Analysis of the

Plan A Self-Pay System Designed to Minimize the Burden of Health Care Costs

Kandice A. Kapinos • Carter C. Price

Drew M. Anderson • Adrienne M. Propp

Raffaele Vardavas • Christopher M. Whaley

C O R P O R A T I O N For more information on this publication, visit www.rand.org/t/RR4270

Published by the RAND Corporation, Santa Monica, Calif. © Copyright 2021 RAND Corporation R® is a registered trademark

Limited Print and Electronic Distribution Rights This document and trademark(s) contained herein are protected by law. This representation of RAND intellectual property is provided for noncommercial use only. Unauthorized online posting of this content is prohibited. Permission is given to duplicate this document for personal use only, as long as it is unaltered and complete. Permission is required from RAND to reproduce, or reuse in another form, any of our research documents for commercial use. For information on reprint and linking permissions, please visit www.rand.org/pubs/permissions.html.

The RAND Corporation is a research organization that develops solutions to public policy challenges to help make communities throughout the world safer and more secure, healthier and more prosperous. RAND is nonprofit, nonpartisan, and committed to the public interest.

RAND’s publications do not necessarily reflect the opinions of its research clients and sponsors.

Support RAND Make a tax-deductible charitable contribution at www.rand.org/giving/contribute

www.rand.org Preface

In this report, we analyze how total health care spending, family out- of-pocket health spending, and federal costs would change under a self-pay system designed to keep the burden of health care costs for most families to less than 10 percent of a family’s income. The 10Plan, conceived by Mark Cuban, would eliminate the need for traditional health insurance for individuals currently purchasing coverage in the nongroup health insurance market or for those who are currently unin- sured. Individuals would pay no premiums up front; they would pay for care only when needed, and they would be able to defer payments after a $25 copay by taking out a low-interest loan from the federal government. In the case of deferred payments, the federal government would pay providers on behalf of 10Plan participants, who would then repay the federal government over time at a rate based on income for a maximum of 15 years or until age 65. We modeled dynamic estimates of health care spending and federal costs that incorporate evidence from the empirical literature on expected changes in health care utili- zation as well as adjusted for expected changes in prices, as the 10Plan would be based on Medicare fee-for-service rates. This research was conducted with funding from Mark Cuban. The work was performed independently of the sponsor and peer- reviewed in keeping with the RAND Corporation’s rigorous quality assurance standards. The study was conducted within the Payment, Cost, and Coverage Program in RAND Health Care. Any opinions, findings, conclusions, and recommendations are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect of Mark Cuban.

iii iv Analysis of the 10Plan

RAND Health Care, a division of the RAND Corporation, promotes healthier societies by improving health care systems in the United States and other countries. We do this by providing health care decisionmakers, practitioners, and consumers with actionable, rigor- ous, objective evidence to support their most complex decisions. For more information, see www.rand.org/health-care, or contact

RAND Health Care Communications 1776 Main Street P.O. Box 2138 Santa Monica, CA 90407-2138 (310) 393-0411, ext. 7775 [email protected] Contents

Preface...... iii Figures...... vii Tables...... ix Summary...... xi Acknowledgments...... xxvii Abbreviations...... xxix

CHAPTER ONE Introduction...... 1

CHAPTER TWO How the 10Plan Works...... 5 Consumers...... 5 Comparison with Status Quo...... 13

CHAPTER THREE Approach...... 17 Data and Methods...... 17 Key Outcomes...... 19

CHAPTER FOUR Results...... 27

CHAPTER FIVE Conclusion...... 49 Limitations and Caveats...... 51

v vi Analysis of the 10Plan

APPENDIXES A. Health Care Demand and Supply...... 57 B. Methodology...... 79 C. Additional Results ...... 91

References...... 101 Figures

S.1. Mean Individual Annual Health Care Expenditures as of Year 15, by Current Health Insurance Status ...... xv S.2. Median Effective Repayment Premium Rate and Total Payment Rate as Percentage of Family Income in Year 15, by FPL Category...... xvii S.3. 15-Year Total Population Health Care Expenditures Plus Administrative Costs...... xviii 2.1. How the 10Plan Would Work...... 6 2.2. Hypothetical Family Health Care Expenditures, Deferred Payments, and Repayments Under the 10Plan...... 12 4.1. Distribution of Total Annual Health Care Expenditures Among 10Plan Families ...... 29 4.2. Mean Individual Annual Health Care Expenditures as of Year 15, by Current Health Insurance Status ...... 30 4.3. Change in Mean Total Annual Health Care Expenditures in Year 15, by Health Status ...... 32 4.4. Population Totals of Out-of-Pocket Health Care Expenditures...... 33 4.5. Median Effective Repayment Premium Rate and Total Payment Rate as a Percentage of Family Income in Year 15, by FPL Category...... 34 4.6. Percentage of 10Plan Families Paying Maximum Repayment Cap in Year 15, by FPL Category...... 35 4.7. 15-Year Total Population Health Care Expenditures Plus Administrative Costs...... 37 B.1. Overview of Health Status Changes...... 84 B.2. Example Classification and Regression Tree...... 87

vii viii Analysis of the 10Plan

C.1. Number of 10Plan-Eligible Individuals with Nonzero Deferred Payment Balance in Year 15, by Income and Age Group...... 94 C.2. Value of Deferred Payment Balances in Year 15, by Age Group...... 95 C.3. Proportion of Total Deferred Payment Balances for All 10Plan Participants, by Income Group and Health Status..... 96 C.4. Average Repayment Premiums in Year 15 by Health Status, Stratified by Income Level...... 96 C.5. Quantiles of Effective Repayment Rate by Income Group in Year 15...... 97 Tables

S.1. Measures of Health Care Spending...... xiv S.2. Effects of the 10Plan on Government Spending, in Billions of Dollars...... xx 2.1. Repayment Premiums as Percentage of Income...... 8 2.2. Overview of Status Quo Versus the 10Plan...... 15 3.1. Key Model Inputs and Data Sources...... 18 3.2. Measures of Health Care Spending...... 21 3.3. Overview of Sensitivity Checks...... 25 4.1. 10Plan Participation at the End of Years 1, 5, 10, and 15...... 28 4.2. Deferred Payment Balances Forgiven by the Government, Stratified by Reason for Forgiveness by Year, in Billions of Dollars...... 38 4.3. Effect of the 10Plan on Government Spending, in Billions of Dollars...... 39 4.4. Sensitivity Analyses, Estimated Total Spending in Year 15 and Across 15-Year Period, in Billions of Dollars...... 44 A.1. Summary of Empirical Evidence: How Utilization Changes in Response to Changes in Required Out-of-Pocket Spending...... 70 A.2. Range of Predicted Changes in Utilization for Currently Uninsured...... 73 A.3. Range of Predicted Changes in Utilization for Currently Insured...... 74 C.1. Distribution of Health Care Spending for 10Plan-Eligible Family Members Under the 10Plan and Status Quo ...... 92 C.2. Comparison of 10Plan and Hybrid Policies Across 10Plan Target Group Medical Spending, Medicaid Population

ix Medical Spending, Payments Deferred, and Forgiven Balances per Year, in Billions of Dollars...... 98 Summary

In this report, we investigate an alternative health care financing approach, the 10Plan, for the nearly 28 million individuals who cur- rently are not covered by health insurance (Terlizzi, Cohen, and Marti- nez, 2019) and the approximately 20 million individuals who purchase private coverage in the nongroup market, including on the Affordable Care Act exchanges (Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services [CMS], 2019; Kaiser Family Foundation, undated). The 10Plan, con- ceived by Mark Cuban, would eliminate the need for traditional health insurance for these individuals and allow them to pay for care only when needed, and then at Medicare prices (Shapiro and Aneja, 2019). The 10Plan is called the “10” Plan because most participants will not pay more than 10 percent of their family’s income on repayment pre- miums. To protect participants from financial uncertainty because of health care events that are high-cost or beyond their ability to afford, participants would be able to defer payments after a $25 copay for each encounter. In the case of deferred payments, participants would be bor- rowing from the federal government at a 3-percent interest rate. The federal government would pay providers on behalf of the 10Plan par- ticipants, who would then repay the federal government over time at a means-tested rate (based on family income) for a maximum of 15 years or until age 65. Even though this is a loan repayment program, we refer to the loan repayments as repayment premiums because they would replace the traditional health insurance premiums and be paid only once care is used. The repayments would be capped based on income, ranging from 2 to 15 percent of income (10 percent or less for families at or below 600 percent of the federal poverty level [FPL]). Payments

xi xii Analysis of the 10Plan

Key Findings • The 10Plan would cover approximately 46 million individ- uals, including 28 million who are currently uninsured. • The 10Plan is predicted to reduce family-level health care spending, especially for those currently covered by a non- group plan. Average out-of-pocket costs would decline by about $1,343 per participant, per year. • Depending on model assumptions, federal spending could decrease by $17 billion or increase by $566 billion over the first 15 years. could be deferred cumulatively over multiple years, and repayments could change over time as an individual’s or family’s income changes and at certain ages (26 and 65). The 10Plan would be available to anyone not covered by employer- sponsored insurance, Medicare, Medicaid, or another government plan (e.g., Tricare or Indian Health Services) and who is current on any repayment premiums from previous deferred payments. This would amount to approximately 15 percent of the U.S. population, or approx- imately 43 to 48 million individuals in about 30 million families, having access to a plan to pay for health care in a way that limits out- of-pocket costs based on income. (Of note: We determined eligibility for the 10Plan using age and health insurance coverage type and did not impute documentation status. Therefore, in our model, undocu- mented immigrants are eligible to receive the 10Plan, which may not be the case if the plan is implemented). The purpose of this analysis was to determine how much the 10Plan would cost participating individuals and families and how much it would cost the federal government. We also highlighted inci- dences in which individuals could be negatively affected by the imple- mentation of the 10Plan by examining family-level financial burden. On the one hand, the 10Plan could be viewed as potentially transfer- ring the risk of high-cost and catastrophic health care events to the federal government because the plan limits a family’s financial respon- sibility based on ability to pay. On the other hand, the 10Plan replaces Summary xiii nongroup health insurance, so the extent to which this plan changes the financial burden for those already insured is unclear. Specifically, the report addresses the following research questions:

• How would health care spending change for individuals and fam- ilies under the 10Plan relative to the status quo? • How would these changes vary for different participants, depend- ing on insurance status and income level? • How much would the 10Plan cost the federal government com- pared with the status quo?

To address these questions, we used a microsimulation model to estimate health care spending under the 10Plan compared with the status quo. The model uses individual-level microdata to simulate changes over time, including repayment of deferred payments, unex- pected health problems, changes in employment or income, and family structure. We assumed that the uninsured would consume 20 percent more care because of their expected ability to defer costs relative to the status quo. Under the status quo, they may forgo care because they are afraid of not knowing exactly what their out-of-pocket liability will be for any medical encounters. Because the repayment premiums (deferred payments for medical expenses) can be spread over multiple years with the 10Plan, we built a dynamic model that accounts for year-to-year changes in medical spending, income, and family struc- ture over a 15-year period. We chose a 15-year time horizon because after 15 years, deferred payments from the first year would be forgiven. A key outflow for the government will be forgiveness of balances after 15 years. The forgiven balances will not be considered taxable income for participating individuals. The main outcomes that we examine are related to health care spending at the individual or family level, and in aggregate at the pop- ulation level. In Table S.1, we show the measures of annual spending that we use to compare the 10Plan to the status quo spending. In addition to presenting aggregate population totals of health care expenditures, we also present a budgetary cash flow of the effects for com- parison with Congressional Budget Office (CBO) scoring approaches. xiv Analysis of the 10Plan

Table S.1 Measures of Health Care Spending

Measure Status Quo 10Plan

1. Individual-level a. Total paid for health b. Amount in 1(a), total health care care under current adjusted for changes expenditures insurance status by all in prices faced payers

2. Individual-level c. Copays and coinsur- d. Copays and total out-of-pocket ance and amounts repayments costs contributed to insur- ance premiums

3. Population-level e. Sum of 1(a) for all f. Sum of 1(b) for total expenditures 10Plan-eligible all 10Plan-eligible individuals individuals

We conducted numerous sensitivity analyses, changing several of our modeling assumptions. The key assumptions we varied were (1) the prices that individuals face (Medicare, various fractions of Medicare, or Medicaid), (2) loan or repayment program details, (3) other plan parameters, and (4) behavioral or demand responses.

Results

Individuals and Families We found that between 15 and 17 percent (approximately 46 million) of people in the United States would be eligible for the 10Plan each year, including the approximately 28.8 million individuals who cur- rently have no insurance and the 18 million who are currently obtain- ing coverage in the nongroup market. In Figure S.1, we present the predicted total individual-level expenditures (measured as defined in row 1 of Table S.1) under the status quo and the 10Plan. Within each bar in Figure S.1, we show the average annual amount spent on cost-sharing (dark blue) and the average annual amount spent on premiums (light blue). Under the status quo, there are no insur- ance premiums for those currently uninsured, but for those currently covered by a nongroup plan, this is average annual insurance premium contributions. Under the 10Plan, the premiums are the average annual Summary xv

Figure S.1 Mean Individual Annual Health Care Expenditures as of Year 15, by Current Health Insurance Status

OOP: Copays and cost-sharing Covered by other payers OOP: Premiums Amounts to defer under 10Plan

10 9,287 8,968 9

8 7,274 7,313 7 6,285 5,977 6

5

4 6,013 3 (65%) 2 2,748 (38%) 1 1,174 1,783 1,405 (19%) (20%) (19%) Annual expenditures (in thousands of dollars) Annual expenditures 687 (11%) 0 SQ 10Plan SQ 10Plan SQ 10Plan Uninsured Nongroup Plan All 10Plan participants

NOTE: SQ = status quo, which is projected spending assuming no 10Plan and a medical inflation rate of 5.1 percent. Each bar reflects total annual health care expenditures as defined in row 1 of Table S.1. The dark blue sections reflect out-of-pocket (OOP) spending on copays and cost-sharing (row 2 of Table S.1). The light blue sections reflect spending on premiums or repayment premiums (row 3 of Table S.1). The green sections reflect amounts covered by other payers under the status quo, and the purple sections reflect amounts deferred under the 10Plan. repayment premiums from deferred payments in earlier years. The green or “other payers” parts of the bars reflect amounts that are cur- rently covered by other payers under the status quo, such as employers and amounts covered by charity care (or written off) and worker’s com- pensation. The purple segments represent the fraction of health care spending that would be deferred under the 10Plan. Overall, the model predicted that total individual health care spending per year would be similar for both the status quo and the 10Plan, but out-of-pocket costs would be $1,343 lower on average xvi Analysis of the 10Plan for individuals under the 10Plan (see the two bars on the far right in Figure S.1). We also found significant differences depending on current health insurance status. For those currently uninsured, our model pre- dicted total health spending per year to be about $308 higher under the 10Plan, on average ($6,285 versus $5,977), or an increase of 5 percent relative to the 20 percent increase in health care utilization assumed under the 10Plan. This translates into an increase in out-of-pocket spending (both blue-shaded segments of the bars in Figure S.1) of $487 for the uninsured. For those currently covered by a nongroup plan, our model pre- dicted that total annual health care spending will be $319 lower under the 10Plan ($8,968 versus $9,287), relative to the status quo. The out-of-pocket spending is predicted to be $4,230 less per year ($1,783 versus $6,013), on average, for these individuals under the 10Plan. In the aggregate, 10Plan participants are predicted to spend $63 billion less per year out of pocket under the 10Plan relative to the status quo, or $940 billion less over the 15-year period. In Figure S.2, we show the median effective repayment rate and total payment rate (repayment premium plus copayment) as a percent- ages of family income in year 15, compared with the maximum annual repayment cap (purple line). The annual repayment premium is capped at a percentage of family income that depends on the family’s income as a percentage of FPL. Thus, the range of repayments for each cohort will fall between 0 and the annual repayment cap (up to 15 percent of income). The copays, however, are not capped. The lowest-income fam- ilies (< 250 percent of FPL) effectively will pay between 3 and 4 percent of income toward the cost of health care for 10Plan participants (red bars, which include copays and repayment premiums), which is more than the repayment cap. The highest-income families will effectively pay less than 1 percent of their income toward the cost of health care for 10Plan participants.

Total Spending Over the 15-year period, we predicted total health care spending of the 10Plan-eligible population, including administrative costs, to be about Summary xvii

Figure S.2 Median Effective Repayment Premium Rate and Total Payment Rate as Percentage of Family Income in Year 15, by FPL Category

16 Repayment premium 14 Total payment 12 Maximum cap

10

8

6

4

Percentage of family income Percentage 2

0 100–150 150–250 250–400 400–600 600–800 800+ Family income as a percentage of FPL

NOTES: Total payment includes both repayment premiums and copayments. We do not show the effective repayment premium rate or total payment rate for the population with family income below 100 percent of FPL because the repayment cap at this level is 0 percent.

$3.87 trillion under the status quo, relative to $3.85 trillion under the 10Plan. This assumes that the 10Plan is able to achieve administrative costs that are similar to the Medicare program. Administrative costs for insurers are typically defined to be the difference between the premi- ums collected and the benefits paid out and include overhead costs. This amounts to about $21 billion in reduced total health care spend- ing over the 15-year period because of lower prices, or about $1.42 bil- lion less spending per year. Savings could be achieved primarily through (1) lower prices for 10Plan participants and (2) lower administrative costs. We esti- mated that if 10Plan participants faced Medicare prices, total health care spending would decline by $33 billion over the 15-year period ($3.57 trillion versus $3.53 trillion). We estimated that administra- tive costs under the status quo are projected to be around $305 billion over the period. If the 10Plan can achieve administrative costs that are xviii Analysis of the 10Plan

10 percent of the value of the loans, that would amount to $316 billion over the 15-year period. Thus, we do not predict savings from admin- istrative costs under these assumptions. For comparison, Shapiro and Aneja (2019) assumed 5 percent administrative costs, and we expect that administrative costs are cur- rently about 20 percent for those covered by a nongroup plan. We have reported total costs in Figure S.3, assuming these administrative costs as well.

Figure S.3 15-Year Total Population Health Care Expenditures Plus Administrative Costs

Population total health expenditures 4,500 Administrative costs 4,000 632 305 316 3,500 158

3,000

2,500

2,000 3,566 of dollars) 3,533 3,533 3,533 1,500

1,000

500 15-year population totals (in billions 0 SQ 10Plan + 10Plan + 10Plan + 5% loan costs 10% loan costs 20% loan costs

NOTES: SQ = status quo. Administrative costs under the SQ are calculated as 20 percent of the total population health expenditures, less the amounts that families pay out of pocket. Administrative costs under the 10Plan are equal to 5, 10, or 20 percent of the amount of deferred payments that the federal government will lend. Summary xix

Federal Government Spending Over the 15-year period, we predicted the federal government would save an estimated $17 billion (see Table S.2).1 However, federal spend- ing would increase to $3 billion a year as of year 15. Because year 15 is the first year in which the unpaid amounts from the first set of deferred payments from year 1 will be forgiven, the accounting in this year gives the best estimate of what the budgetary effect would be over the longer term. Thus, the program is likely to continue to be a net expense to the federal government. However, in the event that there are savings from federal spending on the 10Plan population, those savings can be used in a variety of ways (to be determined), such as reducing the out- of-pocket costs for the lowest-income families, investing savings into medical education scholarships, or covering additional cost-effective treatments with no cost-sharing. Across all of the scenarios, depending on model assumptions, we found a range of changes in federal spend- ing. As noted, federal government spending could decrease by $17 bil- lion or increase by as much as $566 billion over the first 15 years.

Sensitivity Analyses of Health Care Spending We estimated several versions of the dynamic microsimulation varying different aspects of the assumptions. Our estimates of the change in total health care spending relative to the status quo are most sensitive to the price levels that 10Plan-eligible families and individuals will face and less sensitive to the parameters and policy features tested in the other sensitivity analyses. In other words, the prices that we assumed that 10Plan participants would face are the most significant factors in determining whether the 10Plan will generate savings or not. Assuming Medicare prices, as we did for most of the results presented, our model suggests savings of $21.5 billion over 15 years, including administra- tive costs. However, if 10Plan participants face 234 percent of Medi- care rates, as the state of Montana was able to negotiate with hospitals (Appleby, 2018), then we predicted increased spending of $1,263 bil-

1 The 10-year calculations are also provided to match a 10-year CBO baseline projection, but we note that because the plan does not reach the steady state until year 15, our preference is to focus on 15-year results. xx Analysis of the 10Plan $12.45 $0.00 $672.00 $176.65 − $1,271.15 $1,271.15 − $1,766.50 $1,283.60 $1,283.60 $1,283.60 10-Year Total Total 10-Year $0.00 $16.92 $316.11 − $3,161.09 $1,089.00 $2,405.12 $2,405.12 $2,405.12 $2,388.20 $2,388.20 − Total over 15-Year Period overTotal 15-Year $3.08 46.80 $87.75 $31.09 $251.20 $251.20 $251.20 $310.94 $254.29 $254.29 − 45.73 $13.41 $77.00 $23.23 $191.91 $191.91 $191.91 $178.49 $178.49 $232.27 − − 43.61 $16.71 $18.85 $65.00 $137.66 $137.66 $137.66 $167.10 $118.81 $118.81 − − $0.00 $0.00 $0.00 $0.00 $0.00 $0.00 $0.00 43.47 Year 1Year 5 Year 10 Year 15 Year $13.18 $62.00 $83.02 $83.02 $83.02 $131.83 −

Deferred payments Deferred APTC Revenue Repayment premiums Repayment Tax effects Tax Total Outlays Total Administrative costs Outlays Revenue Budget effectBudget Table S.2 Effects of the 10Plan on Government Spending, in Billions of Dollars Net effect Net Number of 10Plan participants 10Plan Number of per year (in millions) NOTES: APTC = Advanced Premium Credit. Tax APTC amounts include all “Marketplace-Related Coverage and the Basic Health Program” expenditures. Note APTC that 15 the projections Year are linearly extrapolated from CBO estimates (Fritzsche and Masi, Administrative 2016). costs are estimated percent at 10 of deferred payments. Summary xxi lion compared with the status quo over 15 years. Even though Montana hospitals may not be representative of all hospitals in the United States, we expect it may be difficult to get hospitals to accept rates lower than 234 percent of Medicare rates. The other modeling assumption that affects whether we predicted savings from the 10Plan concerns forgiving loan balances at age 65. In our main model, we did not assume any behavioral responses from this, but 10Plan participants would have an incentive to increase their consumption of health care (especially discretionary) as they approach age 64. In particular, knowing that they would not have to repay costs in subsequent years may affect their behavior. In one sensitiv- ity check, we increased health care utilization linearly from ages 51 to 64 to account for this possibility. In this model, we estimated that the 10Plan, with Medicare prices, would increase total expenditures by $659 billion over 15 years relative to the status quo.

Discussion

Overall, we predicted a decline in total health care spending among 10Plan participants of almost $33 billion over a 15-year period. Much of this decline results from lower prices (assuming Medicare rates) for the projected 46 million 10Plan participants. Assuming the 10Plan can lower administrative costs to 10 percent of the amount of deferred payments or loans, costs would increase by $11 billion over the 15-year period relative to the status quo. Together, these amount to savings of about $1.4 billion per year ($21.5 billion total over 15 years) for a plan that covers 46 million individuals, includ- ing approximately 28 million who are currently uninsured. Under more-costly assumptions, we predicted federal spending to increase by about $38 billion per year, which is significantly less than estimates of $2 trillion to $3 trillion per year needed under Medicare for All pro- posals (Committee for a Responsible Federal Budget, 2019; Reichling and Smetters, 2020). There are important aspects of our modeling assumptions that can change these estimates such that the 10Plan will yield increases in xxii Analysis of the 10Plan total health care expenditures. First, the assumption that 10Plan partici- pants will pay Medicare rates is critical. Just lowering the prices that this population faces matters significantly. More than 90 percent of physicians accept Medicare, but the extent to which these providers can be mandated to accept 10Plan patients is unclear. Secondly, because deferred payment (or loan) balances are forgiven at age 65, increas- ing health care utilization as individuals approach age 65 changes our results significantly. In this case, we predicted that the 10Plan would increase costs over the 15-year period. Out-of-pocket health care costs are a major concern for many Americans, both because of uninsurance and under-insurance. Health care reform proposals that provide free care or eliminate cost-sharing (e.g., Senator Bernie Sanders’s proposed Medicare for All plan) are an expensive way to reduce consumer costs. The10Plan requires a contri- bution, but, unlike the current cost-sharing arrangement for insured individuals—in which they pay the full cost of a medical visit up front until they hit their deductible—the 10Plan allows deferred payments that can be paid back gradually on a schedule, and repayments are capped in a manner that scales with income. On average, individuals covered by the 10Plan will spend less on health care and have lower out-of-pocket costs compared with the status quo. However, this varies by family income, current health insurance status, and health status. Lower-income families will pay about 3 to 4 percent of their incomes on repayments and copays, which is more than what uninsured indi- viduals in those income categories currently pay out of pocket for health care. In general, uninsured individuals will face greater out-of- pocket health care costs under the 10Plan, regardless of income, but we have assumed they will consume 20 percent more health care and will gain risk protection under the 10Plan because they will not be required to pay more than their means-tested rate. Health insurance provides some risk protection against high-cost catastrophic health events. The 10Plan offers similar protections by capping the loan or amount of the deferred repayments depending on the individual’s or family’s income. This feature addresses the problem of people being unprepared for an unexpected bill without requiring the government to shoulder the entire burden. It follows the logic of Summary xxiii

proponents of high-deductible health plans and universal catastrophic coverage, who argue that “skin in the game” can be a good thing (or, conversely, that first-dollar coverage can lead to overconsumption and may be impractically expensive),2 and addresses the number one criti- cism of such plans, that high deductibles put people at risk of being unable to pay. One potential concern is that individuals who do not make pre- mium repayments under the 10Plan would not be able to continue to use the plan. However, under the status quo, individuals who do not pay for health insurance or do not pay medical bills face the same scenario. Moreover, the 10Plan would adjust repayments or suspend them in the event that someone loses employment. The 10Plan also provides this risk protection to everyone not covered by a public or pri- vate health insurance plan, while, as of this writing, there are approx- imately 28 million people without any risk protection provided by health insurance. The 10Plan would change the federal government’s cash flow. In particular, the government would increase outlays to cover individuals’ health care spending up front and then receive repayment premiums to help cover these amounts in subsequent years. Some amounts would be forgiven after 15 years of repayment premiums, upon death, or as indi- viduals age into Medicare. However, as noted previously, increased uti- lization may yield longer-term improvements in health, and the 10Plan would essentially facilitate low-interest loans for some individuals who may not be able to obtain credit otherwise or would have to pay signifi- cantly higher interest.

Study Limitations There are several limitations and caveats to our estimates that should be considered when interpreting our results. First, we note that there are both potential advantages and disadvantages to the 10Plan that we have not modeled that are important to consider in light of our esti- mates. As discussed previously, the 10Plan offers the advantage of risk

2 First-dollar coverage refers to who is responsible for the up-front and initial costs of care. Insurance plans with deductibles, for example, require enrollees to cover the first-dollar amounts until the deductible is met. xxiv Analysis of the 10Plan protection for both those currently purchasing a plan in the nongroup health insurance market and for those who are uninsured. Currently, those without insurance are less likely to receive regular or preventive care and are less likely to get prescriptions filled (Christopher et al., 2016; Fernandez-Lazaro et al., 2019; Liang, Beydoun, and Eid, 2019; McMorrow, Kenney, and Goin, 2014). The uninsured also have higher rates of emergency department use relative to those with private insur- ance and the cost of care tends to be higher in that setting relative to outpatient settings (Greenwood-Ericksen and Kocher, 2019; Xu et al., 2017). Although we make broad assumptions about utilization increas- ing as a result of the 10Plan, we do not account for the possibility that health outcomes and spending might improve for those who are cur- rently uninsured who would be able to seek treatment earlier and in less costly settings without the risk of catastrophic medical bills. This point is important because we found that out-of-pocket spending would increase, on average, for those who are currently uninsured, and who do not have protection from a costly catastrophic health event under the status quo. About 56 percent of adults report a medical financial hardship, defined as having a problem paying a medi- cal bill, worrying about paying for the cost of care for a serious illness (e.g., “financial toxicity”), or delaying or forgoing care because of wor- ries about costs (Yabroff et al., 2019). Ideally, we would compare health outcomes with quality of care (e.g., access) given the amounts spent under the two options, but we were unable to quantify the change in benefits using the data that we had. There may also be broader market-level effects that influence prices and the supply of health care; we have not modeled these effects. We have assumed that individuals who are currently covered by employer-sponsored plans will keep their current coverage. How- ever, firms may have an incentive to stop providing insurance and instead offer their employees a subsidy to participate in the 10Plan, under which health care prices are lower. This would result in greater participation in the 10Plan, which would have implications for federal cash flows that are associated with managing this program. We also have not modeled potential effects of the 10Plan on health; that is, if the 10Plan increases access, we may observe improved health outcomes over the longer term, which can reduce costs. Summary xxv

Other researchers have predicted that the number of uninsured individuals will increase without any reform to health care delivery in the United States (Reichling and Smetters, 2020), but we have not accounted for growth in this population. If more individuals use the 10Plan, there may be increased costs to the federal government. We also have not adjusted for potential provider response to this plan. In particular, as the 10Plan may increase demand for health care, there is no reason, a priori, to expect a corresponding increase in the supply of providers. In fact, if the 10Plan results in downward pres- sure on reimbursement rates broadly, we may expect supply to contract (e.g., fewer hospitals and providers). Whether supply remains constant or contracts, an increase in demand likely means unmet demand and increases in wait times to receive care. There are likely to be logistical and infrastructure changes to the implementation of this plan that we have not included in our cost esti- mates. Administration of such a plan would impose additional costs on CMS, as well as on the federal entity that would handle the deferred payments and repayment premiums. In our federal budgetary analysis, we assumed administrative costs of 10 percent of the deferred payments, which should be interpreted with caution because we are unclear what actual administrative costs would be. There may also be benefits to the federal government from providing administrative services for a wider segment of the population, such as a potential increase in bargaining power in setting prices and additional data to analyze outcomes of care, fraud, and areas where savings may be achieved. For example, CMS makes additional payments to qualifying hospitals that are known as Disproportionate Share Hospital that serve a large number of Medicaid and uninsured individuals. To the extent that the 10Plan eliminates those who are technically without coverage, the amounts that hospitals spend on uncompensated and charity care may decline. Finally, our models required several assumptions that we detail in the report; all interpretations of our findings should be caveated with these assumptions. Note that this analysis does not account for the coronavirus disease 2019 pandemic, because we wanted to address how the 10Plan would work in a typical year.

Acknowledgments

We thank Katherine Carman and Federico Girosi (RAND Corpora- tion), Jonathan Gruber (Massachusetts Institute of Technology), and James Capretta (American Enterprise Institute) for serving as review- ers of this report. We also received helpful guidance from Christine Eibner, David Adamson, Jayme Fuglesten, Paul Koegel, and Jodi Liu at RAND.

xxvii

Abbreviations

ACA Affordable Care Act APTC Advanced Premium Tax Credit ASEC Annual Social and Economic Supplement to the Current Population Survey CART classification and regression tree CBO Congressional Budget Office CDC Centers for Disease Control and Prevention CDHP consumer-directed health plan CHIP Child Health Insurance Program CMS Center for Medicare and Medicaid Services CPS Current Population Survey ED emergency department FFS fee for service FPL federal poverty level GDP gross domestic product HCUP Healthcare Cost and Utilization Project HIE RAND Health Insurance Experiment

xxix xxx Analysis of the 10Plan

HMD Human Mortality Database IRS Internal Revenue Services MAGI modified adjusted gross income MEPS Medical Expenditure Panel Survey NHEA National Health Expenditures Accounts OHE Oregon Health Experiment PHC personal health care PSID Panel Study of Income Dynamics CHAPTER ONE Introduction

This study investigates an alternative health care financing approach— the 10Plan—for the nearly 28 million individuals who currently are not covered by health insurance and the approximately 20 million indi- viduals who purchase private coverage in the nongroup health insur- ance market, including on the Affordable Care Act (ACA) exchanges (Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services [CMS], 2019; Kaiser Family Foundation, undated; Terlizzi, Cohen, and Martinez, 2019). The 10Plan, conceived by Mark Cuban, would eliminate the need for traditional health insurance for these individuals and allow them to pay only for the health care services that they use, and then at Medicare prices (Shapiro and Aneja, 2019). The 10Plan is called the “10” Plan because most participants will not pay more than 10 percent of their family’s income on repayment premiums. To protect participants from uncertainty from health care events that are high-cost or beyond their ability to afford, participants would be able to defer payments after a $25 copay for each encounter. In the case of deferred payments, par- ticipants would essentially be borrowing from the federal government at 3-percent interest rate. The federal government would pay providers on behalf of the10Plan participants, who would then repay the federal government over time at a means-tested rate (based on family income) for a maximum of 15 years or until age 65. Even though the 10Plan is a loan repayment program, we refer to the loan repayments as repayment premiums because they would replace the traditional health insurance premiums and be paid only once care is used. The repayments would be capped on the basis of income, ranging from 2 to 15 percent of

1 2 Analysis of the 10Plan income (10 percent or less for most families). Payments can be deferred cumulatively over multiple years, and repayments could change over time as income changes and at certain ages (26 and 65). Note that this analysis does not account for the coronavirus disease 2019 pandemic, because we wanted to address how the 10Plan would work in a typical year. The 10Plan would be available to anyone not covered by employer- sponsored insurance, Medicare, Medicaid, or another government plan (e.g., Tricare or Indian Health Services), who is current on any repay- ment premiums from previous deferred payments. This would amount to approximately 15 percent of the population of individuals younger than age 65, or approximately 45 million individuals in about 30 mil- lion families. The 10Plan would eliminate all nongroup health insur- ance plan options. This report builds on earlier studies by incorporating evidence from the empirical literature on expected changes in health care uti- lization as well as adjusting for expected changes in prices. We used individual-level microdata to construct estimates of health care expen- ditures in a dynamic microsimulation model that accounts for changes over time, including repayment of the deferred payments, health shocks, changes in employment and income, and family structure. We assessed the economic implications of the 10Plan, including federal outlays, federal revenues, and individual costs over a 15-year period. We did not seek to determine broader macroeconomic effects or narrow impli- cations for insurance companies or their workforces. Our objective was to determine how much the 10Plan would cost the individuals and families participating in it and how much it would cost the federal government. Specifically, in this report, we address the following research questions:

• How would health care spending change for individuals and fam- ilies under the 10Plan relative to the status quo? • How would these changes vary for different participants, based on insurance status, health status, and income level? Introduction 3

• How much would the 10Plan cost the federal government com- pared with the status quo?

The remainder of the report is organized as follows:

• In Chapter Two, we describe how the 10Plan works for providers, consumers, and the federal government. • In Chapter Three, we describe our analytic approach. • In Chapter Four, we provide our results. • In Chapter Five, we discuss results. • The appendixes present a primer for nonexpert readers on the existing empirical literature about health care supply and demand. They also present key assumptions for readers seeking to know more about how we modeled changes in utilization and prices under the 10Plan.

CHAPTER TWO How the 10Plan Works

In this chapter, we outline the key attributes of the 10Plan, while noting that some details have not been finalized and may require additional consideration. We also compare this plan to the status quo.

Consumers

In Figure 2.1, we present a high-level overview of how the 10Plan would work in practice for consumers, who would pay a $25 copay for each encounter, which would be billed at Medicare fee-for-service rates. The balance of the bill could either be deferred and repaid over time or paid in full out of pocket. We discuss this in more detail in the following sections.

Eligibility and Participation Eligibility would be limited to individuals who are not currently cov- ered by an employer-sponsored plan, Medicare, Medicaid, or another government plan (e.g., Tricare or Indian Health Services). At the time of service, participating providers would need to verify a patient’s iden- tity and eligibility. We determined eligibility for the 10Plan on the basis of age and health insurance coverage type and we did not impute documentation status. Therefore, in our model, undocumented immi- grants are eligible to receive the 10Plan, which may not be the case if the plan is implemented. In our primary analysis, we assumed that individuals covered by a private group plan will not be allowed to use the 10Plan, but we

5 6 Analysis of the 10Plan

Figure 2.1 How the 10Plan Would Work

Health care visit YES

Defer Pay $25 payments copay and receive care Eligible for 10plan? Receive bill Instant driver’s NO license/ID Pay out of eligibility Self-pay check pocket also discussed how our estimates would change if this assumption were relaxed. We also modeled year-to-year changes in insurance status as a result of changes in employment and income in our dynamic estimates. For the purposes of modeling, we have assumed that the 10Plan would eliminate the market for current exchange and other nongroup health insurance plans. In this way, those currently covered by a non- group plan and the uninsured would have to choose to pay out of pocket for care or to participate in the 10Plan. However, individuals could choose to participate at any time as long as they are in good standing with the 10Plan—that is, if they have previously deferred health care expenses through this plan, they must be current on making repay- ment premiums. How long an individual who is not in good standing would be ineligible and what would be necessary to regain eligibility have not be delineated, but we note that the implications are that these individuals would be required to pay for the full cost of care that they received. To the extent that these are low-income individuals, this may increase uncompensated care. How the 10Plan Works 7

Because the 10Plan reimbursement rates are substantially below those of other types of insurance coverage, we have assumed participa- tion will be universal among the eligible population, but we have also modeled costs assuming less than 100 percent take-up.

Health Care Utilization 10Plan participants can seek care directly from participating providers and will be responsible for a $25 copay. Services will be billed to partic- ipants at the Medicare fee-for-service (FFS) rates. Participants will then either pay the remaining balance (less the $25 copay) out of pocket or defer payment, to be deducted from paychecks at a rate based on one’s family income. There are two competing forces when assessing utilization. Because the cost of care is much lower under the 10Plan, one might expect additional consumption. Alternatively, because individuals are exposed to first-dollar costs,1 increases in consumption could be miti- gated for the population that is currently enrolled in a nongroup plan.

Repayment If 10Plan participants choose to defer payment, the visit balance would be paid to providers by CMS and the federal government would ini- tiate the automatic repayment in concert with the Internal Revenue Service (IRS) and the federal entity administering the 10Plan. This system of automatic repayment premiums shares some features with other income-based loan repayment plans. Unlike traditional insur- ance premiums, these are only paid once a 10Plan participant uses care and defers payment. Unlike a typical loan, the balance will be bundled together with other qualifying 10Plan health care expenses over the course of the year, and the repayment premiums will be capped based on family income. The 10Plan is called the “10” Plan because most participants will not pay more than 10 percent of their family’s income on repayment premiums (see Table 2.1). The 10Plan uses the Federal

1 First-dollar coverage refers to who is responsible for the up front and initial costs of care. Insurance plans with deductibles, for example, require enrollees to cover the first-dollar amounts until the deductible is met. 8 Analysis of the 10Plan

Poverty Guidelines, which several other federal programs use to deter- mine financial resources and ability to pay. These guidelines define the federal poverty level (FPL) based on a family’s modified adjusted gross income (MAGI) and the number of individuals in the family. The repayment cap within each bracket (each row in the table) will increase uniformly as income increases. This mitigates situations

Table 2.1 Repayment Premiums as Percentage of Income

Annual Repayment Maximum Percentage of Income as a Percentage Amount Range Income for Second-Lowest of FPL (in percent) Silver Plana

100–150 2–3 2.06 – 4.12

150–200 3–5.25 4.12– 6.49

200–250 5.25 –7.5 6.49–8.29

250–300 7.5–8 8.29–9.78

300–400 8–9 9.78

400–600 9–10 N/A

600–800 10–15 N/A

More than 800 15.0 N/A

NOTE: N/A = not applicable. The ranges within each bracket (row) will increase linearly, so that the repayment percentage increases proportionally within the income range. Income is defined using modified gross adjusted income. A government program like the 10Plan, which seeks to charge repayment premiums on the basis of an individual’s ability to pay, needs to define a concept of financial resources. The 10Plan will use MAGI, which is also used to determine financial eligibility for Medicaid, the Children’s Health Insurance Plan (CHIP), and premium tax credits for plans purchased through the ACA exchanges. MAGI includes adjusted gross income from an individual’s federal tax return plus foreign income, nontaxable Social Security benefits, and tax-exempt interest. Individuals who purchase a health care plan on the exchanges can use their expected income to qualify. For the 10Plan, if income is allowed to be self-attested at the time of service or payment deferral, MAGI could be approximated and reconciled at the end of the tax year using documentation similar to Form 8962 (IRS, 2020). 10Plan-eligible individuals at less than 100 percent of FPL face an annual repayment rate of 0 percent. In some states, families above 133 percent of FPL would be covered by Medicaid; we have used self-reported Medicaid coverage to exclude these families from the 10Plan target population. a 26 CFR 601.105. How the 10Plan Works 9 in which moving across an income threshold would sharply increase repayment premiums. Sharp increases would create an incentive for individuals just below a particular threshold to avoid employment changes that would increase their income and would therefore distort labor market decisions. We also show the premium cap under the ACA, which is the maximum percentage of income for the second-lowest silver plan (IRS, 2020). If the cost of an exchange plan exceeds this cap, individuals are eligible for the premium tax credit. The 10Plan maximum repayment amount is lower than these caps, but there is no cap on amounts spent on copays. However, at $25 per encounter, individuals are unlikely to reach the maximum annual limits for exchange plans, which are $8,150 for individual coverage and $16,300 for other coverage in 2020 (CMS, undated). The federal government would charge simple interest at a low rate. We assumed a 3-percent interest rate, which is slightly higher than the monthly average of the 10-year U.S. Department of the Treasury rates over the last ten years (Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, 2020), but significantly lower than the average student loan interest rate. In sensitivity runs, we assumed interest rates of 1.6 percent and 4.5 per- cent, respectively. Any outstanding deferred health care expenditures would be forgiven after 15 years of repayment premiums or enrollment in Medicare. The latter forgiveness may generate an increase in utiliza- tion as individuals approach age 65, in anticipation of having deferred payments forgiven. We discuss in Chapter Four how we expect this to change our estimates. Parents or legal guardians would be responsible for their depen- dents’ deferred payment balances until age 26. We have modeled an alternative in which we assume any deferred payments under the 10Plan from before age 26 are forgiven at age 26. As income and employment change, participation and repay- ments would also change. For example, if someone moved from a job without employer-provided coverage to one with employer-provided coverage, they would no longer be eligible for the 10Plan but would be required to continue paying any repayment balances. If someone 10 Analysis of the 10Plan became unemployed or had a reduction in income, they would be able to reduce their repayment threshold.

Implementation of Repayment Premiums The 10Plan proposes to draw payments automatically from participat- ing individuals’ paychecks, using gross salary and wage earnings to approximate earners’ MAGI as the income base. Ideally, the percent- age of income drawn would be accurate each month. In reality, there are several additional variables that need to be accurately measured to draw the right payments over the course of a year. Similar to the Advance Premium Tax Credit (APTC) for cur- rent users of ACA exchanges, 10Plan payments can be reconciled based on end-of-year tax filings that take into account the spouse’s income, other sources of cash income, and other factors (IRS, 2020). Although we have assumed that payments would be withdrawn automatically and end-of-year tax reconciliations would be made, we note that there is still a possibility of default. This may be particularly problematic for individuals who are self-employed, work multiple jobs, or have changes in income. The 10Plan specifies that default would result in ineligibility for participation, but the exact rules regarding ineligibility, regaining eligibility, and how those individuals receive care still need to be determined. When multiple expenses are accrued, the repayments for each one are collectively limited to the income percentage so that the total pay- ment for 10Plan health care does not exceed 10 percent of income for most families. The repayment premiums are applied to each expense until they are paid off or until 15 years after the expense was incurred. After 15 years, remaining balances are forgiven, and the forgiveness is not considered taxable income. Repayment is also stopped when the individual enrolls in Medicare or Medicaid. Those who age into Medicare will have any remaining deferred balances forgiven. Those who become eligible for Medicaid will have their repayments paused while covered by Medicaid, though the 15-year repayment clock would continue. In Figure 2.2, we present two simplified examples of how spend- ing could evolve under the 10Plan over a consumer’s life course. In How the 10Plan Works 11

Panel A, we show trajectories of a median-income individual with age- adjusted median health care costs while single and whose expenditures increase as the individual gets married, has a family, and ages. For sim- plicity, we have assumed the individual’s spouse is the same age (though this illustration would be similar unless there were large age differences between the spouses). We have assumed the individual’s family mem- bers have median age-adjusted health care expenditures and included health “shocks” (high-cost events) for childbirth and later in adulthood for the parents. In this example, the family would be repaying costs every year, but the total of these costs would never exceed 10 percent of family income. Panel B is the same hypothetical family, but here we have assumed a chronic health condition for one of the parents at age 36, such that his expenditures are now at the 95th percentile of the age-adjusted health care spending. In this case, the family defers significantly greater health care costs, but is still never paying more than 10 percent in repayment premiums. However, in this example, the federal government would end up forgiving a significant amount of those deferred payments by the time the high-spending individual ages into Medicare. We can consider other potential scenarios in which an individ- ual obtains private health insurance through their employer or ages into Medicare. If a family obtained private employer-sponsored insur- ance, they would still owe any remaining balances from deferred pay- ments after changing plans until those balances are repaid or age 65 is reached. For example, if one parent in Panel A became covered by employer-provided coverage at age 36, the family would simply need to make repayments of accrued amounts up until the point at which they obtained employer-provided coverage, which would include the costs of the childbirths. The 10Plan assumes children’s health care costs incurred up until age 26 will be the responsibility of their par- ents. Finally, at age 65, we have assumed that any accrued deferred payments would be forgiven as per the plan design. In the case of our median family, as shown in Panel A, this would not be a significant amount because the family would have been mostly covering expen- ditures through the repayment premiums. However, we might expect individuals to increase discretionary care utilization as they approach 12 Analysis of the 10Plan

Figure 2.2 Hypothetical Family Health Care Expenditures, Deferred Payments, and Repayments Under the 10Plan

Panel A. Median income, median health care spending

Employment and family structure changes

Married

Dollars Children in family/household

Childbirth

Single

Repayment premiums 28262422 30 38363432 40 48464442 50 58565452 60 6462 Hypothetical Age amount borrowed Panel B. Median income, median health care spending under 10Plan with high-cost health condition Income Medical Employment and family expenditures structure changes

Married

Dollars Children in family/household

Single

28262422 30 38363432 40 48464442 50 58565452 60 6462 Age How the 10Plan Works 13 age 65, in anticipation of this debt forgiveness. We discuss this more in Chapter Four, where we conduct a sensitivity test of how costs might change if we accounted for this.

Providers One key rule for providers under the 10Plan is the acceptance of reim- bursement at current Medicare FFS rates. Although the infrastructure for billing, information-sharing, and payment exists for Medicare, there are aspects of the system that would require modification. The rules, regulations, and procedures for enrollment as a Medicare pro- vider could be used to allow providers to agree to the 10Plan rules. Although we have assumed providers would participate in the 10Plan and accept Medicare rates for these patients for modeling pur- poses, the extent to which this would hold in practice is unknown. Providers may prefer not to participate, given that Medicare rates tend to be lower than commercial rates (White and Whaley, 2019), or they may prioritize commercially insured patients (resulting in increased wait times). In sensitivity analyses, which we present in Chapter Three, we have assumed higher reimbursement rates.

Comparison with Status Quo

In this section, we highlight several key differences between the 10Plan and how eligible individuals currently use and pay for health care (see Table 2.2 for a nonexhaustive list). We have noted potential challenges regarding elements of the plan that have not yet been determined that have implications for how this plan would be implemented and their effects on relevant stakeholders. As previously noted, we have assumed that other aspects of the health care market would remain unchanged for modeling purposes, providing caveats and sensitivity checks in sub- sequent chapters. We have assumed the nongroup health insurance market, including the ACA exchanges and the corresponding APTCs, would be eliminated. There have been two previous estimates of health care expendi- tures under the 10Plan. First, Shapiro and Aneja (2019) derived one- 14 Analysis of the 10Plan year estimates using aggregated statistics on spending for individuals who would participate in the 10Plan, and they suggested savings on the order of $80 billion. District Economics Group also produced estimates of health care expenditures using a dynamic microsimulation model for 10Plan-eligi- ble families, excluding families with members covered by other sources (District Economics Group, 2019). It used a different primary data source (Panel Study of Income Dynamics, whereas we used the Cur- rent Population Survey [CPS]) and made no assumptions about behav- ioral or demand responses to the 10Plan. District Economics Group found that health care expenditures for the 10Plan population would total $2.726 trillion over a 15-year period for approximately 50 mil- lion individuals. It reported that the federal cost of the deferred pay- ments, including amounts forgiven, would amount to $433.6 billion over 15 years, or $29 billion per year, on average. It estimated that the federal outlays would amount to between $94 billion and $131 billion per year. How the 10Plan Works 15 - vement from the group health gistical challenges and adminis- dividuals could opt to not partici not opt to could dividuals N/A Mo insurance market to the 10Plan occurcould without rules place. in In Lo pate and be responsible for costs on own. trative complexities in implementing and managing the 10Plan repay- ment program are likely.

• • • • Potential Challenges with the 10Plan - The 10Plan The ongroup health insurance ndividuals without cover- payment premiums in subse- payment would be auto- 5 copayment for each dividuals are essentially bor essentially are dividuals encounter All i age from another public plan or a group private plan are eligible No n APTCs no and markets $2 Re quent years that are capped on the basis of family income In rowing from the federal gov- ernment at a low interest rate Re matically deducted from pay- checks and could be paused or reduced as income or employ- ment status changes

• • • • • • - - Status Quo illion ngroup: Obtain coverage ngroup: Cost-sharing as per insured: Pay none insured: Pay full amount, tastrophic events signifi dividuals obtain loans or or obtain loans dividuals cantly increase medical debt bankruptcy.a and 28 m Un No through ACA exchange or non market group Un borrow or repayment plan with provider, default (uncom- pensated or charity care) No plan. insurance In credit in the private market with potentially high interest rates and unfavorable terms. Ca

• • • • • • • nsurance Uninsured I premiums Out-of- costs pocket Borrowing to cover costs of care Table 2.2 Overview of Status Quo Versus the 10Plan 16 Analysis of the 10Plan edicare reimbursement rates he 10Plan would increase the As M are lower than commercial rates, providers may prioritize privately insured patients. As t demand for health care, we might also expect increased wait times or access to care challenges without increases in the supply of providers.

• • Potential Challenges with the 10Plan The 10Plan The oviders participating in Pr Medicare would be required to accept Medicare FFS rates for patients.10Plan

• Status Quo oviders can decide to see Pr patients (self-pay) uninsured and whether to enroll as a Medicare provider.

• Provider participation NOTE: N/A = not applicable. a Himmelstein et al., 2009; Dobkin et al., 2018. Table 2.2—Continued CHAPTER THREE Approach

Because payments for medical expenses can be spread over multiple years in the 10Plan, it is important to model the system dynamics around medical spending, income, and family structure over a 15-year period.1 We developed a microsimulation model that tracks individu- als’ medical expenditures over time and factors that influence expendi- tures and payments.

Data and Methods

We started with the 2019 Annual Social and Economic supplement to the CPS (ASEC) (Flood et al., 2015). The CPS is a nationally rep- resentative survey with information on demographics (e.g., age, race, and sex), income (e.g., wages, salary, and other income sources), family structure (e.g., number of children in the household and mar- riage status), and health (e.g., self-reported health status and insurance source). From these data, we created a sample of individuals and fami- lies that we simulated over the 15-year period, predicting the following changes in each year:

• family structure, including marriage, births, and deaths, using births, mortality, and CPS data

1 We model the 10Plan dynamically for 15 years because this is the minimum time span required to capture deferred payment expiration.

17 18 Analysis of the 10Plan

• employment and family income, using the Panel Study of Income Dynamics (PSID) • migration, using U.S. Census Bureau projections • aging and health status, using the Medical Expenditures Panel Survey (MEPS) and Centers for Disease Control and Prevention (CDC) data • health spending using the MEPS • health insurance status, including participation in the 10Plan.

In Table 3.1, we summarize these key measures, how they are used in our model, and the data sources.

Table 3.1 Key Model Inputs and Data Sources

Inputs Model Use Data Source

Family structure Used to calculate family size and income CPS relative to FPL

Births Same as above, and used to include the National Vital cost of childbirth Statistics Births data

Death Same as above, and used to adjust cost National Vital of health care in the last year of life Statistics Deaths data

Employment status Used to predict health insurance PSID and income coverage and family-level income

Migration Used to make sure population growth Census projections matches Census projections

Health status Assigned to “good” or “bad” health MEPS, CDC each year as a function of previous health status, age, and gender. “Bad” health is either an acute condition from which someone can recover or a chronic condition from which someone does not recover

Health expenditures Imputed from MEPS and projected to MEPS grow based on health status, age, and gender

Health insurance Predicted on the basis of employment CPS, PSID status and income and previous year coverage Approach 19

To understand health care spending dynamics, we used the 2015– 2016 MEPS Panel 20 Longitudinal Data File. The 2015–2016 MEPS file contains information about an individual’s medical expenditures for a two-year period spanning 2015 and 2016. We mapped the medi- cal spending distribution from the MEPS to the CPS population to produce a comprehensive picture of income and medical spending for a single year. Once the initial distribution was produced, we updated each individual’s income, medical spending, and other characteristics to produce estimates for 15 years. The income distribution was updated using income change distributions derived from the PSID from 2006 to 2018. We used a classification and regression tree (CART)-based model,2 which is a predictive modeling approach that uses machine learning to estimate a distribution for a person’s medical spending in a year based on their demographic characteristics and spending in the prior year. Family and demographic characteristics were updated with fertility and mortality data from the CDC. Other relevant values, such as the distribution of spending for pregnancy and end-of-life care, were derived from the academic literature. For a more detailed explanation of the dynamic model, refer to Appendix B.

Key Outcomes

Our main measures of interest are health care expenditures under the status quo and the 10Plan. We calculated these at both the individ- ual and family levels and aggregated to population totals to provide ­government-level impacts. We imputed health care expenditures to individuals in the CPS based on the MEPS measure of total annual health care expenditures, which includes all direct payments for care during the year and both out-of-pocket payments and payments by

2 CART is a predictive modeling approach that identifies groups with meaningfully dis- tinct relationships between the predictor and outcome variables—in this case, demographic data and medical spending patterns. We then developed a spending model for each identified group, conditional upon a prediction of nonzero medical expenses. 20 Analysis of the 10Plan insurers.3 All expenditure amounts have been adjusted to 2019 real dollars,4 and also have been adjusted to match the National Health Expenditures Accounts (NHEA).5 In Table 3.2, we describe our approach to reporting expenditures.

Modeling Assumptions It was necessary to make several assumptions and simplifications to build a tractable model of the 10Plan. We highlight the main assump- tions in this section.

3 Payments for over-the-counter drugs and phone contacts with medical providers are not included in MEPS total expenditure estimates. Indirect payments not related to specific medical events, such as Medicaid Disproportionate Share and Medicare Direct Medical Education subsidies, also are not included. Any charges associated with uncollected liability, bad debt, and charitable care (unless provided by a public clinic or hospital) are not counted as expenditures. 4 Nominal amounts were adjusted using the CPI to convert to January 2019 real dollars. 5 NHEA are calculated using aggregate measures of provider revenue, administrative records, and other sources by the Office of the Actuary at CMS. There are well-documented differences in the NHEA estimates and the MEPS estimates of health care expenditures (see Bernard et al., 2012). The NHEA estimates include several categories of health care spending, from individual-level purchases of products and services consumed to government administrative costs and public health services. One component of the NHEA is the amount spent on personal health care (PHC), which includes out-of-pocket spending on hospital care; physician and clinical services; dental services; other professional services; other health, residential, and personal care; home health care; nursing care facilities and continuing care retirement communities; prescription drugs and other nondurable medical products; and durable medical equipment. In comparison, the MEPS estimates are based on a nationally representative survey of noninstitutionalized individuals. MEPS respondents and their pro- viders give details on health care utilization and expenditures for health care received during the year. Thus, the NHEA and MEPS estimates of health care expenditures differ for several reasons, including differences in the data and populations that were surveyed, the types of services that were counted, and how the services were categorized and excluded. The MEPS estimates exclude several types of spending, including on over-the-counter medications; other health, residential, and personal care services; grants and supplemental payments; and public health programs (see Stagnitti et al., 2018). After subtracting these expenditures from NHEA PHC estimates, the Agency for Healthcare Research and Quality estimated that the adjusted NHEA estimate of PHC was $1,718 billion in 2012, which was still $369 bil- lion more than the MEPS estimate of total health care spending ($1,351 billion). Thus, the adjusted NHEA PHC estimate was 1.27 times greater than the MEPS estimate. Approach 21

Table 3.2 Measures of Health Care Spending

Measure Status Quo 10Plan

1. Individual-level a. Total paid for health b. Amount in 1(a), total health care care under current adjusted for changes expenditures insurance status by all in prices faced payers

2. Individual-level c. Copays and coinsur- d. Copays and total out-of-pocket ance and amounts repayments costs contributed to insur- ance premiums

3. Population-level e. Sum of 1(a) for all f. Sum of 1(b) for total expenditures 10Plan-eligible all 10Plan-eligible individuals individuals

A key feature of the dynamic model is the projection of medical spending from year to year. The determinants of medical spending in this model are age group (< 19, 19–34, 35–49, 50–64), sex (male/female), health status (good/bad),6 income (continuous measure), race (White/ Black/Hispanic/Other), insurance category (Medicaid/Other Public/ Private NonGroup/Other Private/Uninsured), and medical spending in the previous year (continuous measure). We assumed a medical infla- tion rate of 5.1 percent based on projections of Medicare per capita spending through 2028 (Cubanski, Neuman, and Freed, 2019), and an interest rate or administrative fee on deferred payments of 3 percent. We adjusted the prices that the 10Plan-eligible population will face to be equivalent to Medicare rates by using average per-encounter pay- ments according to MEPS (see Appendix B for more details). However, we did not project health care expenditures at the event level in the dynamic model, so we created a composite adjustment factor for the expenditures of both the currently uninsured and previously nongroup private populations. We assumed that currently uninsured individuals were 20 percent more likely to have nonzero medical spending under the 10Plan relative to the status quo, but otherwise do not account for any price elasticity or behavioral responses to the 10Plan, except in rel-

6 Although the MEPS provides a 5-level scale of health status from Excellent to Poor, the model was not as sensitive to the 5-level scale as to the aggregated 2-level scale. 22 Analysis of the 10Plan evant sensitivity analyses (see the next section for a description of sensi- tivity analyses). We assumed that children remain in their parents’ households until age 26, at which point the entire deferred payment balance is left with the parents’ household unless there are no living parents.7 We assumed that rates of birth, death, and migration follow the Census Bureau 2017 National Population Projections Tables, in which the number of deaths for individuals under age 65 is approximated using the CDC 2019 National Vital Statistics Reports (Heron, 2019). Deferred payment balances are assumed to be forgiven upon death. We assumed that all individuals retire at age 65, and we adjusted family income according to the proportion of family income that was previously attributable to the retiring family member’s wages or salary. This assumption likely leads to an underestimation of family income in many cases, especially considering the trend toward later retire- ment and the tendency for unearned income to increase as a propor- tion of total income as individuals age. Deferred payment balances are assumed to be forgiven at age 65, and we assumed no gaming behavior or increase in utilization as individuals approach retirement except in the relevant sensitivity analysis (see the following section for a descrip- tion of sensitivity analyses). We assumed that transitions in insurance status accompany income shocks in which family income changes by 10 percent or more. We did not make any assumptions about changes in the insurance status distribution resulting from the 10Plan, and instead assigned new insurance status based on the original distribution of insurance status by income level. We assumed that all individuals eligible for the 10Plan would use it. We assigned individuals’ primary source of health insurance cov- erage for the year using a hierarchical approach to reduce potential measurement error (Call et al., 2013) from individuals reporting one type of coverage but having another (e.g., reporting a group plan, but really having Medicaid). In particular, we were concerned that indi- viduals might report that they were covered by a private plan when,

7 In this case, the deferred payment balance is forgiven. Approach 23 in reality, they were covered by a Medicaid managed care plan, which would result in us overestimating the number of 10Plan-eligible indi- viduals who would participate in the 10Plan. Although the following hierarchical assignment will mitigate this concern, there still may be reporting error. The hierarchy that we used was as follows (higher on the list means that category dominates): Medicaid/CHIP; Medicare; other public plan (not Medicare or Medicaid/CHIP); private plan on the exchange; private, nongroup off the exchange; private plan through employer or other group; and uninsured.8 We note that we have made additional refinements to this approach in our model using income and employment status to correct insurance status discrepancies as a sensitivity check (see Model 27 in Table 3.3).

Sensitivity Analyses Several aspects of the 10Plan parameters and our modeling assump- tions may have significant impact on our results. We discussed assump- tions necessary for modeling in the prior section; potential behavioral demand responses are discussed in the appendixes. In this section, we summarize the set of additional estimates we ran to test the sensitiv- ity of our results to various parameters (see Table 3.3). Model 1 is the status quo, and Model 2 is our “baseline” 10Plan model; results in Chapter Four are based on Model 2, unless otherwise noted. In Model 3, we modified the calculation of repayment rates to increase marginally instead of continuously over the income cat- egory. The 10Plan specifies that the repayment rate is calculated as a simple percentage of income with the percentage calculated on the basis of income level. In this model, the repayment rate was calculated by applying increasing rates to income in increasingly higher catego- ries, similar to a marginal tax rate system. Models 4 and 5 are the lower and upper bounds on expected elasticity or demand changes; we

8 In particular, if someone reports Medicaid coverage in any month, we assign Medicaid coverage for the year. Then, if they report Medicare in any month, we assign Medicare cover- age for the year; and so on. This approach accounts for individuals who may report multiple sources of coverage in a given month as well as addresses our concern that someone with Medicaid might misreport their coverage. 24 Analysis of the 10Plan

have assumed small/conservative and large/moderate estimates of the change in demand for health care (see Appendix A for more details). Models 6 through 11 vary the prices that the 10Plan-eligible pop- ulation would face. Models 12, 13, and 28 vary aspects of the repay- ment program, allowing for forgiveness of deferred payments at age 26 (instead of transferring to parents) and charging a higher or lower inter- est rate on deferred payment balances. Models 14 and 15 are hybrid versions of the 10Plan that include a single-payer plan for those under a certain income threshold; these versions attempt to adopt elements of other single payer plans currently being considered. Models 25 and 26 are other potential ways to lower costs—particularly for lower-income families—by reducing copayments (Model 25) and repayment caps (Model 26). The remaining models vary particular elements of our model- ing assumptions: medical inflation (Model 16), scaling of the distribu- tion of health status to match the MEPS (Model 17), allowing health care demand to increase further as individuals reach age 65 because of deferred payment forgiveness (Model 18),9 end-of-life utilization (Model 19), the relationship between health spending and mortality rates (Models 20 and 21), additional adjustments to utilization among the currently uninsured (Models 22 and 23), assuming individuals do not borrow everything after the copayment (Model 24), and insurance status assignment corrections (Model 27).

9 We linearly increased the behavioral shift from 0.13 to 0.64 (Pendzialek, Simic, and Stock, 2016). Approach 25

Table 3.3 Overview of Sensitivity Checks

Model Description

1 Status quo policies and prices

2 Baseline: Medicare prices, continuous repayment cap, no behavioral changes

Changes to Modeling Compared with Baseline

3 Marginal repayment cap

4 “Small” behavioral changes (see Appendix A)

5 “Large” behavioral changes (see Appendix A)

6 Medicaid prices

7 Medicare prices + 10%

8 Medicare prices + 50%

9 Medicare prices + 100%

10 Medicare prices + 134%

11 Medicare prices 10%

12 Deferred payments− forgiven for children at age 26 (instead of parents)

13 4.5 percent interest rate instead of 3 percent

14 Expand Medicaid up to 400 percent of FPL

15 Expand Medicaid up to 250 percent of FPL

16 4.4 percent medical inflation instead of 5.1 percent

17 No adjustments to the distribution of health status; instead, scaling to match MEPS

18 Increase utilization as individuals approach age 65

19 Utilization and spending increases prior to death only for those with chronic conditions

20 Increase the mortality scaling as a function of health spending

21 Decrease the mortality scaling as a function of health spending 26 Analysis of the 10Plan

Table 3.3—Continued

Model Description

22 Uninsured are not any more likely to have nonzero spending instead of a 20 percent increase in likelihood of nonzero spending

23 Uninsured 35 percent more likely to have nonzero spending instead of a 20 percent increase in likelihood of nonzero spending

24 Individuals do not borrow full amounts, but instead pay 115 percent of the repayment cap up front, out of pocket, in addition to copayments

25 Reduce copay to $10 for individuals with income < 400 percent of FPL

26 Reduce repayment caps for low incomea

27 Insurance status corrections to account for possible underestimation of target populationb

28 1.6 percent interest rate instead of 3 percent

a Maximum repayment caps reduced to 1 percent, 2 percent, 3 percent, and 5 percent for individuals between 100–150 percent of FPL, 150–250 percent of FPL, 250–400 percent of FPL, and 400–600 percent of FPL, respectively. See Table 2.1 for the original maximum repayment caps. b Insurance status corrections included reassigning individuals according to the following three rules: (1) correct anyone on Medicaid at or over 400 percent of FPL to have group private insurance, (2) correct anyone on Medicaid between 200–400 percent of FPL to have nongroup private insurance, and (3) correct anyone at or below 100 percent of FPL with nongroup private insurance to be uninsured. These corrections allow us to evaluate the sensitivity of the model to potential misreporting of insurance status. CHAPTER FOUR Results

In this chapter, we present results comparing status quo policies with the 10Plan using Medicare prices (Models 1 and 2, respectively) unless stated otherwise. We present results for families and individuals par- ticipating in the 10Plan, then aggregate amounts to the federal govern- ment level. In some results, we present the full 15-year trajectory, but in other cases, we present either the results as of the end of the 15th year or cumulatively summing aggregated amounts over the full period. The former results are important because they reflect the steady state of our dynamic model—the point at which all aspects of the 10Plan, including the forgiveness of deferred payment balances after 15 years, would factor into our calculations. In years prior to this, we would not have reached the point at which deferred payment balances from year 1 are forgiven and in every year after year 15, these amounts will con- tinue to be forgiven. We also present cumulative population-level estimates for our government-level analysis, whereby we calculate federal costs. In these cases, we report results over time when there are significant year-to-year changes that are important to illustrate; otherwise, we show results in the steady state (as of the end of year 15) or cumulatively over the entire 15-year period.

10Plan Participants We found that between 15 and 17 percent of the model population would participate in the 10Plan in each year of the simulation, includ-

27 28 Analysis of the 10Plan ing all individuals under 65 years of age who are currently uninsured or purchase nongroup private insurance. In Table 4.1, we show the number of 10Plan participants at the end of years 1, 5, 10, and 15, by gender, race, and age group, and by mean family income.

Family Health Care Spending In Figure 4.1, we show the distribution of annual health care expen- ditures (as defined by row 1 of Table 3.2) for families with at least one person participating in the 10Plan over the 15-year period. For each year, we show the box and whisker plot of the predicted health care expenditures for 10Plan-eligible family members under the status quo (blue) and under the 10Plan (red). The boxes represent the inter- quartile range—from the 25th to 75th percentiles—and the middle

Table 4.1 10Plan Participation at the End of Years 1, 5, 10, and 15

Year 1 Year 5 Year 10 Year 15

Number of Individuals 43.5 43.6 45.7 46.8 (millions)

% Female 50 51 50 50

% Male 50 49 50 50

% White 53 52 52 50

% Black 16 16 15 16

% Hispanic 24 24 25 26

% < 19 29 30 30 29

% 19 to 34 26 25 24 24

% 35 to 49 22 23 25 24

% 50 to 64 23 22 21 23

Mean Family Income ($ 86.8 90.5 89.7 88.0 thousands) Results 29

Figure 4.1 Distribution of Total Annual Health Care Expenditures Among 10Plan Families

35 Status quo 30 10Plan

25

20

15

10

5 Annual family health care expenditures Annual family health care

(10Plan eligibles, in thousands of dollars) 0 1413121110987654321 15 Year

NOTES: SQ = status quo. Boxes represent the interquartile range of predicted health care spending under the 10Plan, assuming Medicare prices; lines (or whiskers) represent other quartiles. Family spending includes only amounts for 10Plan-eligible members. line represents the median. The lines from each box, called whiskers, represent the other two quartiles (from 0 to 25th percentile and from 75th to 100th percentile). Note that Figure 4.1 is truncated and does not show maximums here to avoid skewing the figure (see Table C.1 for full results). Overall, median family health care expenditures under the 10Plan are not very different from predicted amounts under the status quo. In Figure 4.2, we present the predicted total individual-level expenditures (defined in row 1 of Table 3.2) under the status quo and the 10Plan. Within each bar, we show the average annual amount spent on cost-sharing (dark blue) and the average annual amount spent on premiums (light blue). Under the status quo, there are no insurance premiums for those currently uninsured, but for those currently cov- ered by a nongroup plan, these are the average annual insurance pre- mium contributions. Under the 10Plan, the premiums are the average 30 Analysis of the 10Plan

Figure 4.2 Mean Individual Annual Health Care Expenditures as of Year 15, by Current Health Insurance Status

OOP: Copays and cost-sharing Covered by other payers OOP: Premiums Amounts to defer under 10Plan

10 9,287 8,968 9

8 7,274 7,313 7 6,285 5,977 6

5

4 6,013 3 (65%) 2 2,748 (38%) 1 1,174 1,783 1,405 (19%) (20%) (19%) Annual expenditures (in thousands of dollars) Annual expenditures 687 (11%) 0 SQ 10Plan SQ 10Plan SQ 10Plan Uninsured Nongroup plan All 10Plan participants

NOTE: SQ = status quo, which is projected spending assuming no 10Plan and a medical inflation rate of 5.1 percent. Each bar reflects total annual health care expenditures as defined in row 1 of Table 3.2. The dark blue sections reflect out-of-pocket (OOP) spending on copays and cost-sharing (row 2 of Table 3.2). The light blue sections reflect spending on premiums or repayment premiums (row 3 of Table 3.2). The green sections reflect amounts covered by other payers under the status quo, and amounts deferred under the 10Plan. N = 46.8 million participants (28.8 million currently uninsured and 18 million currently covered by a nongroup plan). annual repayment premiums from payments deferred in earlier years. The green parts of the bars reflect amounts that are currently covered by other payers under the status quo, such as worker’s compensation and other amounts covered by employers or by charity care (or written off). The purple segments represent the fraction of health care spend- ing that would be deferred under the 10Plan. Results 31

Overall, we predict that total individual health care spending per year will be similar under both the status quo and the 10Plan, but out- of-pocket costs would be $1,343 lower under the 10Plan (see the two bars on the far right in Figure 4.2). We also found significant differences by current health insurance status. For those currently uninsured, our model predicted total health spending per year to be about $308 higher under the 10Plan, on aver- age ($6,285 versus $5,977). This would translate into an increase in out-of-pocket spending (blue-shaded segments of bars) of $487 for the uninsured. For those currently covered by a nongroup plan, our model predicted that total annual health care spending would be $319 lower under the 10Plan ($8,968 versus $9,287) relative to the status quo. The out-of-pocket spending is predicted to be $4,230 less per year ($1,783 versus $6,013), on average for these individuals under the 10Plan. We also break out predicted total health care expenditures by the health status of 10Plan-eligible individuals (see Figure 4.3). Health is defined as good health and bad health, where bad reflects either an acute condition (from which someone can recover) or a chronic condi- tion. We used the average amount currently paid for nongroup health insurance premiums inflated to year 15 in the out-of-pocket calcula- tions for the status quo. These health insurance premiums may vary by health status, but we have assumed the same average across all three health states (good health, bad health with an acute condition, and bad health with a chronic condition). Overall, average total annual expenditures in Year 15 will be about $144 more for individuals in good health. However, those in good health are predicted to spend $3,078 per year in cost-sharing and health insurance premiums under the status quo. This means that some of the amount they pay in pre- miums is being used to offset the costs of care of less-healthy enroll- ees. Those in good health would have $991 in out-of-pocket costs per year under the 10Plan, a savings of $2,087 per year. Those with acute and chronic conditions will have about $27 and $103 less in average total health care expenditures per year, respectively, under the 10Plan relative to the status quo. Out-of-pocket costs will fall significantly for those with an acute and chronic condition, as well, by $1,368 and $1,213, respectively. 32 Analysis of the 10Plan

Figure 4.3 Change in Mean Total Annual Health Care Expenditures in Year 15, by Health Status

OOP: Copays and cost-sharing Covered by other payers OOP: Premiums Amounts to defer under 10Plan

16

14 13,557 13,453

12 11,720 11,693

10

8

6

4 2,530 2,674 2 3,078 3,139 3,185 1,821 1,945 } 991 0 Annual expenditures (in thousands of dollars) Annual expenditures –2 SQ 10Plan SQ 10Plan SQ 10Plan Good health Acute condition Chronic condition

NOTE: SQ = status quo, which is projected assuming there is no 10Plan and a medical in ation rate of 5.1 percent. N = 46.8 million participants.

Repayments and Copays In Figure 4.4, we show the total population-level aggregate amounts (as defined by row 3 of Table 3.2, summed across all 10Plan participants) predicted to be spent on out-of-pocket costs under the status quo (blue bars) and the 10Plan (red bars). For each year, we predicted the aggre- gated amounts that would be spent on cost-sharing (dark blue bar) and health insurance premiums (light blue bar) under the status quo. We inflated health insurance premiums using a 5.1 percent medical inflation rate to be consistent with other inflation adjustments in the model. The dark red bars reflect the aggregated amounts predicted to be spent on copayments under the 10Plan, and the light red bars reflect aggregated repayment premiums. On average, 10Plan participants are Results 33

Figure 4.4 Population Totals of Out-of-Pocket Health Care Expenditures

160 10Plan copays 149 10Plan repayment premiums 142 140 135 SQ cost-sharing 129 123 SQ insurance premiums 118 120 112 107 102 97 100 93 89 82 86 80 78 66 60 63 60 53 54 57 49 50 43 46 39 40 40 35 29 20 18 Total population-level out-of-pocket Total 0

health care expenditures (in billions of dollars) expenditures health care 1413121110987654321 15 Year

NOTES: SQ = status quo, which is projected spending assuming there is no 10Plan and a medical in ation rate of 5.1 percent. N = 46.8 million participants. predicted to spend $63 billion less per year in out-of-pocket spending under the 10Plan relative to the status quo, or $940 billion less over the 15-year period. Another way to examine a family’s burden under the 10Plan is to examine the fraction of income that would be spent on health care. Under the 10Plan, families are responsible for paying a $25 copayment for each health care interaction (including visits and prescriptions) in addition to a repayment premium toward the deferred payment bal- ance from previous years’ health interactions, if nonzero. The required annual repayment premium is capped at a percentage of family income that depends on the family’s income as a percentage of FPL. Thus, the range of repayments for each cohort will fall between 0 and the annual repayment cap, given in Table 2.1. In Figure 4.5, we show the median effective repayment rate (blue bar) and total payment rate (repayment premium plus copay- ment, shown in the red bar) as a percentage of family income in year 34 Analysis of the 10Plan

Figure 4.5 Median Effective Repayment Premium Rate and Total Payment Rate as a Percentage of Family Income in Year 15, by FPL Category

16 Repayment premium 14 Total payment 12 Maximum cap SQ—uninsured 10 SQ—nongroup 8

6

Percentage of families Percentage 4

2

0 100–150 150–250 250–400 400–600 600–800 800+ Family income as a percentage of FPL

NOTES: SQ = status quo. Total payment includes both repayment premiums and copayments. We do not show the effective repayment premium rate or total payment rate for the population with family income below 100 percent of FPL because the repayment cap at this level is 0 percent. N = 46.8 million participants (28.8 million currently uninsured and 18 million currently covered by a nongroup plan.)

15, compared with the maximum annual repayment cap (purple line). These metrics account for utilization levels, amounts forgiven, and the median percentage of income actually paid by families. The lowest income families (< 250% of FPL) will effectively pay between 3 and 4 percent of income toward the cost of health care for 10Plan participants (including copayments and repayment premiums). The highest-income families will effectively pay less than 1 percent of their income toward the cost of health care for 10Plan participants. For comparison, we also show the median percentage of income that individuals currently pay for out-of-pocket health care expenses (the triangle represents those who are currently uninsured, and the square represents those who are currently covered by a nongroup plan). Results 35

Figure 4.6 Percentage of 10Plan Families Paying Maximum Repayment Cap in Year 15, by FPL Category

60 54 50

40 39

30 25

20 17

10 9 Percentage of 10Plan families Percentage

1 0 100–150 150–250 250–400 400–600 600–800 800+ Family income as a percentage of FPL

NOTE: 10Plan families are families with at least one 10Plan-eligible member. We do not show the effective repayment premium rate or total payment rate for the population with the family income below 100 percent of FPL because the repayment cap at this level is 0 percent. N = 46.8 million participants.

When we consider the percentage of 10Plan households at each income level that pay the maximum repayment rate (Figure 4.6), we see that these families are primarily lower-income households. This is consistent with the findings illustrated in Figure 4.5. Over 50 percent of households with at least one 10Plan-eligible member and income between 100 and 150 percent of FPL pay at the maximum repayment cap in year 15. This percentage drops as income level increases.

Government-Level Analysis In this section, we report details on population-level changes in health care spending among 10Plan participants; amounts that would be for- given because of expiration, death, or age; predicted effects on the fed- eral budget; and a set of sensitivity results. 36 Analysis of the 10Plan

Total Health Care Expenditures Among 10Plan Participants Over the 15-year period, we predicted total health care spending (not including administrative costs) under the status quo to be about $3.57 trillion relative to $3.53 trillion under the 10Plan. This amounts to about $33 billion in reduced total health care spending over the 15-year period because of lower prices, or about $2.18 billion less in spending per year. We do not know how much is currently spent on administra- tive costs under the status quo from the data we used, but other stud- ies have estimated administrative costs at between 12 and 22 percent of net premiums earned (which are essentially premiums paid in, less claims paid out) (Hall, McCue, and Palazzolo, 2018; McCue, Hall, and Liu, 2013; Snyder and Rudowitz, 2015). Administrative costs were 10.4 percent for Medicaid enrollees in 2017 (Snyder and Rudowitz, 2015; Wolfe, Rennie, and Truffer, 2017). Estimates of the administrative costs for Medicare vary depending on whether they include administrative expenses incurred by the insur- ance companies managing the Medicare Advantage and Part D plans, and range from 1.4 to 6 percent. Under the status quo, insurers are required to spend 80 percent of amounts collected in premiums (actu- arially) on health care expenditures (Berwick and Johnson, 2019): This means that not more than 20 percent should go to cover insurer administrative and overhead costs. In Figure 4.7, we show 15-year cumulative totals of population- level health care expenditures and estimated administrative costs under the status quo and 10Plan. We assumed administrative costs under the status quo of 20 percent of health care expenditures not covered by the family. We separately assumed 5, 10, and 20 percent of the amounts that would be borrowed (repayment premiums) under the 10Plan as the administrative costs. If the 10Plan is able to achieve administrative costs at 5 percent, the 10Plan would yield an additional $147 billion in savings from lower administrative costs, respectively. However, with 10 or 20 percent administrative costs, the 10Plan would be more expen- sive to administer than the current nongroup plans. Our preferred assumption regarding 10Plan administrative costs is that they will be 10 percent of deferred payments. Although this is Results 37

Figure 4.7 15-Year Total Population Health Care Expenditures Plus Administrative Costs

Population total health expenditures 4,500 Administrative costs 4,000 632 305 316 3,500 158

3,000

2,500

2,000 3,566 3,533 3,533 3,533 1,500

1,000

500 15-year population totals (in billions) 0 SQ 10Plan + 10Plan + 10Plan + 5% loan costs 10% loan costs 20% loan costs

NOTES: SQ = status quo. The population total health expenditures refer to row 3 in Table 3.2. Administrative costs under the status quo are calculated as 20 percent of the total population health expenditures, less amounts that families pay out of pocket. Administrative costs under the 10Plan are equal to 5, 10, or 20 percent of the amount of deferred payments that the federal government will lend out. greater than the 5 percent assumed by Shapiro and Aneja (2019), it is similar to recent estimates of administrative costs for Medicaid enroll- ees (10.4 percent) (Holahan and McMorrow, 2019). Thus, our model suggests that the 10Plan will result in savings of $33 billion from lower prices but would increase administrative costs by $11 billion over the 15-year period (net savings of $21.5 billion total). This amounts to around $1.4 billion in savings per year, assuming Medicare prices and no behavioral changes in demand for health care.

Forgiveness of Deferred Payment Balances Deferred payment balances are forgiven for any of the following four reasons: the balance expires after 15 years, an individual dies, an indi- vidual turns 65 and rolls into Medicare, or an individual without living parents turns 26. Note that we generally assumed that the balances of 38 Analysis of the 10Plan

Table 4.2 Deferred Payment Balances Forgiven by the Government, Stratified by Reason for Forgiveness by Year, in Billions of Dollars

Year 1 5 10 15

Total Forgiven 6.3 14.5 17.6 29.0

Forgiven due to 0 0 0 0.1 expiration

Forgiven due to 3.5 8.6 13.4 23.6 death

Forgiven at age 2.1 3.3 3.0 4.7 65

Forgiven at age 0.7 2.7 1.2 0.6 26

NOTE: Values are rounded to the nearest $100 million and are not cumulative.

26-year-olds are left with their parents, but in cases in which a 26-year- old is predicted to have no living parents, we assumed balances were forgiven.1 Table 4.2 shows that forgiveness due to death accounts for by far the largest share of total balances forgiven.

Federal Budgetary Effects To evaluate the 10Plan’s impact on government spending, we evaluated the projected outlays and revenue associated with the 10Plan, shown in Table 4.3. Government outlays include deferred payments, which can be compared with the government’s current spending on APTCs, and administrative costs.2 The Congressional Budget Office (CBO) provides projections for marketplace-related APTC outlays from 2019 to 2029, which we extended an additional four years (Fritzsche, McNel- lis, and Vreeland, 2019). Revenue consists only of repayment premiums

1 We also conducted a sensitivity analysis in which the balances of all 26-year-olds are com- pletely forgiven rather than left with the parents. 2 The 10-year calculations are also provided to match the CBO baseline projections, but we note that because the plan does not reach the steady state until year 15, our preference is to focus on 15-year results. Results 39 a (CBO) $12.45 $176.65 $672.00 − − $1,271.15 $1,271.15 $1,766.50 $1,283.60 $1,283.60 $1,283.60 10-Year Total Total 10-Year Period $16.92 $316.11 − $3,161.09 $1,089.00 $2,405.12 $2,405.12 $2,405.12 $2,388.20 $2,388.20 − Total over 15-Year overTotal 15-Year 46.80 $3.08 $0.00 $87.75 $31.09 $251.20 $251.20 $251.20 $310.94 $254.29 $254.29 − 45.73 $0.00 $13.41 $77.00 $23.23 $191.91 $191.91 $191.91 $178.49 $178.49 $232.27 − − 43.61 $0.00 $16.71 $18.85 $65.00 $137.66 $137.66 $137.66 $167.10 $118.81 $118.81 − − 43.47 $0.00 $0.00 $0.00 $0.00 Year 1Year 5 Year 10 Year 15 Year $13.18 $62.00 $83.02 $83.02 $83.02 $131.83 −

Deferred payments Deferred APTC Administrative costs Net effect Net Revenue Tax effects Tax Total Outlays Total premiums Repayment The 10-year calculations are also provided to match the CBO baseline projections, but we note that because the plan does not Outlays Budget effectBudget Revenue Number of 10Plan participants (in millions) Table 4.3 Table Effect of the 10Plan on Government Spending, in Billions of Dollars a reach the steady state until year our 15, preference is to focus on 15-year results. NOTES: APTC amounts include all “Marketplace-Related Coverage and the Basic Health Program” expenditures. APTC 15 Year projections are linearly extrapolated from CBO estimates (Fritzsche and Masi, Administrative 2016). costs are estimated at 10 payments. deferred of percent 40 Analysis of the 10Plan paid toward 10Plan participants’ deferred payment balances each year because there is no effect on tax revenue. Although we do not know what the administrative costs of the 10Plan would be, we used 10 per- cent of deferred payments as an estimate for these administrative costs. Our federal budgetary analysis suggests that the federal costs will be the highest in the first two years of 10Plan implementation, but will decline as deferred payments are repaid. Then, once the first set of deferred payments (from year 1) are forgiven at the end of year 15, we expect the 10Plan to cost the federal government about $3 billion per year. Still, we estimated that the federal government would need about $83 billion for the 10Plan program in year 1. The current plan does not include a plan to raise revenues to cover these costs. Over the 15-year period, we predicted the net effect on federal spending will be a decrease of almost $17 billion. As year 15 is the first year in which the first set of deferred payments will be forgiven, the accounting in this year gives the best estimate of what the budgetary effect will be over the longer term. Thus, although we found govern- ment savings over the entire 15-year period, those are likely not sus- tainable. In the event that there are savings from federal spending on the 10Plan population, those savings can be used in several ways, such as reducing out-of-pocket costs for the lowest-income families, invest- ment in medical education scholarships, or covering additional cost- effective treatments with no cost-sharing.

Sensitivity Analyses We tested several versions of the dynamic microsimulation varying dif- ferent aspects of the assumptions in isolation.3 In Table 4.4, we present the results from these additional runs focusing on the 15-year totals of health care expenditures for all 10Plan-eligible individuals, estimated administrative costs, the comparison to the status quo, and the net effect on federal spending. Our estimates of the change in total health care spending relative to the status quo are most sensitive to the price levels that 10Plan-eligi-

3 Importantly, we varied assumptions one at a time. In reality, there may be interactive effects between many of the policy features and parameters considered here. Results 41 ble families and individuals will face, and less sensitive to the parame- ters and policy features tested in the other sensitivity analyses. In other words, the prices that we assume that 10Plan participants would face are the most significant factor in determining whether the 10Plan will generate savings. Assuming Medicare prices, as we did for most of the results presented, our model suggests savings of $21.5 billion over 15 years, including administrative costs of 10 percent. However, if 10Plan participants face rates that are 234 percent that of Medicare, as the state of Montana was able to negotiate with hospitals (Appleby, 2018; Liang, Beydoun, and Eid, 2019) then we predicted increases in health care expenditures of $1,236 billion over 15 years (see Model 10). Even though Montana hospitals may not be representative of all hospitals in the United States, we expect getting hospitals to (systematically) accept rates lower than those of Montana hospitals may be difficult. Forgiveness of loan balances at age 65 is another modeling assump- tion that predicts whether the10Plan saves money. In our main model, we did not assume any behavioral responses from this, but 10Plan participants would have an incentive to increase their consumption of health care (especially discretionary health care) as they approach age 65, especially at age 64. In particular, knowing that they would not have to repay costs in subsequent years may affect their behavior. In one sensitivity check, we increased health care utilization linearly from ages 51 to 64 to account for this. In this model, we estimated that the 10Plan, with Medicare prices, would increase total expenditures by $659 billion over 15 years (see Model 18). Using a marginal repayment rate calculation (similar to the way that income tax brackets are applied, in which the repayment rate on the next dollar of income increases) would yield lower repayment pre- miums (and hence, greater costs to the federal government) than using a continuous cap as we assumed (comparing Model 2 with Model 3) but would not change the overall total health care expenditures. Varying our assumptions about demand elasticities changed our estimates. If we assumed smaller changes in demand (see Appendix A), we still found savings, though to a slightly lesser degree than in our baseline estimates (compare Model 2 with Model 4). However, assum- ing larger changes in demand resulted in increased spending relative to 42 Analysis of the 10Plan the status quo, such that total costs would be about $19 billion higher than under the status quo (Model 5). In Models 12, 13, and 28, we varied aspects of the repayment pro- gram. Forgiving the deferred payment balances of all children at age 26 (as opposed to transferring remaining balances to parents) would cost the federal government an additional $46 billion over the 15 years rela- tive to the status quo (Model 12). Charging a higher interest rate of 4.5 percent instead of 3 percent would reduce federal costs by about $70 billion over the 15-year period (Model 13). Charging a lower interest rate of 1.6 percent, which is the current ten-year Treasury rate, would increase federal costs to $31 billion over the 15-year period (Model 28). Models 14 and 15 are hybrid programs combining the 10Plan with an expansion of Medicaid. These models do not include the amount of federal funding that would be required to cover new Medic- aid enrollees. The CBO projects that Medicaid spending will be about $549 billion in 2029 and would cover 64 million beneficiaries. Model 14 would expand coverage to an additional 126 million individuals by 2029, increasing Medicaid spending to $1.42 trillion. We predicted that Medicaid enrollment would increase by about $129 million as of year 15 ($125 million as of 2029), and Medicaid spending would increase to $2.10 trillion as of year 15 (or $1.429 trillion as of year 2029). For comparison with the CBO budget projections, this would be an additional $1.39 trillion in Medicaid spending as of year 15 (or $870 billion in Medicaid spending as of 2029). This amount would cover 129 million individuals with incomes up to 400 percent of FPL, and almost eight million under the 10Plan. These estimates suggest lower total health care costs for the target group (uninsured and non- group private) relative to the status quo. Models 25 and 26 are additional alternative approaches to the 10Plan that could potentially lower family costs, particularly for lower- income families. Model 25 assumes lower copayments for families under 400 percent of FPL, but they would still face the same repay- ment rules; this increased the predicted federal costs by $42 billion over the 15 years. Similarly, reducing the repayment caps would reduce revenue and thus increase federal costs by about $144 billion over the 15 years. Results 43

Changing the following modeling assumptions resulted in greater savings: lower medical inflation (Model 16), inflating end-of-life costs only for those with chronic conditions (Model 19), scaling down the mortality factor (Model 20), increasing the amount that families will pay by an additional 115 percent of their repayment cap up front (and thus reducing the amount borrowed; Model 24), and making addi- tional adjustments to health insurance status (Model 27). The results of other sensitivity analyses on our modeling assump- tions still tend to predict higher total health care expenditures under the 10Plan, similar to Model 2. In summary, our estimates of the change in total health care spending relative to the status quo are most sensitive to price levels that 10Plan-eligible families and individuals will face, and less sensitive to the parameters and policy features tested in the other sensitivity analy- ses. The price level element of the 10Plan matters significantly: Assum- ing Medicare rates yields an estimated $21.5 billion decrease in total health care expenditures (including administrative costs) over the 15 years, but assuming 234 percent of Medicare rates yields an estimated increase of $1,263 billion in total health care expenditures relative to the status quo. Using Medicare prices would net the federal govern- ment $17 billion over the 15 years, but using 234 percent of Medicare would cost the federal government an additional $566 billion.

Discussion Our model estimates $3.53 trillion in total annual spending by 10Plan participants summed over the 15-year period, after adjusting prices to Medicare levels and not accounting for changes in demand. This amount is almost $33 billion less than we predicted under the status quo. Our estimate with no demand change is about $39 billion higher than District Economic Group’s estimates of health care spending over the 15-year period, $3.146 trillion under the 10Plan (they do not pres- ent the counterfactual). If under the status quo, administrative costs are around 20 per- cent (Hall, McCue, and Palazzolo, 2018) and if the 10Plan can achieve administrative costs on par with Medicaid (at approximately 10 per- 44 Analysis of the 10Plan $8 $11 $17 $39 $23 − $213 $416 $341 − − − Spending Net Effect on Federal $1 $15 $19 $21 $21 $509 $985 $832 − − − − Status Quo Difference from from Difference Total $3,871 $3,039 $3,872 $3,856 $3,849 $3,849 $3,889 $4,380 $317 $319 $316 $316 $247 $320 $362 $305 $404 $4,856 Estimated Administrative Costs $2,792 $4,017 $3,553 $3,570 $3,533 $3,533 $3,539 $3,566 $4,452 Total 10PlanTotal Population Health Care Expenditures dicare prices,dicare demand no dicare prices,dicare demand no dicare prices, small prices, dicare large dicaid prices, demanddicaid no dicare prices, + 10% no dicare + 50% prices, no dicare + 100% prices, no tus quo changes Sta Me repaymentchanges, marginal cap Me demand changes demand changes Me Me changes demand changes demand changes demand changes Me Me Me Me

Table 4.4 Table Sensitivity Analyses, Estimated Spending Period, and Total Across 15 in Billions in Year 15-Year of Dollars 2. 3. Model 1. 4. 5. 9. 6. 8. 7. Results 45 $70 $65 $50 $30 $46 $618 $566 $663 − − − − − Spending Net Effect on Federal $11 $21 $21 $46 $157 − − − − − $2,157 $1,263 Status Quo $2,809 − − Difference from from Difference Total $1,714 $5,133 $3,714 $1,062 $3,825 $3,849 $3,849 $3,860 $89 $141 $317 $314 $316 $316 $427 $306 Estimated Administrative Costs $973 $3,511 $1,573 $4,707 $3,533 $3,533 $3,543 $3,408 Total 10PlanTotal Population Health Care Expenditures del 2 with forgiveness of del 2 with higher del 2 with lower rate of del 2 with no adjustments dicare +134% prices,dicare no +134% dicare −10% prices,dicare −10% no brid 10Plan with Medicaid brid 10Plan with Medicaid demand changes Me demand changes Me Mo deferred payments of all chil- dren at age 26 Mo interest(4.5%) on deferred payments Hy expansion for all under 400 percent FPL of Hy expansion for all under 250 percent FPL of Mo medical inflation Mo to distribution of health status

Table 4.4—ContinuedTable Model 10. 11. 12. 13. 14. 15. 16. 17. 46 Analysis of the 10Plan $19 $27 $25 $40 -$17 $528 $323 − − − − − Spending Net Effect on Federal $21 $21 $25 $32 $47 $197 $659 − − − − − − Status Quo Difference from from Difference Total $3,674 $3,824 $4,530 $3,838 $3,849 $3,849 $3,846 $141 $315 $314 $316 $316 $316 $378 Estimated Administrative Costs $4,152 $3,510 $3,533 $3,533 $3,533 $3,523 $3,530 Total 10PlanTotal Population Health Care Expenditures del 2 with demand for del 2 with end-of-life del 2 with deflation of del 2 with inflation of del 2 with no adjustment del 2 with larger adjust- del 2 with individuals bor- Mo health care increasing as indi- approach retirement viduals Mo health care consumption inflated only for those with conditions health chronic Mo mortality scaling factor Mo mortality scaling factor Mo of consumption of currently population uninsured Mo ment of consumption of cur- rently uninsured population Mo rowing above 115% of theirrowing above 115% repayment cap (i.e., paying of their repayment115% cap up front, out of pocket, in copayments) to addition

Table 4.4—ContinuedTable Model 18. 19. 20. 21. 22. 23. 24. Results 47 $31 $35 $42 $144 − Spending Net Effect on Federal $5 $21 $21 $33 − − − − Status Quo Difference from from Difference Total $3,849 $3,865 $3,838 $3,849 $316 $315 $316 $332 Estimated Administrative Costs $3,533 $3,533 $3,533 $3,522 Total 10PlanTotal Population Health Care Expenditures del 2 with reduced copay del 2 with reduced repay- del 2 with insurance cat- del 2 with lower (1.6%) del 2 with lower (1.6%) Mo for all under($10) 400 per- FPLcent of Mo ment caps Mo egory corrections Mo interest on deferred payments

26. Model 25. 27. 28. NOTES: The analysis in this chapter is for Model 2, unless otherwise stated. See 3.3 Table for more details on these different models and sensitivity tests. Table 4.4—ContinuedTable 48 Analysis of the 10Plan cent), administrative costs would increase by about $11 billion over the 15-year period. Our estimated net cash flow, assuming 10 percent administrative costs, suggests that the federal government would need as much as $83 billion in year 1 (under Model 2), but only $3 billion per year as of year 15 (when the first set of deferred payment balances would be forgiven). Our amounts have subtracted what the federal government would have spent on APTC subsidies, which would no longer exist (CMS, 2019). We have assumed that individuals who are currently covered by an employer-sponsored plan would keep their plan; but, as noted, this is an unrealistic expectation. Although our dynamic model allows movement into and out of the 10Plan from year to year, we have main- tained the distribution of individuals in the private group market as constant over the 15-year period. On the one hand, greater participa- tion in the 10Plan would drive up the federal cost of providing deferred payment up front. On the other hand, it is difficult to predict what would happen more broadly in the health care market. Perhaps, this movement would put downward pressure on commercial prices. Alter- natively, an increase in the demand for health care that we predict under the 10Plan, more broadly, without a corresponding change in supply, may put upward pressure on prices or result in increased wait- ing or decreased access. The 10Plan effectively caps out-of-pocket costs for those who are 10Plan-eligible. For the population below 400 percent of FPL, indi- viduals typically spend 3 to 4 percent of their income on health care. For higher-income groups, the share of income is typically lower. This implies that, despite the progressivity of the required repayment rates, the 10Plan is slightly regressive in practice. However, from a financial risk standpoint, the lower-income groups have lower cost variability than they may have under the status quo. CHAPTER FIVE Conclusion

Overall, we predicted a decline in total health care spending among 10Plan participants of almost $33 billion over a 15-year period. The results stems largely from lower prices (assuming Medicare rates). Assuming that the 10Plan can lower administrative costs to 10 per- cent of the amount of deferred payments or loans, administrative costs would increase by $11 billion over the 15-year period, relative to the status quo. Together, these amount to savings of $21.5 billion total over 15 years, or about $1.4 billion per year. Under more-costly assump- tions, we predicted federal spending to increase by around $38 bil- lion per year, which is significantly less than estimates of $2 trillion to $3 trillion per year needed under Medicare for All proposals (Ber- wick and Johnson, 2019; Committee for a Responsible Federal Budget, 2019). However, there are important aspects of our modeling assump- tions that can change these estimates such that the 10Plan will increase total health care expenditures. First, the assumption that 10Plan partici- pants will pay Medicare rates is critical. Lowering the prices that this population faces matters significantly. The feasibility of implementing these lower rates, however, is unclear. Second, as deferred payment (or loan) balances are forgiven at age 65, increasing health care utiliza- tion as individuals approach age 65 changes our results significantly. In this case, we predicted that the 10Plan would increase costs over the 15-year period. On average, individuals covered by the 10Plan will spend less on health care and have lower out-of-pocket costs when compared with

49 50 Analysis of the 10Plan the status quo. However, this varies by family income, current health insurance status, and health status. Lower-income families will pay about 3 to 4 percent of their income on repayments and copayments, which is more than what uninsured individuals in those income cate- gories currently pay out of pocket for health care. In general, uninsured individuals will face greater out-of-pocket health care costs under the 10Plan, regardless of income. On the other hand, under the 10Plan, these individuals gain risk protection against large, unexpected medi- cal bills. They will not be required to pay more than their means-tested rate in any given year, excluding copayments. The 10Plan also pro- vides this risk protection to everyone not covered by a public or pri- vate health insurance plan, whereas currently there are approximately 28 million people without any risk protection from health insurance. Higher-income individuals currently covered by a nongroup plan (with incomes above 400 percent of FPL) will pay less out of pocket, as they will have no insurance premiums. Lower-income individuals will pay a higher percentage of income on health care, however. We also found differences in the changes in predicted health care expenditures by health status, with those who are in good health expe- riencing increases and those with chronic or acute conditions experi- encing decreases in expenditures. One potential concern about the 10Plan: In eliminating the non- group health insurance market, those currently covered by a nongroup plan will lose the risk protection they have through an insurance plan. However, the ability to defer payments under the 10Plan and make means-tested repayments over time provides similar risk protection to paying premiums on a nongroup plan and having limited cost-­sharing. Under the latter arrangement, someone could incur large health care expenses in one year, pay their maximum in cost-­sharing, and then drop coverage, whereas under the 10Plan, the individual could be making repayments on that high-cost event for up to 15 years. Fur- thermore, for those in the highest-income groups covered by 10Plan, 10Plan may provide less risk protection than insurance. In our model- ing, we are not able to determine the extent to which risk protection changes beyond comparing predicted out-of-pocket costs for 10Plan families under the status quo with such costs under the 10Plan. Conclusion 51

The 10Plan would change the federal government’s cash flow. In particular, the government would increase outlays to cover individuals’ health care spending up front and then receive repayment premiums to cover these amounts in subsequent years. Some amounts would be forgiven after 15 years or as individuals age into Medicare. However, as noted previously, increased utilization may yield longer-term improve- ments in health, and the 10Plan would essentially facilitate low-interest loans for individuals who may not be able to obtain credit otherwise or would have to pay significantly higher interest.

Limitations and Caveats

As noted throughout the report, there are several limitations to our estimates that should be considered when interpreting our results. In this section, we briefly review these limitations to remind readers that all interpretations of our findings should be caveated with these assumptions.

Plan Implementation Implementation of the 10Plan would likely require significant logistical and infrastructure changes that we have not included in our cost esti- mates. Convincing providers to agree to participate and accept Medi- care rates may be politically challenging or even infeasible. Although CMS could require providers that currently accept Medicare benefi- ciaries as patients to accept 10Plan participants, providers may not be willing to do this. Currently, the 10Plan does not have specific rules that would compel participation. Even with provider buy-in, some elements of Medicare reimburse- ment would be difficult to translate to the 10Plan. For example, hos- pitals are currently reimbursed by Medicare using the inpatient pro- spective payment system, which calculates payments for a particular discharge based on the patient’s Medicare-Severity Diagnosis-Related Group and attributes of the hospital (i.e., whether it provides medical education, local wages). Payment can also be reduced if a patient is readmitted. The extent to which these payment systems could be used 52 Analysis of the 10Plan to bill individuals using the 10Plan is unclear. For modeling purposes, we have just scaled expenditures down to the Medicare average, but how this would work in practice would need to be decided. We have not estimated the costs of 10Plan administration (which would include enrollment of providers, processing of bills and repay- ment premiums, and fraud management), but instead have presented a range of what those costs would be, given total population-level health care spending (between 5 and 20 percent). In our federal budgetary cash flow analysis, we have assumed administrative costs of 10 percent of deferred payments, which is greater than the 5 percent assumed by Shapiro and Aneja (2019) but on par with recent estimates of admin- istrative costs for Medicaid enrollees, at 10.4 percent (Holahan and McMorrow, 2019). Although we have assumed that payments would be withdrawn automatically and end-of-year tax reconciliations would be made, we note that there is still a possibility of default. This may be particularly problematic for individuals who are self-employed, work multiple jobs, or have changes in income. The 10Plan specifies that default would result in ineligibility, but the exact rules regarding ineligibility, regain- ing eligibility, and how those individuals would receive care still need to be determined. We have not estimated how many individuals would potentially default. There are also several other aspects of plan implementation that still need to be decided, including how to handle undocumented individuals,1 family structure dynamics, how to prevent migration from other health insurance sources, and other behavioral responses that could negatively affect the sustainability of the plan. There may also be benefits to the federal government from providing administra- tive services for a wider segment of the population, such as a potential increase in bargaining power in setting prices, and additional data to analyze outcomes of care, fraud, and areas in which savings may be achieved. For example, CMS currently makes additional payments to qualifying hospitals that serve a large number of Medicaid and unin- sured individuals that are known as Disproportionate Share Hospital

1 See Appendix B for our sampling strategy, which does not exclude these individuals. Conclusion 53 payments. To the extent that the 10Plan eliminates those who are tech- nically without coverage, the amounts that hospitals spend on uncom- pensated and charity care may decline.

Modeling It was necessary to make several assumptions to model the costs of the 10Plan, either because of complexity, a lack of appropriate data, or uncertainty regarding the effects of the 10Plan on the health care system. Although we have endeavored to provide several estimates to demonstrate the sensitivity of our results to these assumptions, we acknowledge that we were not able to capture all sources of uncer- tainty in our results. We note that implementation of the 10Plan would be a significant change to the current health care delivery landscape in the United States. Therefore, there may be additional effects that we are not anticipating and have not accounted for that could change our estimates. We review several of our key assumptions in the following paragraphs. First, we note that there are both potential advantages and disad- vantages to the 10Plan—that we have not modeled—that are impor- tant to consider in light of our estimates. As discussed in the prior section, the 10Plan offers risk protection for both those currently pur- chasing a plan in the nongroup health insurance market and those who are uninsured. Currently, those without insurance are less likely to receive regular or preventive care and are less likely to get prescriptions filled (Fernandez-Lazaro et al., 2019). The uninsured also have higher rates of emergency department use relative to those with private insur- ance and the cost of care tends to be higher in that setting relative to outpatient settings (Greenwood-Ericksen and Kocher, 2019; Xu et al., 2017). Although we make broad assumptions about utilization increas- ing as a result of the 10Plan, we do not account for the possibility that health outcomes and spending might improve for those who are cur- rently uninsured and who, under the 10Plan, can seek treatment earlier and in less-costly settings without the risk of catastrophic medical bills. This point is important, as we predicted that out-of-pocket spend- ing would increase, on average, for those who are currently uninsured, and who do not have the protection from a costly catastrophic health 54 Analysis of the 10Plan event under the status quo. Currently 56 percent of adults report a medical financial hardship, defined as having a problem paying a med- ical bill, worrying about paying for the cost of care for a serious illness (e.g., “financial toxicity”), or delaying or forgoing care due to worries about costs (Yabroff et al., 2019). We would like to compare health out- comes and quality of care (e.g., access) given the amounts spent under the two options, but we were unable to quantify the change in benefits using the data available. There may also be broader market-level effects that influence prices and the supply of health care; we have not modeled these effects. Introducing a new approach to health care delivery will likely have spillover effects on other groups, not just the uninsured or those in the nongroup market. We have assumed that individuals who are currently covered by employer-sponsored plans will keep their current coverage. However, firms may have an incentive to stop providing insurance and instead offer their employees a subsidy to participate in the 10Plan, under which health care prices are lower. We have made no assump- tions about the employer mandate from the ACA. This would result in greater participation in the 10Plan, which has implications for federal cash flows associated with managing this program. We have also assumed that individuals currently covered by Med- icaid would maintain their coverage, though some may prefer to use the 10Plan if access to care is better or easier. We also have not adjusted for the potential provider response to this plan. As the 10Plan may increase demand for health care, there is no reason, a priori, to expect a corresponding increase in the supply of providers. In fact, if the 10Plan results in downward pressure on reimbursement rates broadly, we may expect supply to contract (e.g., fewer hospitals and providers). Whether supply remains constant or contracts, an increase in demand likely means unmet demand and increases in wait times to receive care. We note that we have not modeled the borrowing behavior of 10Plan participants, though this could be done using a utility maxi- mization framework. We assumed that all 10Plan participants would elect to defer all medical payments beyond the required copayment each year and make repayments at the minimum required rate (the Conclusion 55 repayment cap). In reality, however, 10Plan participants might opt to pay some or all of their medical expenses up front; for example, if the expenses are particularly low or if the participants are averse to incur- ring debt. Another key limitation relevant to enrollee behavior is that we did not estimate any change in medical spending behavior on the basis of the current deferred payment balance. However, it is likely that in a sit- uation in which, for example, an individual incurs a large expense and expects to pay the required repayment premium each year for several years, that individual might exhibit different spending behavior than if the payment balance were zero. Similarly, individuals with chronic health conditions who expect to pay at or near the repayment cap each year might exhibit different spending behavior than individuals who do not expect to reach the cap.

APPENDIX A Health Care Demand and Supply

In this appendix, we describe key features of the U.S. health care system, the empirical evidence on demand for health care, and the market structure of the U.S. health care system. The appendix is intended as a primer for nonexpert readers.

Health Insurance and Risk

Health care is a unique good in that individuals consume or use it for the purposes of improving or preserving their health, and not because they derive utility from going to medical visits per se. In this way, individuals “demand” health care in the economics sense because they want better health (Grossman, 1972). In the United States, the major- ity of individuals pay for their health care through private or public health insurance. The vast majority of individuals younger than 65 have health insurance through a private source, though this varies somewhat by age (Cohen, Martinez, and Zammitti, 2018). The rationale for using health insurance to pay for health care expenditures is that it mitigates individuals’ risk of high or unexpected health care expenditures. Health insurers can pool risks so that the costs of expensive illnesses or conditions are spread across numerous enrollees. Health insurance is also a way for individuals to “smooth” their health care consumption costs over time. Insurance premiums and expected out-of-pocket copays and coinsurance will be more stable from month to month than health care costs incurred without health insurance.

57 58 Analysis of the 10Plan

The market for health care is characterized by what economists call “information asymmetries” and “principal-agent” problems, which theoretically can result in market distortions (i.e., the market does not reach the most-efficient outcomes) (Hurley, 2000). Information asym- metries arise when one person involved in a transaction does not have the same information as the other party. This can lead to suboptimal decisionmaking. The principal-agent problem refers to the challenges that arise when one person (the agent) makes decisions for another party (the principal). In health, the medical provider (agent) advises the patient (principal) about what medical care to consume; the medical provider is also often an agent to the payer or insurer through negoti- ated contracts; and similarly, insurers and their enrollees have a con- tractual relationship. By having individuals pay the “first dollar” for coverage, the principal-agent problem is mitigated by the 10Plan, but it is not eliminated because some individuals can be fairly certain that they will not repay the full amount. Informational asymmetries arise in health for a variety of rea- sons, including: (1) prices are not always transparent; (2) the consumer (patient) and the supplier (physician) have different levels of under- standing of medicine, meaning that patients often do not know what procedures they need; and (3) third-party insurers lack both informa- tion on patients prior to insuring them and on what care is needed after they are insured (Cutler and Zeckhauser, 2000; Zweifel and Manning, 2000). Although we would expect lack of price transparency to lead to higher prices charged, the empirical evidence is mixed (Brown, 2019; Cutler and Dafny, 2011; Whaley, 2019). Lack of a clear price may also lead patients to agree to more care (including unnecessary care) than they might have agreed to “buy” if they had known the price. How- ever, over time, consumers may use less of certain types of medical care, such as preventive care, because they are concerned about what they may be billed. Patients’ lack of information under a fee-for-service health care system can contribute to overuse of unnecessary care as providers get paid for each service they provide. There is a large body of empirical evidence documenting this so-called physician-induced demand (Johnson, 2014). There is also extensive evidence on informa- Health Care Demand and Supply 59 tion gaps between insurers and patients that can lead to suboptimal decisionmaking. The 10Plan implementation will require some degree of price transparency, which should mitigate some of these negative effects. However, the scale of this mitigation will depend on the specif- ics of the implementation. These informational asymmetries and the principal-agent prob- lem in health insurance markets result in two challenges to optimiz- ing health care utilization and spending: adverse selection and moral hazard (Cutler and Zeckhauser, 2000; Zweifel and Manning, 2000). Adverse selection refers to the phenomenon in which individuals who choose to purchase health insurance are likely to be systematically dif- ferent from those who choose to go without health insurance. In par- ticular, individuals who are sick or expect high medical expenditures in the future are more likely to purchase health insurance and may seek more-generous plans than their healthier counterparts. Moral hazard occurs when, once covered by health insurance, individuals have an incentive to use more health care services than they would in the absence of insurance. Subject to the cost-sharing terms of their coverage, individuals may engage in less-healthy behav- iors, knowing that their health insurance will pay for care regardless of their behavior. Some have more aptly labeled moral hazard as “hidden action” to avoid negative connotations of the term—it merely reflects differences in incentives to consume health care among those who are insured relative to those who are not (Anderson, Dobkin, and Gross, 2012; Card, Dobkin, and Maestas, 2008; Pauly, 1968; Zeckhauser, 1970). For example, individuals paying out of pocket may be more conscientious about the services that their providers are recommend- ing, ask more questions about health care prices, and be more willing to forgo services. For most of the population, the 10Plan will have less of a moral hazard concern than traditional insurance products because individuals will be required to pay off accumulated spending. However, for the highest-cost individuals with sufficiently low income, there is a potential for moral hazard because they will likely see their accumulated health costs forgiven on the margin. 60 Analysis of the 10Plan

Health Care Prices

The United States spends more on health care than any other country, and research suggests that the main reason is that the prices paid for any given type of care are higher in the United States than in other developed nations. The 10Plan directly addresses this by limiting the prices paid by the population covered by the 10Plan to the lower prices negotiated by Medicare. The United States spends a much higher portion of its gross domestic product (GDP) on health care than any other country. In 2016, health care spending accounted for 17.8 percent of U.S. GDP. Among other developed nations, the share ranged from 9.6 percent in Australia to 12.4 percent in Switzerland (Papanicolas, Woskie, and Jha, 2018). As summarized by Irene Papanicolas and colleagues (2018), there are several potential explanations for these differences. First, U.S. consumers may be sicker and thus require more care than other nations. However, compared with ten other high-income coun- tries (Japan, Switzerland, France, Canada, the Netherlands, Sweden, Australia, the United Kingdom, Germany, and Denmark), the United States has similar utilization rates of many health care services. On a per-capita basis, the United States has similar numbers of physicians and nurses, hospital beds, hospital discharges, and surgical procedures. Despite similar rates of health care utilization, the United States has worse outcomes than the comparison countries. The United States has the shortest life-expectancy and the highest infant mortality rate. Although the United States has the second-lowest smoking rate, it has the highest rate of adults who are overweight or obese; though there may be some differences in health outcomes, it is not clear that these would explain higher health care costs. Thus, differences in the use or quality of health care do not appear to explain the difference in health care spending between the United States and other high-income nations. The explanation that does hold is the price of care (Anderson, Hussey, and Petrosyan, 2019). Prices for health care goods and services are much higher in the United States than in other developed nations. For example, U.S. per capita spending on prescription drugs is 52 per- Health Care Demand and Supply 61 cent higher than the next highest Organisation for Economic Co- operation and Development (OECD) country, France (Danzon and Furukawa, 2008). The use of prescription drugs is 39 percent higher in France than in the United States, but prices are 26 percent lower. In France, the share of lower-cost generic versus brand-name drugs is 14 percent higher. Among other services, a 2014 report by the Interna- tional Federation of Health Plans shows that the average price of diag- nostic magnetic resonance imaging (MRI) ranges from $130 in Spain to $811 in New Zealand, compared with $1,119 in the United States (International Federation of Health Plans, 2015). For diagnostic colo- noscopies, the same study finds that average prices range from $372 in Australia to $1,421 in New Zealand, much less than the United States’ $3,059 average price. One potential downside to lower prices in the United States is that they might negatively affect provider supply and patient wait times (Davis et al., 2007). Much of the price difference between the United States and other countries occurs among the population with employer-sponsored insur- ance or insurance purchased on the individual (nongroup) market as opposed to public insurance (e.g., Medicare). Even within the United States, there is wide variation in prices. For example, average reim- bursement rates for hospital services within the employer-sponsored market are 241 percent of Medicare rates (White and Whaley, 2019). Medicaid reimbursement rates are much lower than Medicare reim- bursement rates. In exchange for generous prescription drug insurance coverage, pharmaceutical manufacturers are mandated by statute to give Medicaid the “best prices” for prescription drugs.

Sources of High Prices for the Privately Insured Population Understanding the source of higher prices in the United States is criti- cal to determining the extent to which prices can be lowered. Prices for Medicare services are set administratively by CMS. CMS adjusts prices on the basis of geography-specific cost differences and provider characteristics, but prices are similar overall among pro- viders. Medicaid reimbursement rates are set by both individual states and, in states where Medicaid services are contracted out to private 62 Analysis of the 10Plan insurers, through Medicaid managed care plans. Managed care plans use networking strategies to manage care utilization and negotiate preferential prices. Prices for the privately insured population, however, are estab- lished through a complex negotiation process. Every insurance car- rier negotiates separately with every hospital or health care provider to determine reimbursement rates for that insurer’s enrollee population. Insurers use preferential networks and the threat of exclusion from these networks to bargain for lower prices. Hospitals use reputation, quality, and status to negotiate for higher prices. There is little empiri- cal evidence that supports the hypothesis that high prices for private insurance payers are primarily because of low reimbursement rates from Medicare and Medicaid. In other words, high private insurer prices are not the result of shifting costs from public payers, and private insurer prices would remain high even if public payers increased their reim- bursement rates (Frakt, 2011). This negotiation system has resulted in a chaotic landscape with high and variable prices. For hospital services, a recent report found negotiated prices for hospitals range all the way up to 646 percent of Medicare prices (Frakt, 2011). Several other studies document the wide variation in prices among the privately insured population for common services (Baker, Bundorf, and Royalty, 2013; Cooper et al., 2019; Fran- zini et al., 2014). Wide variation exists both within markets and across markets. One recent example includes a BlueCross BlueShield report that found a 267 percent range in the price for knee replacement sur- geries in and a 313 percent range in the price for hip replace- ments in Boston (BlueCross BlueShield, 2015).

Price Transparency and Price Shopping One rationale behind a self-insurance plan, such as the 10Plan, is that individuals who are paying out of pocket for health care will have more incentive to pay attention to prices. In other words, perhaps they will demand to know prices up front, be more conscientious about using costly discretionary services, or do both. As noted previously, price transparency is an issue in health care. Many hospitals and health care providers cannot readily provide their Health Care Demand and Supply 63 own prices (Bernstein and Bernstein, 2014), even for common services and for patients without insurance. State regulations mandating that providers disclose prices have not led to increased price transparency because many providers do not comply with these regulations (Anthony and Haller, 2015; Anthony and Haller, 2017; Saloner et al. 2017; Wil- liams, 2019), and consumers have difficulty interpreting price infor- mation. Combined with the wide variation in provider prices, the lack of price transparency limits patient ability to price shop for common services. Several “price transparency tools” have been developed to fill these gaps. These tools range from state-administered websites, tools developed by insurance carriers, and third-party companies. Current estimates suggest that over 90 percent of the privately insured popula- tion has access to some form of price transparency (White et al., 2014). Although these tools should enable patients to shop for lower-priced providers, the current evidence found very modest effects on lowering the prices that the average patient pays (Brown, 2019; Desai et al., 2016; Desai et al., 2017; Mehrotra, Brannen, and Sinaiko, 2014; Whaley, 2019). One potential reason why price transparency tools have not led to meaningful savings is that they do not change the underlying incen- tives to price-shop. Many Americans have generous insurance cover- age. The financial incentives to price-shop are limited when patients pay the same copayment regardless of providers or coinsurance. In recent years, high-deductible health plans and consumer- directed health plans (CDHPs) have become increasingly popular. In 2018, 47 percent of privately insured patients were enrolled in a CDHP, an 88 percent increase from 2010, when CDHP enrollment was 25 percent of this population. These plans require patients to bear the first portion of health care spending in a year before insurance coverage kicks in. These deductibles can be quite large. In 2010, the average deductible for an employer-sponsored CDHP plan was $1,729 for an individual plan (Kaiser Family Foundation, 2018). By 2018, the average deductible amount increased to $2,349. Many ACA exchange enrollees have deductibles of $5,000 and higher. The motivation for these plans is that the increased “skin in the game” will lead patients to shop for lower-priced providers. However, substantial empirical evi- 64 Analysis of the 10Plan dence suggests that patients instead cut back on care, and there is no observed change in price-shopping (Sood et al., 2013). Patients are just as likely to cut back on high-value care as they are on low-value and potentially wasteful care (Brot-Goldberg et al., 2017). However, there is evidence that other, less blunt, programs can induce price-shopping. One such example is reference pricing and tiered cost-sharing, which use more-targeted cost-sharing incentives to encourage the use of lower-priced providers. Patients who receive care from higher-priced providers are required to pay much higher costs than patients who go to less expensive providers. Across several popu- lations and services, reference pricing programs have led to savings of 10 percent to 32 percent (Robinson, Brown, and Whaley, 2017). The services eligible for this type of program account for 30 to 40 percent of health care spending.

How Will the 10Plan Change Health Care Utilization?

The 10Plan will eliminate the need for participating families to pur- chase health insurance in the nongroup market and allow them to pay for care directly out of pocket or through repayment premiums. Each of these features of the plan may change how much health care indi- viduals consume. In addition, limiting prices to Medicare FFS rates will lower the amount that providers receive. The extent to which such a plan would affect health care utilization and spending is unknown, but we can draw on empirical evidence on the demand elasticity of health care. Variation in consumer demand for health care (elasticity) reflects how sensitive patients are to seeking health care when the price of health care changes or when income changes. More specifically,

• Price elasticity of demand reflects how responsive patients are to changes in the price of medical services. Mathematically, it is cal- culated as the percentage change in quantity of medical services demanded, divided by the percentage change in the price. An elasticity of less than one means that demand is relatively inelas- Health Care Demand and Supply 65

tic, or that consumers do not change their utilization much when prices change. An elasticity of more than one means that demand is relatively elastic, that is consumers are sensitive to price changes. • Income elasticity of demand reflects how individuals’ demand for a good or service changes with income. Typically, as income increases, the demand for goods will rise, (except in the case of so-called inferior goods that households purchase less of as their income rises).

We discuss empirical evidence on the expected behavioral responses to each of the key changes under the 10Plan. This evidence is critical to informing the assumptions of our microsimulation model, which predicts how individual health care use and spending would change if the 10Plan were implemented. Reduced expenditures on health insurance plan premiums. Families currently purchasing health insurance in the nongroup market will no longer incur premium costs under the 10Plan. In 2018, the average premium for plans obtained on the exchanges was $594 per month (CMS, 2019). About 87 percent of enrollees in exchange plans received an APTC, and the average monthly tax credit among those individuals was $518. Thus, not having to pay these premiums will result, on aver- age, in an additional $912 and $7,128 per year in savings, for individu- als with and without APTCs, respectively. To the extent that these reduced expenditures can be seen as increasing families’ incomes, we might expect a change in the demand for health care. In other words, because individuals have more income to spend, they may “buy” more health care (e.g., use more preventive services) or they may save more for unexpected health care. Empiri- cal estimates, however, suggest that this increased income is unlikely to affect individuals’ demand for health care; a meta-analytic review found no evidence of an income elasticity for health care greater than one (Costa-Font, Gemmill, and Rubert, 2011; Getzen, 2000). Reduced medical prices. The 10Plan will have a reference price list delineating the maximum amount that providers can charge for differ- ent services, which will be based on Medicare FFS rates. For families currently covered by a nongroup plan, this may mean lower prices than 66 Analysis of the 10Plan what they currently face. Previous studies have estimated that Medicare rates are about 80 percent lower for physician services and 60 percent lower for hospital services than private insurance rates (American Hos- pital Association, 2018; Federal Hospital Insurance and Federal Sup- plementary Medical Insurance Trust Funds Boards of Trustees, 2012). As the price of health care decreases, we would expect the amount of health care demanded to increase. However, under the 10Plan, individuals would also become directly responsible for their health care costs, which may cause indi- viduals to use less health care (see below). The out-of-pocket financial exposure at the point of service may be higher under the 10Plan, even though prices may be lower, but families’ out-of-pocket exposure will also be capped. For individuals currently uninsured, it is unclear how the refer- ence price list will compare with prices they currently face and the extent to which this would influence their behavior. There is signifi- cant evidence that uninsured individuals consume less health care than those who have health insurance (as we review later in this section). However, they may pay out of pocket for a significantly smaller fraction of their expenditures because expenditures for the uninsured are often uncompensated—expenditures unpaid by the patient and cov- ered by indirect sources (Coughlin et al., 2014). Some have referred to this gap between what the uninsured pay for their care and the expenses they incur as implicit insurance (Finkelstein, Mahoney, and Notowidigdo, 2018). The implication from this work is that the unin- sured may be less sensitive to prices because of the existence of this substantial implicit insurance. Those who are currently uninsured may face other financial and legal threats that influence their use of care. However, we found that, among those who were uninsured in 2017 with any health care expenditures, out-of-pocket costs amounted to 60 percent of the total cost of care. Under the 10Plan, even though all costs will be compensated through the removal of implicit insurance, the currently uninsured may be more willing to seek care. Paying out of pocket. The 10Plan will require enrollees to pay for their care out of pocket or by borrowing from the federal government. To gauge how we might expect health care utilization to change, we Health Care Demand and Supply 67 first turn to the extensive literature on expansions of health insurance coverage in the United States. We note that these quasi-experimental studies on expansions of health insurance coverage (and, in a few cases, true experiments) can offer significant insight into how we might expect individuals to respond to changes in prices under a health insur- ance plan, but responses under the 10Plan, which is not an insurance plan, may be different. The impact of health insurance expansion on health care uti- lization and expenditures among those who are already covered has largely been studied by examining changes in health insurance cover- age, including within-firm changes in plans (Beeuwkes Buntin et al., 2011; Bundorf, 2016; Fronstin and Roebuck, 2013; Haviland et al., 2016; Kozhimannil et al., 2013; Lo Sasso, Helmchen, and Kaestner, 2010; Wharam et al., 2011), recent reforms in Massachusetts (Finkel- stein, Hendren, and Shepard, 2019; Smulowitz et al., 2014), Medic- aid expansions stemming from the ACA (Ladhania et al., 2019), and experiments, like the RAND Health Insurance Experiment (HIE) in the 1970s (Keeler and Rolph, 1988; Manning et al., 1987), and the recent Oregon Health Insurance Experiment (OHE) (Finkelstein et al., 2012; Finkelstein et al., 2016; Taubman et al., 2014) as part of the ACA Medicaid expansions.

Summary of Previous Empirical Studies The HIE, conducted in the 1970s, is the foremost experimental study on health insurance design in the United States (Keeler and Rolph, 1988; Manning et al., 1987). Randomization is the gold standard in research design for establishing convincing evidence on causal impacts, but is often not possible in health policy (Choudhry, 2017; Finkel- stein and Taubman, 2015). The HIE randomized almost 3,000 fami- lies (7,700 individuals) to five types of health insurance plans offering varying degrees of cost-sharing, ranging from 0 to 95 percent, and fol- lowed them for three to five years. Researchers found that individuals consumed less health care as the amount they were required to pay for their care increased, on average. Across all types of care, the average price elasticity of demand was estimated at −0.20, which means that for a 1 percent increase in the price of health care, we would expect 68 Analysis of the 10Plan individuals to consume 0.20 percent less health care (Keeler and Rolph, 1988; Manning et al., 1987). In 2008, the state of Oregon used a lottery to expand Medicaid to uninsured low-income adults, which allowed for a strong assessment of the causal effects of providing health care with no cost-sharing but with low monthly premiums (ranging from $0 to $20) (Finkelstein et al., 2016; Finkelstein et al., 2012; Taubman et al., 2014). Research- ers found a significant increase in self-reported utilization, particularly for outpatient visits, inpatient visits (not originating in the emergency department), and prescription drugs, resulting in around a 25 percent increase in annual health care expenditures (Finkelstein et al., 2012). Using administrative hospital data in Oregon, researchers subsequently found a significant increase in emergency department use among cur- rently uninsured individuals who enrolled in Medicaid, relative to a comparison group that remained uninsured (Taubman et al., 2014). Several quasi-experimental and observational studies of other state Medicaid expansions and reforms have generally found that lower out- of-pocket liability for medical expenditures is associated with higher utilization (Nikpay et al., 2017; Smulowitz et al., 2014; Sommers et al., 2016; Wharam et al., 2011; Wherry and Miller, 2016). In addition, studies examining associations between health care utilization and being on a high-deductible and consumer-directed plan have found that spending is negatively correlated with the deduct- ible and that, overall, utilization declines between 5 and 15 percent when individuals switch to a plan that requires greater out-of-pocket responsibility. As others have noted (Einav and Finkelstein, 2018), plans tend to be more complicated than just requiring a set cost-sharing percentages. Instead, there are often deductibles, cost-sharing that varies by type of care, and then 0 percent cost-sharing after a maximum out-of-pocket amount has been reached. This means that behavioral responses may vary, not only by type of care, but with aspects of the plan’s budget set. For the purposes of modeling behavioral responses, we have estimated changes in utilization and cost with and without changes in demand, using a range of elasticities from the previous literature, and we have allowed these changes to vary by the individual’s current Health Care Demand and Supply 69 health insurance status (e.g., uninsured versus covered by a nongroup plan). Specifically, we assumed a set of “small” and “large” elasticities to give a range of estimates. In Table A.1, we present the key studies we reviewed in formulat- ing our modeling assumptions.

Modeling Assumptions

Currently Uninsured Those who are currently uninsured may respond differently under the 10Plan than those currently insured because of pent-up demand for health care that they could not afford previously or because of moral hazard. The studies examining the expansion of Medicaid are most relevant for predicting how those who are currently uninsured would respond to the 10Plan, which does not require any up-front premiums. Across most studies of Medicaid expansions—including the OHE, which included randomization to address potential selection issues— uninsured individuals who became covered by Medicaid increased their utilization, with estimates ranging as follows (see studies described in previous section):

• outpatient care increased between 7 and 55 percent • inpatient care increased by 2 to 29 percent • emergency department visits ranged from decreases of 29 percent to increases of 41 percent • total spending increased by 25 percent.

However, although the 10Plan may increase access to care for those currently uninsured, they will still be directly responsible for the copayment and, in the case of those earning more than 150 per- cent of FPL, the cost of all nonpreventative care that they use, either through immediate or deferred repayment. Thus, we might expect to observe smaller increases in utilization than we observed from Med- icaid expansions. To adjust for this out-of-pocket financial exposure, we adjusted the Medicaid demand elasticities shown above downward using estimates from the HIE. Specifically, we adjusted all amounts downward by 20 percent. We present two sets of assumptions we use to 70 Analysis of the 10Plan a,b a,b a,b a,b e d e g

f Study c c RAND Health Insurance Study RAND Health Insurance Study Medicaid expansion OHE Medicaid expansion Insurance plans offering high deductible plans RAND Health Insurance Study OHE Medicaid expansion Medicaid expansion RAND Health Insurance Study Estimated Effects 0.17 0.17 Elasticity: −0.16 Elasticity: −0.14 Medicaid expansion in Kentucky relative to none increase in à 25% Elasticity: − Medicaid hospital coverage à increased admissions by 30% increaseMedicaid expansion à 2.4% Elasticity: −0.20 Medicaid coverage à 1.08 additional outpatient visits (55%) Medicaid expansion à visits increased by 6.6% Elasticity: − Medicaid expansion states à 29% increase in admissions

Acute visits Well visits visitsOutpatient Outpatient and pharmaceutical spending admissionsHospital hospitalOvernight stays Chronic visits Chronic visitsOutpatient General practicioner visits use Hospital admissionsHospital

Outpatient Care Outpatient Care Inpatient Type of CareType Table A.1 Summary of Empirical Evidence: How Utilization Changes in Response to Changes in Required Out-of-Pocket Spending Health Care Demand and Supply 71 j o k p q d i m l Study h c Analysis of multiple private plans Medicaid expansion Massachusetts health care reform Natural experiment switch to high deductible plan Natural experiment switch to high deductible plan Single firm switching OHE Medicaid expansion Analysis of multiple private plans OHE Analysis of multiple private plansn Analysis of multiple private plans 5% decline5% Estimated Effects Medicaid expansion in Kentucky relative to none decreasein à 29% Texas increase à 1-2% reform Massachusetts Switch led decline to 34% to 21.5 in visits, gender and severity on depending à 16.45% declineSwitch High deductible plans à decline à 25% Switch Medicaid coverage à increased probability of ED use by 7 percentage points and increased number of ED visits by 0.41 per increase) new enrollee (41% Medicaid coverage à increased ED visits by 0.59 per new enrollee increase)* (9% High deductible declines plans and 15.7% à 15 in first and second post-years Medicaid coverage à total spending increases by increase)$778 (25% HSA enrollees spending à 5-7% relative to non- enrollees High deductible decline plans à 14%

ED visits ED visits ED visits Annual spending Annual spending Annual spending Emergency Department (ED) (ED) Department Emergency visits ED visits ED visits Annual spending Annual spending Annual spending

Total spending Total Table A.1—Continued Department Emergency Type of CareType 72 Analysis of the 10Plan Study Estimated Effects Table A.1—Continued Brot-Goldberg et al., 2017. Manning et al., 1987. Sommers et al., 2016. Ladhania et al., 2019. Taubman et al., 2014. Lo Sasso, Shah, and Frogner, 2010. Haviland et al., 2016. Beeuwkes Buntin et al., 2011. Fronstin and Roebuck, 2013. Keeler and Rolph, 1988. Wherry and 2016. Miller, Wharam et al., 2011. Finkelstein et al., 2012. Lo Sasso, Helmchen, and Kaestner, 2010. Nikpay et al., 2017. Nikpay et al., 2017. Smulowitz et al., 2014. Kozhimannil et al., 2013. Type of CareType a b c d e f g h i j k l m n o p q NOTES: Elasticities are calculated as the percentage change in quantity demanded divided by the percentage change in price. Thus, an elasticity of −0.20 indicates decline that for in a 1% the price, the quantity demanded increased by 0.20 percent. * Nikpay et al. find (2017) a 2.5 increase in additional ED visits per 1,000 individuals, which is about a 9 percent increase on the baseline rate of 46.74 per 1,000 in expansion states. Health Care Demand and Supply 73 model changes in uninsured individual’s behaviors in Table A.2: a set of changes with the smaller magnitude of expected change from the empirical estimates (labeled “small changes”) and a set with the largest expected change (labeled “large changes”).

Currently Insured In general, previous studies have demonstrated that, as individuals’ out- of-pocket financial responsibility for health care increases, their utiliza- tion decreases. However, as noted previously, the change for those who are currently covered by a nongroup health insurance plan is likely to depend on various aspects of the current plan. First, among individuals who currently face deductibles, we would expect an increase in health care utilization under the 10Plan relative to the status quo because, under the status quo, all care used up to the amount of the deductible would require individuals to pay out of pocket and would be applied to the annual deductible. However, after the annual deductible is met, individuals currently insured would have lower out-of-pocket liabili- ties, as they would only be responsible for the coinsurance amounts after the deductible has been met. Thus, we would expect utilization to decline under the 10Plan relative to the status quo for those cur- rently insured after spending an amount equivalent to their status quo deductible. In the MEPS data, we know whether individuals currently have an annual deductible and whether it is more or less than $1,300 per person (or $2,600 per family) per year. We therefore assumed behavioral responses to the 10Plan that depend on the year-to-date

Table A.2 Range of Predicted Changes in Utilization for Currently Uninsured

Type of Care Small Changes Large Changes

Outpatient Increases 5.6% Increases 44%

Inpatient Increases 1.6% Increases 23.2%

ED Decreases 23.2% Increases 32.8%

All other care Increases 20% Increases 20% 74 Analysis of the 10Plan spending and whether that amount has exceeded $1,300. We list these assumptions in Table A.3.

10Plan Versus Private Insurance This section presents a set of other factors that would influence indi- viduals’ preference for the 10Plan relative to existing health insurance product options, including employer-sponsored insurance and non- group insurance. Although eligibility for the 10Plan is restricted to those with- out offers of private group insurance, we consider a counterfactual in which an individual could choose between the two. The extent to which someone would prefer private insurance over the 10Plan will depend on their out-of-pocket costs, their risk exposure, and their risk and debt aversion preferences. We discuss each of these aspects in turn.

Out-of-Pocket Costs If the 10Plan is able to set reimbursement rates to Medicare FFS levels (or slightly higher), private insurance may be less attractive to the extent that the higher private rates translate into higher out-of- pocket costs relative to the 10Plan (Frakt, 2011). Even though privately insured enrollees often do not pay those rates, the higher commercial rates directly affect an enrollee’s cost-sharing and premium costs. Under the 10Plan, the repayment premiums would be limited on the basis of income, but there is no cap on copays. Under a private health insurance plan, enrollees face annual premium costs and cost-

Table A.3 Range of Predicted Changes in Utilization for Currently Insured

Year to Date Spending Type of Care Small Changes Large Changes

< $1,300 All care Increases 20% Increases 20%

Outpatient Decreases 14% Decreases 20%

Inpatient Decreases 17% Decreases 20% >=$1300 ED Decreases 21% Decreases 34%

All other care Decreases 5% Decreases 25% Health Care Demand and Supply 75 sharing, with the latter capped both annually and across their lifetime. In general and on the basis of out-of-pocket costs, if the premium and cost-sharing for a private insurance plan are higher than the copays and annual repayment premiums under the 10Plan, individuals would prefer the 10Plan. This will generally be the case for people with lower income and those with low utilization. In general, if the maximum out-of-pocket spending under a private plan is less than the total copay- ments and annual repayment premiums under the 10Plan, individuals would prefer the private plan. For those with chronic conditions or high utilization, the out-of- pocket cost comparison is not as straightforward. There may be dif- ferences in the quality or access to provider networks, as well as other factors to consider, including one’s income trajectory, myopia, risk exposure, and preferences.

Myopia and Income Part of this calculus will require individuals to think about future income and health care expenditures. There is a large body of behav- ioral economics literature on individuals’ myopia—a focus on near- term versus longer-term—with respect to decisionmaking (Cairns and van der Pol, 2000; Dasgupta and Maskin, 2005; Story et al., 2014). Comparing only the one-year costs under the 10Plan with a private plan might yield different preferences than would comparing costs over the longer-term. For someone who expects to have very low utilization and health care costs, the longer-term and myopic preferences are both likely to be for the 10Plan, especially if there is a large difference between expected spending under the 10Plan and a private plan premium. For someone with a chronic condition that permanently elevates health care spending (such as diabetes or high blood pressure), one might prefer a private plan if one expects to reach their maximum out- of-pocket ($8,150 in 2020 under current law) every year, and if that amount plus the annual premium is less than what one would expect to pay under the 10Plan. Thus, those with a chronic condition and higher income would likely prefer a private plan. 76 Analysis of the 10Plan

Someone expecting a very high-cost event in one year would also likely prefer private insurance because of the annual maximum out-of- pocket. Under the 10Plan, one would be likely to defer those payments as a debt and then have to pay back over time with interest. Finally, one’s expectations about future income matter, as well. If someone expects to have a much lower income in the future, that indi- vidual may prefer the 10Plan because their repayment premiums would be tied to the lower income in the future (and eventually forgiven). On the other hand, if someone expects future income to grow, the prefer- ence may be for a private health insurance plan, particularly if the plan provides access to better or more providers and the cost of the premium and cost-sharing is expected to be less than the copays and repayments under the 10Plan.

Risk and Debt Aversion Individual tolerance for risk (in this context, we will use risk to mean variability in spending) is another consideration when comparing the 10Plan with status quo insurance options. Because the 10Plan has indi- viduals pay out-of-pocket for the first dollar of care and can spread costs out over time, it is structurally a riskier option than private insurance. However, in practice, it will be lower risk for many people because the government will pay off some portion of their spending. In particular, while the maximum out-of-pocket cap limits the risk for individuals with private insurance, people on the 10Plan know that their annual costs will be a fixed share of their income in a year, but because there may be volatility in their future income, they may not know how much they will be responsible for in the future (either as a share of their income or as a dollar value). This uncertainty around future income translates into financial risk with the 10Plan. Thus, the risk associated with the 10Plan will be higher for people with higher incomes, those who are younger, and those who have more-volatile incomes (in par- ticular, those who may expect to have substantive income growth in the future). Additionally, the 10Plan essentially allows individuals to borrow money from the federal government at a low interest rate to pay for medical care. Some individuals will strongly prefer not to hold this Health Care Demand and Supply 77 debt (i.e., debt aversion) and may prefer a private insurance plan, even at a higher cost, to avoid this. In summary, although we can discuss potential behavioral responses to the 10Plan in abstraction, modeling these decisions—and the impetus for them—is much more complicated. Fundamentally, the 10Plan will be a substantive disruption to the insurance market. Based on the cost to individuals alone, health insur- ance companies will have trouble competing with the existing business model. Structurally, there are portions of the population who would likely prefer existing insurance products to the 10Plan, but there may be substantive changes to the underlying risk pool. For the work in this study, we assumed that the 10Plan would only be taken up by those who are currently uninsured or those currently in the nongroup insur- ance market.

APPENDIX B Methodology

As discussed in Chapter Four, we developed a microsimulation model that tracks individuals’ medical expenditures, demographic character- istics, and deferred payments over time. In this section, we provide a more detailed explanation of the data, methodologies, and limitations.

Data To construct a representative population, we relied on demographic and income information from the 2019 ASEC supplement to the CPS, which allows us to create a sample of individuals and families with the required information to determine whether they would be 10Plan- eligible and what their maximum costs could be. To understand the medical expenditures faced by individuals and families, we used the 2015 and 2016 MEPS. The 2015–2016 MEPS has longitudinal data about an individual’s medical expenditures for both 2015 and 2016. Thus, we were able to build and test a model of expected medical spending in 2016 based on the details from 2015. In addition to the MEPS and CPS, we relied on other sources to provide information necessary to inform the dynamics. We used National Vital Statistics data from the CDC from 2017 to produce estimates for pregnancy and birth rates (Martin et al., 2018; Matthews and Hamilton, 2019). Data from the Healthcare Cost and Utilization Project (HCUP) provided a distribution of the costs associated with pregnancy (Agency for Healthcare Research and Quality, 2016). We used a combination of the U.S. life expectancy tables given by both the Human Mortality Database (HMD) (D’Addio and d’Ercole, 2005)

79 80 Analysis of the 10Plan and the United Nations Mortality projections (United Nations, 2019) to provide data on national death rates by age and gender. We obtained target numbers for births, deaths, and immigration per year from the U.S. Census Bureau 2017 National Population Projections Tables and the CDC 2019 National Vital Statistics to inform the proportion of deaths attributable to the population under 65 years of age (CDC, undated; U.S. Census Bureau, 2017). Because a substantial portion of medical expenditures are in the last few months of one’s life and the MEPS does not capture some end- of-life spending, we relied on information from Einav et al. (2018) to produce estimates for medical expenditures in the last six months of life. We used various data sources to model health status transition rates. First, we considered the incidence rates by gender and age groups for two major chronic conditions that have very few comorbidities, namely, all cancers and heart disease. We used statistics from recent analyses by the CDC (American Cancer Society, 2019) and other researchers (Crimmins et al., 2008) to obtain incidence rates by gender and age for all cancers, heart disease, and all other chronic and acute conditions paired with National Vital Statistics cause of death data (Murphy et al., 2018) from 2017 age and gender. To model how income evolves over time, we used the income mobility estimates from the PSID (U.S. Department of the Treasury, 2008).

Model Structure We modeled the cost implications for the federal government and indi- viduals under the 10Plan by evolving the starting population built from the CPS over a 15-year period. This is necessary because the 15th year is the first year in which deferred payment balances can be for- given because of expiration. Starting from the CPS population, our dynamic model produces life trajectories for each record—or individual—in our population. The dynamic model is a discrete time microsimulation model that advances the population from year to year by annually updating the following four major components of the dynamic model: Methodology 81

1. demographic attributes, including age and family size 2. family income, based on employment changes and including health insurance status 3. health status, including good or bad health, chronic and acute conditions, end-of-life care, and pregnancy 4. medical spending for all 10Plan participating family members.

Individuals belonging to different family units are assumed not to interact with each other. We projected the model forward as a Markov chain, where the state in year t is predicted based on the state in year t−1. Income and health care expenditures are stochastically generated for each record using the methods described previously. Each year, individual records are also sampled for childbirth (if female), a negative health shock (such as an acute injury), the onset of a chronic disease, and death. Each of these events helps further specify an individual record’s health care expenditures for the year. We describe the key tran- sitions in more detail in the following section.

Demographic Changes Births introduce new individuals to the active population and are tracked by the dynamic model. To model births, we assumed that each female’s annual probability of giving birth depends on age and race, according to CDC fertility statistics (Matthews and Hamilton, 2019). Infants introduced to the population were given the same race, insur- ance status, and family ID as their mothers, and received new individ- ual identifiers. Gender was randomly assigned with equal probability, and health status was randomly assigned based on probabilities from the MEPS data. Medical spending in the first year of life was modeled based on health status and statistics from the National Conference of State Legislatures (2013) memo on the costs of prenatal care. We also added families to the model population by simulating immigration. Each year, we sampled from the immigrant family IDs in the CPS to attain a sample weight roughly equal to the appropriate projection from the Census Bureau 2017 National Population Projec- tions Tables. We sampled from the group of eligible and ineligible (for the 10Plan) immigrants proportionally, and did not make any further 82 Analysis of the 10Plan assumptions about immigration levels or their eligibility for the 10Plan (U.S. Department of Homeland Security, 2018). Deaths removed individuals from the active population and were tracked by the dynamic model. To model deaths, we used national 2017 U.S. life tables taken from the HMD. We made minor adjust- ments by assuming a smooth transition from the 2017 HMD tables to 2018 using United Nations life-expectancy table projections for the United States. From the life tables, we extracted the age- and gender- specific average probabilities of death. Individual-level variability of these probabilities and their indirect dependence on health status was introduced using an analysis given by Einav et al. (2018).

Income Changes We modeled the evolution of each individual’s income over time using data from the PSID. We used data covering 2006 to 2018. Because the PSID collects information for every other year for this time period, we have six datapoints per record in this timeframe. We inflated all income to 2018 dollars using the Consumer Price Index research series using current methods (R-CPI-U-RS) and estimated the annual change to real income by comparing income in consecutive observations for each individual (U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, 2020). We updated incomes on the basis of income quintile, age group (18 to 24, 25 to 34, 35 to 49, and 50 to 64), and sex, then sampled from the distribution of income changes for the relevant CPS records. We assumed that individuals whose income fell 90 percent or more between years, occurring in 1 to 3 percent of cases for most age and income groups, experienced job loss. We randomly assigned these individuals an income in the bottom 15th percentile of the income distribution. To model the effect of transitioning from unemployment to employment, we randomly assigned individuals in the bottom 15th percentile to an income based on transitions of those who moved out of the bottom 15th percentile in the PSID. Finally, we applied an inflation rate of 2.1 percent to the income projections so that all income numbers are in nominal dollars for the respective year. Methodology 83

The timeframe involved in the PSID data covers portions of the 2001 to 2007 business cycle, the 2008 recession, and the current busi- ness cycle up to 2016. This period saw slower income growth and lower labor force participation than did the U.S. economy prior to 1980. If macroeconomic conditions in the future are better or worse than during this time frame, our projections would be off. Specifically, if income growth is higher, more people would fall in the upper bands of the 10Plan and therefore be less likely to require debt forgiveness. Alternatively, if the growth rate is lower or if the job loss rate is higher, there may either be more participants in the 10Plan, or those individu- als that do participate may be in the lower bands and require more debt forgiveness.

Insurance Status Changes As insurance status is often correlated with employment status, we modeled the transition of people onto and off of the 10Plan based on income transitions. For families whose household income changed by over 10 percent of their previous income, we randomly assigned insur- ance status based on the original distribution of insurance status by poverty level. Thus, when a family transitioned to a higher income level, they were more likely to be enrolled in employer-sponsored insur- ance, for example, and if they transitioned to a lower income level, they were more likely to be enrolled in Medicaid. This method is clearly limited, as there may be many scenarios in which an individ- ual or family changes insurance status without a significant change in income. Furthermore, the transition rates are poorly defined. How- ever, it is uncertain how the 10Plan would affect transitions between insurance statuses, and adding a more complicated model of insurance status transitions would only add uncertainty to the model.

Health Status Changes The health status of individuals in our model takes on two possible levels, namely “good” and “bad” health. The CART model, a predic- 84 Analysis of the 10Plan

tive modeling approach that uses machine learning,1 uses health status defined by self-reported health in the MEPS, which is initially provided on a five-level scale from Excellent (1) to Poor (5). This raw variable was not a significant predictor in the CART model, so we considered a collapsed metric. The best separation was between states 3 and 4, lead- ing us to classify individuals with health status 1–3 as being in “good” health and individuals with health status 4–5 as being in “bad” health. Although the two-level scale was not highly predictive of key partitions for the CART model, it had higher significance than the raw variable. In our dynamic model, we evolved the good or bad health status from year to year and also predicted whether someone suffered from an acute or chronic condition when in “bad” health (see Figure B.1). A bad health status because of a chronic condition is an absorbing state; an individual with a chronic condition is assumed to have that condi- tion henceforth and cannot transition back to a good health status. In

Figure B.1 Overview of Health Status Changes

Chronic Acute

b Good [PCDD] Bad Good x Bad sx health health health g health status status status x status

NOTES: PCDD refers to progressive chronic degenerative diseases, which we simply

refer to as a chronic condition. Sx is the probability of transitioning from good health

to bad health because of a chronic condition, bx is he probability of transitioning

from good health to bad health because of an acute condition, and gx is the probability of recovering from an acute condition and thus transitioning from bad health to good health.

1 CART is a predictive modeling approach that identifies groups with meaningfully dis- tinct relationships between the predictor and outcome variables—in this case, the demo- graphic data and medical spending patterns. Each group is defined by its combination of values for certain key variables identified as being highly predictive of the outcome variable. We then developed a spending model for each identified group, conditional on a prediction of nonzero medical expenses. Methodology 85

contrast, those with an acute condition have a chance to recover and transition back to good health status in subsequent periods. We stochastically changed the health status of each individual using a Bernoulli process with transition rates informed by CDC data (Heron, 2019). We obtained the proportions of 2017 deaths for each age group attributable to each of the top ten causes of death, which we labeled as either “chronic” or “acute” conditions,2 and assumed that these rates are reflective of incidence rates by age for various other chronic and acute conditions. We smoothly increased the incidence rate of acute conditions for younger ages in our sample so that our rates matched those found in the MEPS data. The impact of omitting this adjustment was evaluated in Model 17.

Health Care Spending Changes We used the MEPS 2015–2016 longitudinal data file to model the tra- jectory of health care expenditures. Because we were mainly interested in modeling the medical spending of potential 10Plan-eligible indi- viduals, we restricted this analysis to individuals under 65 years of age. We also excluded pregnant women from the sample because the costs associated with pregnancy are not easily determined from the MEPS longitudinal file, and instead modeled the costs associated with mater- nity separately. We used a two-part method in which we first predicted whether an individual had nonzero medical spending in a given year, and, con- ditional on this, predicted the log-transformed level of medical spend- ing. The log-transform is necessary because the distribution is skewed because of the many individuals with no health care expenditures and outliers with very high expenditures. We assumed a medical inflation rate of 5.1 percent (Cubanski, Neuman, and Freed, 2019). We incorporated adjustments to medical prices and expenditures to approximate the different price levels that 10Plan participants may

2 We classified heart disease, cancer, chronic lower respiratory diseases, stroke (cerebrovas- cular diseases), Alzheimer’s disease, diabetes, and nephritis (including nephrotic syndrome and nephrosis) as “chronic” conditions, and influenza, pneumonia, accidents, and inten- tional self-harm or suicide as “acute” conditions. 86 Analysis of the 10Plan face, as well as to account for changes in the use of care. As described in Appendix A, we assumed different behavioral or demand responses for 10Plan participants depending on whether they were currently unin- sured or covered by a nongroup plan. To adjust utilization for cur- rently insured individuals, we estimated each individual’s deductible level using average 2019 figures from eHealth (“How Much Does Indi- vidual Health Insurance Cost?” 2020), because this information is not provided in the CPS or the MEPS longitudinal file. Finally, to adjust prices to the appropriate level (i.e., Medicare, Medicare plus some per- centage), we created a composite adjustment factor using the average cost of a visit of each type of care for each insurance status, and the relative proportions of each type of care consumed. We used a logistic regression to predict a binary indicator of non- zero spending in a given year using age group, sex, health status, insur- ance category, race, income, pregnancy status, nonzero spending in the previous year, and total spending in the previous year. To project medical expenditures from year to year, given a predic- tion of nonzero spending, we built a CART model to identify groups with meaningfully distinct medical spending patterns. The CART determined that medical spending in the previous year and age group were typically the most important factors by which to partition the population, though insurance category, sex, income, race, and health status were also significant predictors. We then built a unique regres- sion model for each group to predict the next year’s health expendi- tures, again using spending in the previous year, age group, insurance category, sex, income, race, and health status as predictor variables. We developed a unique CART model and set of regressions for each pricing scheme and behavioral scenario considered. Figure B.2 shows the CART built with Medicare prices, assuming no behavioral changes. Although all predictors considered in the dynamic model (spending in the previous year, age group, insurance category, sex, income, race, and health status) were available to the CART algorithm, the data with this pricing scheme was best partitioned based on LY1 (the log transform of medical expenditures in year t), age group, and insurance category. Recall that the CART and regression models are based on the log-transform of medical expenditures, LY1, in Figure B.2, Methodology 87 because of the skewness of the distribution. The CARTs trained on the MEPS data in this way achieved an R-squared of approximately 0.3, which provided a good base for our partition-specific regression models. Although it would have been preferable to develop a model of spending patterns with more than two years of data, the MEPS is not designed to link data across more than two years, and the authors are unaware of a publicly available dataset of comparable quality contain- ing the required information for more than two years. However, the literature suggests that the relationship between medical spending in year t and year t+2 is much weaker than that between spending in year t and year t+1 (Eichner, McClellan, and Wise, 1997), so additional data of this nature would be unlikely to dramatically improve results.

Figure B.2 Example Classification and Regression Tree

7.4 100% Yes No LY1 < 7.8

6.8 8.3 61% 39% LY1 < 7 LY1 < 9.3

6.5 8 9.1 41% 27% 12% InsCat = Medicaid, uninsured Age group = <19,19–34 LY1 < 11

8.2 16% LY1 < 8.4

6.2 6.7 7.3 7.6 7.9 8.5 8.8 9.9 13% 28% 20% 11% 7% 9% 10% 3%

SOURCE: Analysis of 2016–2017 longitudinal MEPS data, weighted using person-level year weights. NOTES: InsCat = insurance category. Developed with Medicare prices and no behavioral changes. Predictor variable LY1 is the log-transform of medical spending in year t, and outcome variable LY2 is the log-transform of medical spending in year t+1 (not shown in figure). 88 Analysis of the 10Plan

Because all dependent variables used in the CART analysis were present in the CPS except for medical spending, we were able to use the CART informed by MEPS data to produce unbiased estimates of the medical spending of individuals in the CPS. We assigned prelimi- nary spending levels to our CPS dataset using a “matching” technique in which we drew a spending level from a sample of similar individuals on the basis of age group and insurance category, the two main deter- minants of health care expenditures in the MEPS. We used data from the HCUP and previous literature (Hsia, Antwi, and Weber, 2014; Xu et al., 2015) to estimate pregnancy costs, which we modeled separately from other health care expenditures. These costs were generated stochastically using a log-normal distribu- tion with the average pregnancy cost matching the national averages given by the HCUP. We further set the variance of the log-normal to statistically reproduce the variability in the costs across different insur- ance statuses and states to capture outlier costs in pregnancy. To inform medical spending in the year of death, we drew from Einav et al. (2018). This study produced a prediction model for end- of-life medical spending for those aged 65 years and over, modeling medical spending in the final year of life as a function of the predicted mortality rate. Their model predicted that the average end-of-life med- ical costs are $30,000 for those with a mortality rate below 10 percent. However, end-of-life medical costs rise sharply for those with higher mortality rates, reaching costs over $60,000. Although the model by Einav et al. for end-of-life costs applies to those 65 and older, we assumed that the model linking predicted mor- tality rate to end-of-life-spending could also be used for the younger population to predict the minimum final year of life total health costs.3 Hence, we inflated medical spending incurred in the year of death based on individuals’ age-adjusted mortality rate in the year of death.

3 Although those aged 65 and above will obviously exhibit higher predicted mortality dis- tributions and hence higher predicted end-of-life spending distributions, we assume here that the relationship between mortality rate and end-of-life spending can be extended to younger groups. In other words, we assume that an individual at any age with a given prob- ability of mortality (i.e., because of a certain chronic condition) has the same end-of-life spending distribution as an individual of any age with that same probability of mortality. Methodology 89

Limitations Several assumptions were made in developing this dynamic model. For example, we did not model the borrowing behavior of 10Plan partici- pants, and instead assumed that all 10Plan-eligible individuals would elect to defer payment for all medical expenses beyond the required copayment each year.4 In reality, however, some 10Plan participants will likely borrow less than the maximum possible amount. We also did not make any assumptions about the potential move- ment of individuals from other health plans to the 10Plan, and instead preserved the distributions of each coverage type at each family income level. In addition, we only allowed for transitions in insurance cover- age type in the event of a transition in income level. Although it is common that these two events coincide, this likely underestimates the transition in insurance coverage type for our population. The dynamic model required several other, more-technical assumptions. For example, we assumed that pregnancy rate is indepen- dent of health status. In reality, females in poor health may be much less likely to become pregnant. To predict mortality, we used a scaled version of the plots produced by Einav et al. (2018) linking mortality rate to health spending. Though these plots were developed for the Medicare population, we assumed that they apply to all age groups. Our characterization of health status permits multiple transitions to bad health because of an acute condition and may thus overweight the proportion of acute conditions relative to chronic conditions in the population. Furthermore, end-of-life spending is indirectly depen- dent on health status in our model because of the assumed dependence of mortality rate on health spending and the dependence of health spending on health status. However, controlling for mortality rate, it is possible that end-of-life spending should be greater for those suffering from a chronic condition than for those with an acute condition, for example. Thus, a more direct dependence could improve the model. In addition to limitations related to necessary assumptions regard- ing health characteristics, we made assumptions regarding income dis- tribution and growth. We used data from the PSID from 2006 to 2018

4 However, this assumption is modified in Model 24. 90 Analysis of the 10Plan to evolve the income distribution over time. This period saw limited wage growth for the majority of the population and included the sig- nificant recession beginning in 2008. If future economic conditions have a recession less (or more) severe than in 2008, or if wage growth differs from recent historical trends, the share of the population that would participate in the 10Plan at some point in their lives could differ from that predicted by our model. Although we made assumptions regarding behavioral or demand responses, there are additional potential changes that could affect the results. As previously discussed, there may be changes in the broader health care market—in the employer-sponsored market and on the supply (provider) side. Additionally, because any deferred payments are forgiven once a person ages into Medicare, there may be increases in utilization as individuals approach age 65. For example, individuals may have an incentive, at age 64, to utilize more elective health care knowing that the payments can be deferred, and the deferred payment balances will be forgiven in the next year. APPENDIX C Additional Results

In Table C.1, we present results that were used to create Figure 4.1.

Deferred Payment Balances To understand the implications of the 10Plan on household expendi- tures, we must first consider its utilization by different cohorts of the population over time. In year 15, 96.5 percent of 10Plan-eligible indi- viduals have a nonzero deferred payment balance, with a median total balance of $3,280. In Figure C.1, we show the number of individuals with nonzero deferred payment balances in the final year of the simulation, strati- fied by age group and family income as a percentage of FPL. We see that the vast majority of deferred payment balances are held by lower- income individuals with family income under 400 percent of FPL. The transfer of deferred payment balances to parents at age 26 contributes to the relatively lower number of nonzero balances for individuals in the 19–34 age group,1 and costs associated with infancy contribute to the high number of nonzero balances in the < 19 age group. The distribution of the value of the deferred payment balances in year 15 is shown in Figure C.2, stratified by age group. These box plots show the median (center black line), interquartile range (upper and lower edges of the box), and outliers (black dots). The value of deferred

1 We assumed that the deferred payment balances of 26-year-olds are passed to their par- ents. In the case where a 26-year-old does not have parents in our simulated population, the balances are forgiven.

91 92 Analysis of the 10Plan $237,178 $212,139 $177,559 Maximum $201,152 $196,651 $231,766 $235,154 $246,130 $174,904 $222,751 $235,516 $254,731 $246,521 $264,072 $223,859 $26,115 $16,717 $22,711 $19,875 $29,710 $18,593 $27,420 $31,956 $21,339 $30,755 $33,851 $32,820 $28,668 $34,895 $24,446 $9,782 $17,914 $12,136 $17,203 $14,514 $17,605 $12,781 $11,430 $15,723 $13,835 $13,282 $16,050 $15,209 $15,894 $16,504 10Plan $7,079 $6,614 $6,591 $6,571 $6,723 $6,652 $6,930 $5,898 $6,258 $6,043 $6,334 $6,643 $6,668 $4,902 $6,342 25th Percentile25th 50th Percentile Percentile 75th $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 Minimum 1 Year 3 4 2 5 11 10 12 6 13 7 8 9 14 15 Table C.1 Table Distribution of Health Care Spending for 10Plan-Eligible Family Members Under the 10Plan and Status Quo Additional Results 93 $252,119 $312,314 $275,713 $220,143 $382,109 $403,045 $415,202 $377,908 $428,519 $231,458 $414,481 $412,040 $296,924 $342,550 $382,639 Maximum $17,813 $31,360 $27,952 $21,959 $16,558 $19,002 $26,693 $30,929 $28,647 $30,095 $25,584 $24,240 $29,485 $22,900 $20,484 $9,466 $13,141 $11,182 $12,514 $11,953 $15,812 $15,931 $14,212 $14,951 $15,758 $16,072 $10,652 $15,823 $15,940 $15,442 Status Quo $6,137 $6,613 $5,749 $5,734 $6,703 $6,316 $6,575 $6,033 $6,337 $5,858 $6,620 $6,824 $6,660 $6,494 $4,858 25th Percentile25th 50th Percentile Percentile 75th $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 $0 Minimum Year 1 2 3 4 5 9 8 6 7 10 11 12 13 14 15 Table C.1—Continued Table 94 Analysis of the 10Plan

Figure C.1 Number of 10Plan-Eligible Individuals with Nonzero Deferred Payment Balance in Year 15, by Income and Age Group

8

7 Under 19 19–34 6 35–49 50–64 5

4

N (millions) 3

2

1

0 Under 100 100–150 150–250 250–400 400–600 600–800 800+ Percentage of FPL payment balances increases with age, though there is considerable vari- ation among all age groups. We might expect that individuals in poor health would spend more on health care than those in good health, particularly because our model does not account for health improvements that might result from more health care utilization. In Figure C.3, we show the propor- tion of the total deferred payment balances for all 10Plan participants stratified by income group and health status. Low-income individuals in poor health contribute most to the total value of all deferred pay- ment balances. Accordingly, median repayment premiums are higher for indi- viduals in poor health across all income levels (except the very lowest, where they are nearly equivalent), as seen in Figure C.4. In Figure C.5, we show the 50th, 75th, 95th, and 99th quantile effective repayment rate by income group for year 15. In the lowest income group, the spread between 50th and 99th quantile effective repayment rate is low, largely because the maximum repayment cap is very low (between 2 and 3 percent for families between 100 and Additional Results 95

Figure C.2 Value of Deferred Payment Balances in Year 15, by Age Group

10,000

100

Deferred payment balance ($) Deferred 1

Under 19 19–34 35–49 50–64 Age group

NOTE: The vertical axis is on a log-transformed scale.

150 percent of FPL). For the highest-income groups, over 50 per- cent of households pay 0 percent of their yearly household income in repayment premiums. These results demonstrate that in lower-income groups, there is little spread between those who fare better or worse, though in higher-income groups, those with high expenditures (and thus high payments) pay a great deal more than the rest of the pop- ulation. It is also the case that high-income families pay back their deferred payments in fewer years than do low-income families because of the relatively high repayment premium rates they face. Finally, we present results comparing the 10Plan with two alterna- tives incorporating expansion of Medicaid in Table C.2. In both cases of Medicaid expansion, the first extending to those under 250 percent of FPL and the second extending to those under 400 percent of FPL, the additional costs incurred by Medicaid enrollees far outweigh the drop in deferred payments by the 10Plan-eligible population. 96 Analysis of the 10Plan

Figure C.3 Proportion of Total Deferred Payment Balances for All 10Plan Participants, by Income Group and Health Status

20

18

16 Good health Bad health 14

12

10

8

6

4

2 Percentage of total deferred balance value of total deferred Percentage 0 Under 100 100–150 150–250 250–400 400–600 600–800 800+ Family income as a percentage of FPL

Figure C.4 Average Repayment Premiums in Year 15 by Health Status, Stratified by Income Level

6

Good health 5 Bad health

4

3 ($ in thousands) 2 Medium repayment premium Medium repayment 1

0 100–150 150–250 250–400 400–600 600–800 800+ Income as a percentage of FPL Additional Results 97

Figure C.5 Quantiles of Effective Repayment Rate by Income Group in Year 15

16

14 50th quantile 75th quantile 12 95th quantile 99th quantile 10

8

6

4

Percentage of family income Percentage 2

0 100–150 150–250 250–400 400–600 600–800 800+ Family income as a percentage of FPL 98 Analysis of the 10Plan

Table C.2 Comparison of 10Plan and Hybrid Policies Across 10Plan Target Group Medical Spending, Medicaid Population Medical Spending, Payments Deferred, and Forgiven Balances per Year, in Billions

Year 1 5 10 15

Total spending 10Plan-eligible 150.1 188.7 258.8 342.3

Hybrid (250%) 69.7 95.6 117.7 131.5 10Plan-eligible

Hybrid (400%) 46.6 62.2 73.9 78.1 10Plan-eligible

Difference—10Plan 80.4 93.1 141.1 210.8 and Hybrid (250%)

Difference—10Plan 103.5 126.5 184.8 264.1 and Hybrid (400%)

Medicaid 10Plan 367.2 393.9 547.5 817.2 spending Hybrid (250%) 654.5 740.1 1.1 1.6 (Medicaid expansion)

Hybrid (400%) 855.3 1.0 1.4 2.0 (Medicaid expansion)

Difference—10Plan –287.3 –346.1 –533.7 –776.1 and Hybrid (250%)

Difference—10Plan –488.2 –608.8 –872.1 –1.2 and Hybrid (400%)

10Plan payments 10Plan payments 131.8 167.1 232.3 310.9 deferred deferred

Hybrid (250%) 61.0 85.1 106.1 119.3 payments deferred

Hybrid (400%) 41.5 56.5 67.9 72.2 payments deferred

Difference—10Plan 70.8 82.0 126.2 191.6 and Hybrid (250%)

Difference—10Plan 90.3 110.6 164.3 238.8 and Hybrid (400%) Additional Results 99

Table C.2—Continued

Year 1 5 10 15

Amounts 10Plan 6.3 14.5 17.6 29.0 forgiven Hybrid (250%) 1.8 7.2 8.1 11.8

Hybrid (400%) 1.1 4.1 6.9 11.6

Difference—10Plan 4.5 7.3 9.5 17.3 and Hybrid (250%)

Difference—10Plan 5.2 10.4 10.7 17.4 and Hybrid (400%)

NOTE: Values greater than $5 billion are rounded to the nearest $10 billion.

References

Agency for Healthcare Research and Quality, Healthcare Cost and Utilization Project: National Inpatient Sample, 2016. American Cancer Society, Cancer Facts and Figures 2019, Atlanta, Ga., 2019. American Hospital Association, “Trendwatch Chartbook 2018, Supplementary Data Tables, Trends in Hospital Financing,” webpage, 2018. As of August 21, 2020: https://www.aha.org/guidesreports/2018-05-23-trendwatch-chartbook-chapter-4- trends-hospital-financing Anderson, Gerard F., Peter Hussey, and Varduhi Petrosyan, “It’s Still the Prices, Stupid: Why the U.S. Spends So Much on Health Care, and a Tribute to Uwe Reinhardt,” Health Affairs, Vol. 38, No. 1, January 2019, pp. 87–95. Anderson, Michael, Carlos Dobkin, and Tal Gross, “The Effect of Health Insurance Coverage on the Use of Medical Services,” American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, Vol. 4, No. 1, February 2012, pp. 1–27. Anthony, Barbara, and Scott Haller, Mass Hospitals Weak on Price Transparency, policy brief, Boston, Mass.: Pioneer Institute, 2015. Anthony, Barbara, and Scott Haller, Massachusetts Hospitals Score Poorly on Price Transparency . . . Again, Boston, Mass.: Pioneer Institute, White Paper No. 167, April 2017. Appleby, Julie, “‘Holy Cow’ Moment Changes How Montana’s State Health Plan Does Business,” Kaiser Health News, June 20, 2018. Baker, Laurence, M. Kate Bundorf, and Anne Royalty, “Private Insurers’ Payments for Routine Physician Office Visits Vary Substantially Across the United States,” Health Affairs, Vol. 32, No. 9, September 2013, pp. 1583–1590. Beeuwkes Buntin, Melinda, Amelia M. Haviland, Roland McDevitt, and Neeraj Sood, “Healthcare Spending and Preventive Care in High-Deductible and Consumer-Directed Health Plans,” American Journal of Managed Care, Vol. 17, No. 3, March 2011, pp. 222–230.

101 102 Analysis of the 10Plan

Bernard, Didem M., Cathy Cowan, Thomas M. Selden, David Lassman, and Aaron Catlin, Reconciling Medical Expenditure Estimates from the MEPS and NHEA, 2012, Rockville, Md.: Agency for Healthcare Research and Quality, 2012. Bernstein, Jillian R. H., and Joseph Bernstein, “Availability of Consumer Prices from Philadelphia Area Hospitals for Common Services: Electrocardiograms vs Parking,” JAMA Internal Medicine, Vol. 174, No. 2, 2014, pp. 292–293. Berwick, Donald M., and Simon Johnson, letter to Senator Elizabeth Warren regarding the cost of a Medicare for All plan, October 31, 2019. BlueCross BlueShield, A Study of Cost Variations for Knee and Hip Replacement Surgeries in the U.S., 15-041-R02, 2015. Brot-Goldberg, Zarek C., Amitabh Chandra, Benjamin R. Handel, and Jonathan T. Kolstad, “What Does a Deductible Do? The Impact of Cost-Sharing on Health Care Prices, Quantities, and Spending Dynamics,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 132, No. 3, August 2017, pp. 1261–1318. Brown, Zach Y., “Equilibrium Effects of Health Care Price Information,” Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 101, No. 4, October 2019, pp. 699–712. Bundorf, M. Kate, “Consumer-Directed Health Plans: A Review of the Evidence,” Journal of Risk and Insurance, Vol 83, No. 1, March 2016, pp. 9–41. Cairns, John, and Marjon van der Pol, “Valuing Future Private and Social Benefits: The Discounted Utility Model Versus Hyperbolic Discounting Models,” Journal of Economic Psychology, Vol. 21, No. 2, April 2000, pp. 191–205. Call, Kathleen T., Michael E. Davern, Jacob A. Klerman, and Victoria Lynch, “Comparing Errors in Medicaid Reporting Across Surveys: Evidence to Date,” Health Services Research, Vol. 48, No. 2, Pt. 1, April 2013, pp. 652–664. Card, David, Carlos Dobkin, and Nicole Maestas, “The Impact of Nearly Universal Insurance Coverage on Health Care Utilization: Evidence from Medicare,” American Economic Review, Vol. 98, No. 5, December 2008, pp. 2242–2258. CDC—See Centers for Disease Control and Prevention. Centers for Disease Control and Prevention, “National Vital Statistics Reports,” webpage, undated. As of September 22, 2020: https://www.cdc.gov/nchs/products/nvsr.htm Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services, “Final HHS Notice of Benefit and Payment Parameters for 2020: Fact Sheet,” press release, undated. Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services, “Early 2019 Effectuated Enrollment Snapshot,” webpage, August 12, 2019. As of August 14, 2020: https://www.cms.gov/newsroom/fact-sheets/ early-2019-effectuated-enrollment-snapshot References 103

Choudhry, Niteesh K., “Randomized, Controlled Trials in Health Insurance Systems,” New England Journal of Medicine, Vol. 377, No. 10, September 7, 2017, pp. 957–964. Christopher, Andrea S., Danny McCormick, Steffie Woolhandler, David U. Himmelstein, David H. Bor, and Andrew P. Wilper, “Access to Care and Chronic Disease Outcomes Among Medicaid-Insured Persons Versus the Uninsured,” American Journal of Public Health, Vol. 106, No. 1, 2016, pp. 63–69. CMS—See Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services. Code of Federal Regulations, Title 26, Chapter I, Subchapter H, Section 601.105, Examination of Returns and Claims for Refund, Credit or Abatement; Determination of Correct Tax Liability. Cohen, Robin A., Michael E. Martinez, and Emily P. Zammitti, Health Insurance Coverage: Early Release of Estimates form the National Health Interview Survey, January—March 2018, Washington, D.C.: National Center for Health Statistics, Centers for Disease Control and Prevention, U.S. Department of Health and Human Services, August 2018. Committee for a Responsible Federal Budget, “How Much Will Medicare for All Cost?” post, February 27, 2019. As of October 7, 2020: http://www.crfb.org/blogs/how-much-will-medicare-all-cost Cooper, Zach, Stuart V. Craig, Martin Gaynor, and John Van Reenen, “The Price Ain’t Right? Hospital Prices and Health Spending on the Privately Insured,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 134, No. 1, February 2019, pp. 51–107. Costa-Font, Joan, Marin Gemmill, and Gloria Rubert, “Biases in the Healthcare Luxury Good Hypothesis? A Meta-Regression Analysis,” Journal of the Royal Statistical Society: Series A (Statistics in Society), Vol. 174, No. 1, January 2011, pp. 95–107. Coughlin, Teresa A., John Holahan, Kyle Caswell, and Megan McGrath, Uncompensated Care for the Uninsured in 2013: A Detailed Examination, Washington, D.C.: Kaiser Commission on Medicaid and the Uninsured, 2014. Crimmins, Eileen M., Mark D. Hayward, Hiroshi Ueda, Yasuhiko Saito, and Jung Ki Kim, “Life With and Without Heart Disease Among Women and Men over 50,” Journal of Women and Aging, Vol. 20, No. 1–2, 2008, pp. 5–19. Cubanski, Juliette, Tricia Neuman, and Meredith Freed, “The Facts on Medicare Spending and Financing,” research brief, Menlo Park, Calif.: Henry J. Kaiser Family Foundation, August 2019. Cutler, David, and Leemore Dafny, “Designing Transparency Systems for Medical Care Prices,” New England Journal of Medicine, Vol. 364, No. 10, March 10, 2011, pp. 894–895. 104 Analysis of the 10Plan

Cutler, David M., and Richard J. Zeckhauser, “The Anatomy of Health Insurance,” in Anthony J. Culyer and Joseph P. Newhouse, eds., Handbook of Health Economics, Vol. 1A, Amsterdam: Elsevier, 2000, pp. 563–643. D’Addio, Anna Christina, and Marco Mira d’Ercole, Trends and Determinants of Fertility Rates, Paris: Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, Directorate for Employment, Labour and Social Affairs, OECD Social, Employment and Migration Working Papers No. 27, September 2, 2005. Danzon, Patricia M., and Michael F. Furukawa, “International Prices and Availability of Pharmaceuticals in 2005,” Health Affairs, Vol. 27, No. 1, January/ February 2008, pp. 221–233. Dasgupta, Partha, and Eric Maskin, “Uncertainty and Hyperbolic Discounting,” American Economic Review, Vol. 95, No. 4, 2005, pp. 1290–1299. Davis, Karen, Cathy Schoen, Stephen C. Schoenbaum, Michelle M. Doty, Alyssa L. Holmgren, Jennifer L. Kriss, and Katherine K. Shea, Mirror, Mirror on the Wall: An International Update on the Comparative Performance of American Health Care, New York: Commonwealth Fund, May 2007. Desai, Sunita, Laura A. Hatfield, Andrew L. Hicks, Michael E. Chernew, and Ateev Mehrotra, “Association Between Availability of a Price Transparency Tool and Outpatient Spending,” Journal of the American Medical Association, Vol. 315, No. 17, May 3, 2016, pp. 1874–1881. Desai, Sunita, Laura A. Hatfield, Andrew L. Hicks, Anna D. Sinaiko, Michael E. Chernew, David Cowling, Santosh Gautam, Sze-Jung Wu, and Ateev Mehotra, “Offering a Price Transparency Tool Did Not Reduce Overall Spending Among California Public Employees and Retirees,” Health Affairs, Vol. 36, No. 8, August 2017, pp. 1401–1407. District Economics Group, Analysis of the 10Plan Treatment of Health Care Expenditures for the Uninsured and Non-Group Insured Populations, Washington, D.C., 2019. Dobkin, Carlos, Amy Finkelstein, Raymond Kluender, and Matthew J. Notowidigdo, “The Economic Consequences of Hospital Admissions,” American Economic Review, Vol. 108, No. 2, February 2018, pp. 308–352. Eichner, Matthew J., Mark B. McClellan, and David A.Wise, “Health Expenditure Persistence and the Feasibility of Medical Savings Accounts,” Tax Policy and the Economy, Vol. 11, 1997, pp. 91–128. Einav, Liran, and Amy Finkelstein, “Moral Hazard in Health Insurance: What We Know and How We Know It,” Journal of the European Economic Association, Vol. 16, No. 4, 2018, pp. 957–982. Einav, Liran, Amy Finkelstein, Sendhil Mullainathan, and Ziad Obermeyer, “Predictive Modeling of U.S. Health Care Spending in Late Life,” Science, Vol. 60, No. 6396, June 29, 2018, pp. 1462–1465. References 105

Federal Hospital Insurance and Federal Supplementary Medical Insurance Trust Funds Boards of Trustees, 2012 Annual Report of the Board of Trustees of the Federal Hospital Insurance and Federal Supplementary Medical Insurance Trust Funds, 2012. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, “10-Year Treasury Constant Maturity Rate (DGS10),” webpage, updated August 19, 2020. As of August 21, 2020: https://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/DGS10 Fernandez-Lazaro, Cesar I., David P. Adams, Diego Fernandez-Lazaro, Juan M. Garcia-González, Alberto Caballero-Garcia, and Jose A. Miron-Canelo, “Medication Adherence and Barriers Among Low-Income, Uninsured Patients with Multiple Chronic Conditions,” Research in Social and Administrative Pharmacy, Vol. 15, No. 6, 2019, pp. 744–753. Finkelstein, Amy, Nathaniel Hendren, and Mark Shepard, “Subsidizing Health Insurance for Low-Income Adults: Evidence from Massachusetts,” American Economic Review, Vol. 109, No. 4, 2019, pp. 1530–1567. Finkelstein, Amy, Neale Mahoney, and Matthew J. Notowidigdo, “What Does (Formal) Health Insurance Do, and for Whom?” Annual Review of Economics, Vol. 10, August 2018, pp. 261–286. Finkelstein, Amy, and Sarah Taubman, Using Randomized Evaluations to Improve the Efficiency of US Healthcare Delivery, Cambridge, Mass.: Abdul Latif Jameel Poverty Action Lab, February 2015. Finkelstein, Amy N., Sarah L. Taubman, Heidi L. Allen, Bill J. Wright, and Katherine Baicker, “Effect of Medicaid Coverage on ED Use—Further Evidence from Oregon’s Experiment,” New England Journal of Medicine, Vol. 375, No. 16, 2016, pp. 1505–1507. Finkelstein, Amy, Sarah Taubman, Bill Wright, Mira Bernstein, Jonathan Gruber, Joseph P. Newhouse, Heidi Allen, Katherine Baicker, and the Oregon Health Study Group, “The Oregon Health Insurance Experiment: Evidence from the First Year,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 127, No. 3, August 2012, pp. 1057–1106. Flood, Sarah, Miriam King, Steven Ruggles, and J. Robert Warren, “Integrated Public Use Microdata Series, Current Population Survey: Version 4.0,” data set, University of Minnesota, 2015. Frakt, Austin B., “How Much Do Hospitals Cost Shift? A Review of the Evidence,” Milbank Quarterly, Vol 89, No. 1, March 2011, pp. 90–130. Franzini, Luisa, Chapin White, Suthira Taychakhoonavudh, Rohan Parikh, Mark Zezza, and Osama Mikhail, “Variation in Inpatient Hospital Prices and Outpatient Service Quantities Drive Geographic Differences in Private Spending in Texas,” Health Services Research, Vol. 49, No. 6, December 2014, pp. 1944–1963. 106 Analysis of the 10Plan

Fritzsche, Kate, and Sarah Masi, Federal Subsidies for Health Insurance Coverage for People Under Age 65: 2016 to 2026, Washington, D.C.: Congressional Budget Office, March 2016. Fritzsche, Kate, Kevin McNellis, and Emily Vreeland, Federal Subsidies for Health Insurance Coverage for People Under Age 65: 2019 to 2029, Washington, D.C.: Congressional Budget Office, 2019. Fronstin, Paul, and M. Christopher Roebuck, “Health Care Spending After Adopting a Full-Replacement, High-Deductible Health Plan with a Health Savings Account: A Five-Year Study,” EBRI Issue Brief, No. 388, July 2013. Getzen, Thomas E., “Health Care Is an Individual Necessity and a National Luxury: Applying Multilevel Decision Models to the Analysis of Health Care Expenditures,” Journal of Health Economics, Vol. 19, No. 2, March 2000, pp. 259–270. Greenwood-Ericksen, Margaret B., and Keith Kocher, “Trends in Emergency Department Use by Rural and Urban Populations in the United States,” JAMA Network Open, Vol. 2, No. 4, 2019. Grossman, Michael, “On the Concept of Health Capital and the Demand for Health,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 80, No. 2, March–April 1972, pp. 223–255. Hall, Mark A., Michael J. McCue, and Jennifer R. Palazzolo, “Financial Performance of Health Insurers: State-Run Versus Federal-Run Exchanges,” Medical Care Research and Review, Vol. 75, No. 3, June 2018, pp. 384–393. Haviland, Amelia M., Matthew D. Eisenberg, Ateev Mehrotra, Peter J. Huckfeldt, and Neeraj Sood, “Do ‘Consumer-Directed’ Health Plans Bend the Cost Curve Over Time?” Journal of Health Economics, Vol. 46, March 2016, pp. 33–51. Heron, Melonie, “Deaths: Leading Causes for 2017,” National Vital Statistics Reports, Vol. 68, No. 6, June 24, 2019. Himmelstein, David U., Deborah Thorne, Elizabeth Warren, and Steffie Woolhandler, “Medical Bankruptcy in the United States, 2007: Results of a National Study,” American Journal of Medicine, Vol. 122, No. 8, August 2009, pp. 741–746. Holahan, John, and Stacey McMorrow, “Slow Growth in Medicare and Medicaid Spending per Enrollee Has Implications for Policy Debates,” Urban Institute, February 11, 2019. “How Much Does Individual Health Insurance Cost?” eHealth, webpage, last updated July 10, 2020. As of September 22, 2020: https://ehealthinsurance.com/resources/individual-and-family/ how-much-does-individual-health-insurance-cost/ References 107

Hsia, Renee Y., Yaa Akosa Antwi, and Ellerie Weber, “Analysis of Variation in Charges and Prices Paid for Vaginal and Caesarean Section Births: A Cross- Sectional Study,” BMJ Open, Vol. 4, No. 1, 2014. Hurley, Jeremiah, “An Overview of the Normative Economics of the Health Sector,” in Anthony J. Culyer and Joseph P. Newhouse, eds., Handbook of Health Economics, Vol. 1A, Amsterdam: Elsevier, 2000, pp. 55–118. Internal Revenue Service, “The Premium Tax Credit - The Basics,” webpage, last updated February 18, 2020. As of August 21, 2020: https://www.irs.gov/affordable-care-act/individuals-and-families/ the-premium-tax-credit-the-basics International Federation of Health Plans, 2015 Comparative Price Report: Variation in Medical and Hospital Prices by Country, 2015. IRS—See Internal Revenue Service. Johnson, E. M., “Physician-Induced Demand,” in Encyclopedia of Health Economics, Vol. 3, Cambridge, Mass.: Elsevier, 2014, pp. 77–83. Kaiser Family Foundation, “Health Insurance Coverage of the Total Population, Timeframe: 2018,” webpage, undated. As of August 14, 2020: https://www.kff.org/other/state-indicator/total-population/?dataView=1 ¤tTimeframe=0&sortModel=%7B%22colId%22:%22Location %22,%22sort%22:%22asc%22%7D Kaiser Family Foundation, 2018 Employer Health Benefits Survey: Section 8: High- Deductible Health Plans with Savings Option, October 3, 2018. Keeler, Emmett B., and John E. Rolph, “The Demand for Episodes of Treatment in the Health Insurance Experiment,” Journal of Health Economics, Vol. 7, No. 4, December 1988, pp. 337–367. Kozhimannil, Katy B., Michael R. Law, Cori Blauer-Peterson, Fang Zhang, and J. Frank Wharam, “The Impact of High-Deductible Health Plans on Men and Women: An Analysis of Emergency Department Care,” Medical Care, Vol. 51, No. 8, 2013, pp. 639–645. Ladhania, Rahul, Amelia M. Haviland, Arvind Venkat, Rahul Telang, and Jesse M. Pines, “The Effect of Medicaid Expansion on the Nature of New Enrollees’ Emergency Department Use,” Medical Care Research and Review, 2019. Liang, Hailun, May A. Beydoun, and Shaker M. Eid, “Health Needs, Utilization of Services and Access to Care Among Medicaid and Uninsured Patients with Chronic Disease in Health Centres,” Journal of Health Services Research and Policy, Vol. 24, No. 3, July 2019, pp. 172–181. Lo Sasso, Anthony T., Lorens A. Helmchen, and Robert Kaestner, “The Effects of Consumer-Directed Health Plans on Health Care Spending,” Journal of Risk and Insurance, Vol. 77, No. 1, 2010, pp. 85–103. 108 Analysis of the 10Plan

Lo Sasso, Anthony T., Mona Shah, and Bianca K. Frogner, “Health Savings Accounts and Health Care Spending,” Health Services Research, Vol. 45, No. 4, August 2010, pp. 1041–1060. Manning, Willard G., Joseph P. Newhouse, Naihua Duan, Emmett B. Keeler, and Arleen Leibowitz, “Health Insurance and the Demand for Medical Care: Evidence from a Randomized Experiment,” American Economic Review, Vol. 77, No. 3, June 1987, pp. 251–277. Martin, Joyce A., Brady E. Hamilton, Michelle J. K. Osterman, Anne K. Driscoll, and Patrick Drake, “Births: Final Data for 2017,” National Vital Statistics Reports, Vol. 67, No. 8, November 7, 2018, pp. 1–50. Matthews, T. J., and Brady E. Hamilton, “Total Fertility Rates by State and Race and Hispanic Origin: United States, 2017,” National Vital Statistics Reports, Vol. 68, No. 1, January 2019, pp. 1–11. McCue, Michael, Mark Hall, and Xinliang Liu, “Impact of Medical Loss Regulation on the Financial Performance of Health Insurers,” Health Affairs, Vol. 32, No. 9, September 2013, pp. 1546–1551. McMorrow, Stacey, Genevieve M. Kenney, and Dana Goin, “Determinants of Receipt of Recommended Preventive Services: Implications for the Affordable Care Act,” American Journal of Public Health, Vol. 104, No. 12, December 2014, pp. 2392–2399. Mehrotra, Ateev, Tyler Brannen, and Anna D. Sinaiko, “Use Patterns of a State Health Care Price Transparency Web Site: What Do Patients Shop For?” INQUIRY, Vol. 51, 2014. Murphy, Sherry L., Jiaquan Xu, Kenneth D. Kochanek, and Elizabeth Arias, “Mortality in the United States, 2017,” NCHS Data Brief, No. 328, November 2018. National Conference of State Legislatures, “Prenatal Care,” webpage, February 2013. As of August 24, 2020: https://www.ncsl.org/research/health/prenatal-care-postcard.aspx Nikpay, Sayeh, Seth Freedman, Helen Levy, and Tom Buchmueller, “Effect of the Affordable Care Act Medicaid Expansion on Emergency Department Visits: Evidence From State-Level Emergency Department Databases,” Annals of Emergency Medicine, Vol. 70, No. 2, August 2017, pp. 215–225. Papanicolas, Irene, Liana R. Woskie, and Ashish K. Jha, “Health Care Spending in the United States and Other High-Income Countries,” Journal of the American Medical Association, Vol. 319, No. 10, March 13, 2018, pp. 1024–1039. Pauly, Mark V., “The Economics of Moral Hazard: Comment,” American Economic Review, Vol. 53, No. 3, Pt. 1, June 1968, pp. 531–537. References 109

Pendzialek, Jonas B., Dusan Simic, and Stephanie Stock, “Difference in Price Elasticities of Demand for Health Insurance: A Systematic Review,” European Journal of Health Economics, Vol. 17, 2016, pp. 5–21. Reichling, Felix, and Kent Smetters, “Budget Model: Medicare for All: Comparison of Financing Options,” research brief, January 30, 2020. As of August 20, 2020: https://budgetmodel.wharton.upenn.edu/issues/2020/1/30/ medicare-for-all-background Robinson, James C., Timothy T. Brown, and Christopher Whaley, “Reference Pricing Changes The ‘Choice Architecture’ of Health Care For Consumers,” Health Affairs, Vol. 36, No. 3, March 2017, pp. 524–530. Saloner, Brendan, Lisa Clemans Cope, Katherine Hempstead, Karin V. Rhodes, Daniel Polsky, and Genevieve M. Kenney, “Price Transparency in Primary Care: Can Patients Learn About Costs When Scheduling an Appointment?” Journal of General Internal Medicine, Vol. 32, No. 7, 2017, pp. 815–821. Shapiro R, and S. Aneja, Providing Healthcare for Americans Without Public or Private Group Insurance: The Impact of Government-Backed Self-Insurance on Participants and the Government, 2019. Smulowitz, Peter B., James O’Malley, Xiaowen Yang, and Bruce E. Landon, “Increased Use of the Emergency Department After Health Care Reform in Massachusetts,” Annals of Emergency Medicine, Vol. 64, No. 2, August 2014, pp. 107–115. Snyder, Laura, and Robin Rudowitz, “Medicaid Financing: How Does It Work and What Are the Implications?” issue brief, Kaiser Family Foundation, May 20, 2015. Sommers, Benjamin D., Robert J. Blendon, E. John Orav, and Arnold M. Epstein, “Changes in Utilization and Health Among Low-Income Adults After Medicaid Expansion or Expanded Private Insurance,” JAMA Internal Medicine, Vol. 176, No. 10, 2016, pp. 1501–1509. Sood, Neeraj, Zachary Wagner, Peter Huckfeldt, and Amelia Haviland, “Price Shopping in Consumer-Directed Health Plans,” Forum for Health Economics and Policy, Vol. 16, No. 1, 2013, pp. 1–19. Stagnitti, Marie N., Steven R. Machlin, Marc W. Zodet, and Erica Saleska, Methodology Report #32: Design, Methods, and Field Results of the Medical Expenditure Panel Survey Medical Provider Component (MEPS MPC) Including the Medical Organizations Survey (MOS)—2016 Data Year, Rockville, Md.: Agency for Healthcare Research and Quality, October 2018. Story, Giles W., Ivo Vlaev, Ben Seymour, Ara Darzi, and Raymond J. Dolan, “Does Temporal Discounting Explain Unhealthy Behavior? A Systematic Review and Reinforcement Learning Perspective,” Frontiers in Behavioral Neuroscience, Vol. 8, No. 76, 2014. 110 Analysis of the 10Plan

Taubman, Sarah L., Heidi L. Allen, Bill J. Wright, Katherine Baicker, and Amy N. Finkelstein, “Medicaid Increases Emergency-Department Use: Evidence from Oregon’s Health Insurance Experiment,” Science, Vol. 343, No. 6168, January 2, 2014, pp. 263–268. Terlizzi, Emily P., Robin A. Cohen, and Michael E. Martinez, Health Insurance Coverage: Early Release of Estimates From the National Health Interview Survey, January–September 2018, Hyattsville, Md.: National Center for Health Statistics, February 2019. U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, “R-CPI-U-RS Homepage,” webpage, last updated August 5, 2020. As of August 26, 2020: https://www.bls.gov/cpi/research-series/r-cpi-u-rs-home.htm U.S. Census Bureau, “2017 National Population Projections Tables: Main Series,” data set, 2017. U.S. Department of Homeland Security, “Table 1. Persons Obtaining Lawful Permanent Resident Status: Fiscal Years 1820 to 2017,” 2017 Yearbook of Immigration Statistics, webpage, October 2, 2018. As of August 24, 2020: https://www.dhs.gov/immigration-statistics/yearbook/2017/table1 U.S. Department of the Treasury, Income Mobility in the U.S. from 1996 to 2005, Washington, D.C., last updated March 2008. United Nations, “Mortality Projections,” data set, 2019. Whaley, Christopher M., “Provider Responses to Online Price Transparency,” Journal of Health Economics, Vol. 66, July 2019, pp. 241–259. Wharam, J. Frank, Bruce E. Landon, Fang Zhang, Stephen B. Soumerai, and Dennis Ross-Degnan, “High-Deductible Insurance: Two-Year Emergency Department and Hospital Use,” American Journal of Managed Care, Vol. 17, No. 10, October 2011, pp. e410–e418. Wherry, Laura R., and Sarah Miller, “Early Coverage, Access, Utilization, and Health Effects Associated with the Affordable Care Act Medicaid Expansions: A Quasi-Experimental Study,” Annals of Internal Medicine, Vol. 164, No. 12, June 21, 2016, pp. 795–803. White, Chapin, Paul B. Ginsburg, Ha T. Tu, James D. Reschovsky, Joseph M. Smith, and Kristie Liao, Healthcare Price Transparency: Policy Approaches and Estimated Impacts on Spending, Washington, D.C.: West Health Policy Center, May 2014. White, Chapin, and Christopher Whaley, Prices Paid to Hospitals by Private Health Plans Are High Relative to Medicare and Vary Widely, Santa Monica, Calif.: RAND Corporation, RR-3033-RWJ, 2019. As of August 21, 2020: https://www.rand.org/pubs/research_reports/RR3033.html References 111

Williams, Jackson, “Massachusetts’ ‘Price Transparency’ Resolution to Surprise Facility Fees, Consumer Protection Laws Yield to Health Care Complexity,” Health Affairs, blog post, January 10, 2019. Wolfe, Christian J., Kathryn E. Rennie, and Christopher J. Truffer, 2017 Actuarial Report on the Financial Outlook for Medicaid, Washington, D.C.: U.S. Department of Health and Human Services, Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services, 2017. Xu, Tim, Angela Park, Ge Bai, Sarah Joo, Susan M. Hutfless, Ambar Mehta, Gerard F. Anderson, and Martin A. Makary, “Variation in Emergency Department Vs Internal Medicine Excess Charges in the United States,” JAMA Internal Medicine, Vol. 177, No. 8, August 1, 2017, pp. 1139–1145. Xu, Xiao, Aileen Gariepy, Lisbet S. Lundsberg, Sangini S. Sheth, Christian M. Pettker, Harlan M. Krumholz, and Jessica L. Illuzzi, “Wide Variation Found in Hospital Facility Costs for Maternity Stays Involving Low-Risk Childbirth,” Health Affairs, Vol. 34, No. 7, July 2015, pp. 1212–1219. Yabroff, K. Robin, Jingxuan Zhao, Xuesong Han, and Zhiyuan Zheng, “Prevalence and Correlates of Medical Financial Hardship in the USA,” Journal of General Internal Medicine, Vol. 34, No. 8, May 1, 2019; pp. 1494–1502. Zeckhauser, Richard, “Medical Insurance: A Case Study of the Tradeoff Between Risk Spreading and Appropriate Incentives,” Journal of Economic Theory, Vol. 2, No. 1, March 1970, pp. 10–26. Zweifel, Peter, and Willard G. Manning, “Moral Hazard and Consumer Incentives in Health Care,” in Anthony J. Culyer and Joseph P. Newhouse, eds., Handbook of Health Economics, Vol. 1A, Amsterdam: Elsevier, 2000, pp. 409–459. C O R P O R A T I O N

he authors of this report investigate an alternative health care financing T approach, the 10Plan, for the nearly 28 million individuals who are not covered by health insurance and the approximately 20 million individuals who purchase private coverage in the nongroup health insurance market, including on the Affordable Care Act exchanges.

The 10Plan, designed by Mark Cuban, would eliminate the need for traditional health insurance for these individuals and allow them to pay only for the healthcare services that they use, and then at Medicare prices. The 10Plan is called the “10” Plan because most participants will not pay more than 10 percent of their family’s income on repayment premiums.

To protect participants from financial uncertainty stemming from healthcare events that are high-cost or beyond participants’ abilities to afford, participants in the 10Plan would be able to defer payments after a $25 copay for each encounter. In the case of deferred payments, participants would be borrowing from the federal government at a 3-percent interest rate.

In this analysis, the authors built a microsimulation model to estimate how much the 10Plan would cost participating individuals and families and what portion of the cost would be shouldered by the federal government. The authors also examine cases in which individuals could be negatively affected by the 10Plan’s implementation.

RR-4270-MC