Adversarial Search (Game Playing)
    Artificial Intelligence Adversarial Search (Game Playing) Chapter 5 Adapted from materials by Tim Finin, Marie desJardins, and Charles R. Dyer Outline • Game playing – State of the art and resources – Framework • Game trees – Minimax – Alpha-beta pruning – Adding randomness State of the art • How good are computer game players? – Chess: • Deep Blue beat Gary Kasparov in 1997 • Garry Kasparav vs. Deep Junior (Feb 2003): tie! • Kasparov vs. X3D Fritz (November 2003): tie! – Checkers: Chinook (an AI program with a very large endgame database) is the world champion. Checkers has been solved exactly – it’s a draw! – Go: Computer players are decent, at best – Bridge: “Expert” computer players exist (but no world champions yet!) • Good place to learn more: http://www.cs.ualberta.ca/~games/ Chinook • Chinook is the World Man-Machine Checkers Champion, developed by researchers at the University of Alberta. • It earned this title by competing in human tournaments, winning the right to play for the (human) world championship, and eventually defeating the best players in the world. • Visit http://www.cs.ualberta.ca/~chinook/ to play a version of Chinook over the Internet. • The developers have fully analyzed the game of checkers and have the complete game tree for it. – Perfect play on both sides results in a tie. • “One Jump Ahead: Challenging Human Supremacy in Checkers” Jonathan Schaeffer, University of Alberta (496 pages, Springer. $34.95, 1998). Ratings of human and computer chess champions Typical case • 2-person game • Players alternate moves • Zero-sum: one player’s loss is the other’s gain • Perfect information: both players have access to complete information about the state of the game.
    [Show full text]
  • Learning Near-Optimal Search in a Minimal Explore/Exploit Task
    Explore/exploit tradeoff strategies with accumulating resources 1 Explore/exploit tradeoff strategies in a resource accumulation search task [revised/resubmitted to Cognitive Science] Ke Sang1, Peter M. Todd1, Robert L. Goldstone1, and Thomas T. Hills2 1 Cognitive Science Program and Department of Psychological and Brain Sciences, Indiana University Bloomington 2 Department of Psychology, University of Warwick REVISION 7/5/2018 Contact information: Peter M. Todd Indiana University, Cognitive Science Program 1101 E. 10th Street, Bloomington, IN 47405 USA phone: +1 812 855-3914 email: [email protected] Explore/exploit tradeoff strategies with accumulating resources 2 Abstract How, and how well, do people switch between exploration and exploitation to search for and accumulate resources? We study the decision processes underlying such exploration/exploitation tradeoffs by using a novel card selection task. With experience, participants learn to switch appropriately between exploration and exploitation and approach optimal performance. We model participants’ behavior on this task with random, threshold, and sampling strategies, and find that a linear decreasing threshold rule best fits participants’ results. Further evidence that participants use decreasing threshold-based strategies comes from reaction time differences between exploration and exploitation; however, participants themselves report non-decreasing thresholds. Decreasing threshold strategies that “front-load” exploration and switch quickly to exploitation are particularly effective
    [Show full text]
  • CS 561: Artificial Intelligence
    CS 561: Artificial Intelligence Instructor: Sofus A. Macskassy, [email protected] TAs: Nadeesha Ranashinghe ([email protected]) William Yeoh ([email protected]) Harris Chiu ([email protected]) Lectures: MW 5:00-6:20pm, OHE 122 / DEN Office hours: By appointment Class page: http://www-rcf.usc.edu/~macskass/CS561-Spring2010/ This class will use http://www.uscden.net/ and class webpage - Up to date information - Lecture notes - Relevant dates, links, etc. Course material: [AIMA] Artificial Intelligence: A Modern Approach, by Stuart Russell and Peter Norvig. (2nd ed) This time: Outline (Adversarial Search – AIMA Ch. 6] Game playing Perfect play ◦ The minimax algorithm ◦ alpha-beta pruning Resource limitations Elements of chance Imperfect information CS561 - Lecture 7 - Macskassy - Spring 2010 2 What kind of games? Abstraction: To describe a game we must capture every relevant aspect of the game. Such as: ◦ Chess ◦ Tic-tac-toe ◦ … Accessible environments: Such games are characterized by perfect information Search: game-playing then consists of a search through possible game positions Unpredictable opponent: introduces uncertainty thus game-playing must deal with contingency problems CS561 - Lecture 7 - Macskassy - Spring 2010 3 Searching for the next move Complexity: many games have a huge search space ◦ Chess: b = 35, m=100 nodes = 35 100 if each node takes about 1 ns to explore then each move will take about 10 50 millennia to calculate. Resource (e.g., time, memory) limit: optimal solution not feasible/possible, thus must approximate 1. Pruning: makes the search more efficient by discarding portions of the search tree that cannot improve quality result. 2. Evaluation functions: heuristics to evaluate utility of a state without exhaustive search.
    [Show full text]
  • Optimal Symmetric Rendezvous Search on Three Locations
    Optimal Symmetric Rendezvous Search on Three Locations Richard Weber Centre for Mathematical Sciences, Wilberforce Road, Cambridge CB2 0WB email: [email protected] www.statslab.cam.ac.uk/~rrw1 In the symmetric rendezvous search game played on n locations two players are initially placed at two distinct locations. The game is played in discrete steps, at each of which each player can either stay where he is or move to a different location. The players share no common labelling of the locations. We wish to find a strategy such that, if both players follow it independently, then the expected number of steps until they are in the same location is minimized. Informal versions of the rendezvous problem have received considerable attention in the popular press. The problem was proposed by Steve Alpern in 1976 and it has proved notoriously difficult to analyse. In this paper we prove a 20 year old conjecture that the following strategy is optimal for the game on three locations: in each block of two steps, stay where you, or search the other two locations in random order, doing these with probabilities 1=3 and 2=3 respectively. This is now the first nontrivial symmetric rendezvous search game to be fully solved. Key words: rendezvous search; search games; semidefinite programming MSC2000 Subject Classification: Primary: 90B40; Secondary: 49N75, 90C22, 91A12, 93A14 OR/MS subject classification: Primary: Games/group decisions, cooperative; Secondary: Analysis of algorithms; Programming, quadratic 1. Symmetric rendezvous search on three locations In the symmetric rendezvous search game played on n locations two players are initially placed at two distinct locations.
    [Show full text]
  • Game Playing (Adversarial Search) CS 580 (001) - Spring 2018
    Lecture 5: Game Playing (Adversarial Search) CS 580 (001) - Spring 2018 Amarda Shehu Department of Computer Science George Mason University, Fairfax, VA, USA February 21, 2018 Amarda Shehu (580) 1 1 Outline of Today's Class 2 Games vs Search Problems 3 Perfect Play Minimax Decision Alpha-Beta Pruning 4 Resource Limits and Approximate Evaluation Expectiminimax 5 Games of Imperfect Information 6 Game Playing Summary Amarda Shehu (580) Outline of Today's Class 2 Game Playing { Adversarial Search Search in a multi-agent, competitive environment ! Adversarial Search/Game Playing Mathematical game theory treats any multi-agent environment as a game, with possibly co-operative behaviors (study of economies) Most games studied in AI: deterministic, turn-taking, two-player, zero-sum games of perfect information Amarda Shehu (580) Games vs Search Problems 3 Game Playing - Adversarial Search Most games studied in AI: deterministic, turn-taking, two-player, zero-sum games of perfect information zero-sum: utilities of the two players sum to 0 (no win-win) deterministic: precise rules with known outcomes perfect information: fully observable Amarda Shehu (580) Games vs Search Problems 4 Game Playing - Adversarial Search Most games studied in AI: deterministic, turn-taking, two-player, zero-sum games of perfect information zero-sum: utilities of the two players sum to 0 (no win-win) deterministic: precise rules with known outcomes perfect information: fully observable Search algorithms designed for such games make use of interesting general techniques (meta-heuristics) such as evaluation functions, search pruning, and more. However, games are to AI what grand prix racing is to automobile design.
    [Show full text]
  • A Model of Add-On Pricing
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES A MODEL OF ADD-ON PRICING Glenn Ellison Working Paper 9721 http://www.nber.org/papers/w9721 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 May 2003 I would like to thank the National Science Foundation for financial support. This paper grew out of joint work with Sara Fisher Ellison. Joshua Fischman provided excellent research assistance. Jonathan Levin and Steve Tadelis provided helpful feedback. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and not necessarily those of the National Bureau of Economic Research. ©2003 by Glenn Ellison. All rights reserved. Short sections of text not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit including © notice, is given to the source. A Model of Add-on Pricing Glenn Ellison NBER Working Paper No. 9721 May 2003 JEL No. L13, M30 ABSTRACT This paper examines a competitive model of add-on pricing, the practice of advertising low prices for one good in hopes of selling additional products (or a higher quality product) to consumers at a high price at the point of sale. The main conclusion is that add-on pricing softens price competition between firms and results in higher equilibrium profits. Glenn Ellison Department of Economics MIT 50 Memorial Drive, E52-274b Cambridge, MA 02142 and NBER [email protected] 1 Introduction In many businesses it is customary to advertise a base price for a product or service and to try to induce customers to buy additional “add-ons” at high prices at the point of sale.
    [Show full text]
  • International Conference Game Theory and Management
    The Tenth International Conference Game Theory and Management 07-09 July, 2016 Saint Petersburg, Russia Organized by Saint Petersburg State University and The International Society of Dynamic Games (Russian Chapter) The Conference is being held at Saint Petersburg State University Volkhovsky per., 3, St. Petersburg, Russia Program Committee Leon Petrosyan (Russia) - chair; Nikolay Zenkevich (Russia) - co-chair; Eitan Altman (France); Jesus Mario Bilbao (Spain); Irinel Dragan (USA); Gao Hongwei (China); Andrey Garnaev (Russia); Margarita Gladkova (Russia); Sergiu Hart (Israel); Steffen Jørgensen (Denmark); Ehud Kalai (USA); Andrea Di Liddo (Italy); Vladimir Mazalov (Russia); Shigeo Muto (Japan); Yaroslavna Pankratova (Russia); Artem Sedakov (Russia); Richard Staelin (USA); Krzysztof J. Szajowski (Poland); Anna Tur (Russia); Anna Veselova (Russia); Myrna Wooders (UK); David W.K. Yeung (HongKong); Georges Zaccour (Canada); Paul Zipkin (USA); Andrey Zyatchin (Russia) Program Graduate School of Management, St. Petersburg State University Volkhovsky per., 3, St. Petersburg, Russia Thursday, July 07 08:45 – 09:30 REGISTRATION 3rd floor 08:45 – 09:30 COFFEE Room 307 09:30 – 09:50 WELCOME ADDRESS Room 309 09.50 – 10:55 PLENARY TALK (1) Room 309 11.00 – 12:00 PLENARY TALK (2) Room 309 12:10 – 14:00 LUNCH University Center 13:30 – 14:00 COFFEE Room 307 14:00 – 16:30 PARALLEL SESSIONS (T1) Room 209, 410 16:30 – 16:50 COFFEE BREAK Room 307 16:50 – 19:00 PARALLEL SESSIONS (T2) Room 209, 410 19:00 – 22:00 WELCOME PARTY Room 309 Friday, July 08 09:30
    [Show full text]
  • Bayesian Search Under Dynamic Disaster Scenarios
    UNIVERSIDAD DEL NORTE Department of Industrial Engineering Barranquilla, Colombia BAYESIAN SEARCH UNDER DYNAMIC DISASTER SCENARIOS BUSQUEDA´ BAYESIANA BAJO ESCENARIOS DE DESASTRE DINAMICOS´ by Jos´eDaniel Betancourt Reyes A thesis submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the Degree of Master of Science in Industrial Engineering Advisor: Gina Galindo, Ph.D. Juries: Dr. Rajan Batta State University of New York Dr. Yezid Donoso Universidad de Los Andes MSc. Santiago Nieto Universidad del Norte Barranquilla, January of 2017 Dedicated to God Who gave me the opportunity to live this wonderful experience and the strength to not give up. He is simply the greatest of my life. My lovely family Whose support and encouragement were exceptional aids to me through this path. My grandparents Vicente and Gloria, my mom and her husband Julia and Luis, my uncles Juan and Jorge, my aunt Zaida and her amazing children Sara and Josue, are all extraordinary people that I will always carry in my heart. My girlfriend Juliette With whom I have been so fortunate of sharing this stage of my life. Her company along this journey has filled my life with thousands of fantastic experiences which I treasure in my heart. ii Acknowledgments First of all, I want to thank God for giving me all the required resources to complete this thesis. I will always recognize that all I achieve is primarily thanks to Him. I feel so happy of been directed by Gina Galindo for the development of this research. Her advices, corrections and instructions were crucial for the satisfactory completion of this thesis.
    [Show full text]
  • Combinatorial Games: Selected Bibliography with a Succinct Gourmet Introduction
    Combinatorial Games: Selected Bibliography With A Succinct Gourmet Introduction Aviezri S. Fraenkel Department of Applied Mathematics and Computer Science Weizmann Institute of Science Rehovot 76100, Israel [email protected] http://www.wisdom.weizmann.ac.il/∼fraenkel 1 What are Combinatorial Games? Roughly speaking, the family of combinatorial games consists of two-player games with perfect information (no hidden information as in some card games), no chance moves (no dice) and outcome restricted to (lose, win), (tie, tie) and (draw, draw) for the two players who move alternately. Tie is an end position such as in tic-tac-toe, where no player wins, whereas draw is a dynamic tie: any position from which a player has a nonlosing move, but cannot force a win. Both the easy game of Nim and the seemingly difficult chess are examples of combinatorial games. And so is go. The shorter terminology game, games is used below to designate combinatorial games. 2 Why are Games Intriguing and Tempting? Amusing oneself with games may sound like a frivolous occupation. But the fact is that the bulk of interesting and natural mathematical problems that are hardest in complexity classes beyond NP ,suchasPspace, Exptime and Expspace, are two-player games; occasionally even one-player games (puzzles) or even zero-player games (Conway’s “Life”). Some of the reasons for the high complexity of two-player games are outlined in the next section. Before that we note that in addition to a natural appeal of the subject, there are applications or connections to various areas, including complexity, logic, graph and matroid theory, networks, error-correcting codes, surreal numbers, on-line algorithms and biology.
    [Show full text]