Political Economy

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Political Economy Part 1 Aspects of the English Corporation ∵ William A. Pettigrew - 9789004387850 Downloaded from Brill.com10/01/2021 11:04:32AM via free access William A. Pettigrew - 9789004387850 Downloaded from Brill.com10/01/2021 11:04:32AM via free access Chapter 1 Political Economy William A. Pettigrew Early modern global interactions were mostly commercial in ambition. These interactions, however, were often inhibited and undermined by cultures (around the world) that remained ambivalent about commercial agendas and activities. Europeans and non-Europeans sized one another up in the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries with profound mutual suspicion expressed in re- markably similar language: both saw each other as brutal, greedy, perfidious infidels.1 Both sides believed the other to be predisposed to commercial trick- ery. For most Europeans, the trading corporation proved the main institutional vehicle for these encounters. The corporation was meant to provide manda- tory government to ensure that cross- culture commerce favoured the inter- ests of Europeans and negated the interests of untrustworthy foreigners. But corporations themselves could not fully shed their associations with intrinsic commercial perfidy. The English East India Company, for example, learnt that it could not send a merchant to serve as its representative at the Mughal Court. Company factors had advised that ‘the title of a merchant is of them despised’.2 While the end for such diplomacy was explicitly commercial, the means would have to pretend otherwise. This inherent contradiction between a trading corporation’s nationalist, governmental responsibilities and the private, profit maximizing interests of 1 Thomas Mun, Discourse of Trade (London, 1621), 8. For Non- European views of Europeans see Anthony Read, ‘Early Southeast Asian Categorizations of Europeans’ in Stuart Schwartz (ed.), Implicit Understandings: Observing, Reporting, and Reflecting on the Encounters Between Eu- ropeans and Other Peoples in the Early Modern Era (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1994), 268– 294, see esp. 287; see also Guido Van Meersbergen ‘Dutch and English Approaches to Cross- Cultural Trade in Mughal India and the Problem of Trust’ in Catia Antunes and Ame- lia Polonia (eds.), Beyond Empires: Global, Self- Organizing, Cross- Imperial Networks, 1500–1800 (Leiden: Brill, 2016), 69– 87; and Sanjay Subrahmanyam, ‘Taking Stock of the Franks: South Asian Views of Europeans and Europe, 1500–1800’, The Indian Economic and Social History Review, 42, 1, (2005): 69– 101. 2 Letters Received by the East India Company from its servants in the East [hereafter Letters Re- ceived] 6 vols. (London, 1896 – 1902), ed. F C Danvers and W Foster, Vol. 2: William Edwards to Sir Thomas Smith, 26 December 1614, 243– 44. See also Rupali Mishra, ‘Diplomacy at the Edge: Split Interests in the Roe Embassy to the Mughal Court’, Journal of British Studies, vol. 53, 1, (2014): 5– 28. © William A. Pettigrew, 2019 | DOI:10.1163/9789004387850_003 This is an open access chapter distributed under the terms of the prevailing CC-BY-NC-ND license at the time of publication. William A. Pettigrew - 9789004387850 Downloaded from Brill.com10/01/2021 11:04:32AM via free access 44 Pettigrew the merchants who largely financed and managed such companies became a foundational concern for political economists in the later eighteenth cen- tury. For Adam Smith the paradox implied ‘a strange absurdity’ in corporate political economy. For Smith, this schizophrenia of ‘sovereign’ and ‘mercan- tile’ priorities was inherent to corporate political economy: ‘As sovereigns, their interest [the East India Company’s] is exactly the same with that of the country which they govern. As merchants, their interest is directly opposite to that interest’.3 These contradictions imply – from a twenty- first century per- spective – a strange role for political economy in the careers of the English trading corporations of the late sixteenth to Smith’s day.4 Of course, the early modern mind did not always draw hard distinctions between what the modern world can distinguish as separate economic and political realms. But none- theless – the emerging and increasingly contentious and public debate about political economy – or the theory of the proper role of commercial matters within domestic and international politics – became more avowedly economic across this period. Recent and important depictions of trading corporations as governing and constitutional structures ought not to inhibit us from not- ing the influence that trading corporations had over this process of separating economic and political phenomena.5 The end result of this separation allowed for the emergence of classical economic theory and – in the context of the global interactions this volume focusses on – the belief (among Europeans at least) that ‘sweet’ commerce would facilitate mutually beneficial commercial relationships around the world (to substitute for the profound mutual suspi- cion of the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries).6 Across the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries, the terms of English thought and practice about political economy broadened from ‘civic humanist’ to the elastic, versatile languages of 3 Adam Smith, An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations (London, 1776), vol. 2, chapter 7, book 3 www.econlib.org/ library/ Smith/ smWN17.html#B.IV, Ch.7, Of Colo- nies [accessed October 3 October 2017]. 4 According to Julian Hoppit, the term political economy was first used in France in 1615 and was used infrequently prior to the 1760s. See Julian Hoppit, Britain’s Political Economies: Par- liament and Economic Life, 1660– 1800 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2017), 3. 5 On these attempts see Philip J Stern The Company- State: Corporate Sovereignty and the Ear- ly Modern Origins of the British Empire In India (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2011) and William A Pettigrew, ‘Corporate Constitutionalism and the Dialogue between the Global and Local in Seventeenth Century English History’, Itinerario, vol. 39, 3, (2015): 487 – 501. 6 On doux of sweet commerce see Albert O Hirschman, The Passions and the Intersts: Polit- ical Arguments for Capitalism before Its Triumph (New Jersey: Princeton University Press, 1997: New Edition), 56– 62. William A. Pettigrew - 9789004387850 Downloaded from Brill.com10/01/2021 11:04:32AM via free access Political Economy 45 commercial and liberal thought.7 This chapter will argue that the distinctive global sociology of trading corporations played a central role in this volte face in global political economy. Trading corporations provoked, nurtured, and focussed debates about po- litical economy. As structures that gave separate legal personality to dynamic networks of individuals, the corporation helped to absorb and shape think- ing and writing about political economy and give that writing a public role and audience. To be sure, not all paradigm shifts in political economy derived from corporate settings. The writings of Sir William Petty – a pioneer in this field – appear to owe very little to corporate issues.8 Nonetheless leading mem- bers of trading corporations – like Thomas Mun and Josiah Child and Malachy Postlethwayt became celebrated and influential political economists while established writers like Charles Davenant and Daniel Defoe supported trad- ing corporations. The companies financed large- scale state lobbying machines and pamphleteering operations to nurture these views and deploy them in defence of their privileges. As powerful and often- wealthy, privileged entities whose existence upheld controversial positions within prevailing debates about political economy, the trading corporations were central characters in these debates and their development. This chapter examines the distinctive global sociology of the trading corpo- ration through the lens of political economy. It notes how the corporate argu- ments in favour of monopoly, to take the most prominent example, remained profoundly static across the period 1550– 1750. This chapter focusses, howev- er, on certain moments of conceptual innovation that trading corporations spurred and shaped. It places the relationship between corporate activity and developing political economy into a global framework of cross- cultural inter- actions. These global corporate debates about political economy channelled the experiences of international contexts into domestic public debates and back again. In this way, corporations help us to demonstrate the global con- texts in which mercantilist doctrine emerged and altered and show us how non- Europeans peoples’ interactions with European corporations prompted and structured transnational debates about political economy. Scholars have most often associated corporate political economy with that most colligatory of early modern historians’ devices – mercantilism. Corporations 7 For an earlier statement of this view see J G A Pocock, The Machiavellian Moment: Floren- tine Political Thought and the Atlantic Republican Tradition (New Jersey: Princeton University Press, 1975), Ch xiii. 8 Ted McCormick, William Petty and the Ambitions of Political Arithmetic (Oxford: Oxford Uni- versity Press, 2009). William A. Pettigrew - 9789004387850 Downloaded from Brill.com10/01/2021 11:04:32AM via free access 46 Pettigrew articulated and upheld pillars of mercantilist doctrine as part of their special pleading in defence of their corporate privileges – especially monopoly. This in- tellectual and – for the most part
Recommended publications
  • New Working Papers Series, Entitled “Working Papers in Technology Governance and Economic Dynamics”
    Working Papers in Technology Governance and Economic Dynamics no. 74 the other canon foundation, Norway Tallinn University of Technology, Tallinn Ragnar Nurkse Department of Innovation and Governance CONTACT: Rainer Kattel, [email protected]; Wolfgang Drechsler, [email protected]; Erik S. Reinert, [email protected] 80 Economic Bestsellers before 1850: A Fresh Look at the History of Economic Thought Erik S. Reinert, Kenneth Carpenter, Fernanda A. Reinert, Sophus A. Reinert* MAY 2017 * E. Reinert, Tallinn University of Technology & The Other Canon Foundation, Norway; K. Car- penter, former librarian, Harvard University; F. Reinert, The Other Canon Foundation, Norway; S. Reinert, Harvard Business School. The authors are grateful to Dr. Debra Wallace, Managing Director, Baker Library Services and, Laura Linard, Director of Baker Library Special Collections, at Harvard Business School, where the Historical Collection now houses what was once the Kress Library, for their cooperation in this venture. Above all our thanks go to Olga Mikheeva at Tallinn University of Technology for her very efficient research assistance. Antiquarian book dealers often have more information on economics books than do academics, and our thanks go to Wilhelm Hohmann in Stuttgart, Robert H. Rubin in Brookline MA, Elvira Tasbach in Berlin, and, above all, to Ian Smith in London. We are also grateful for advice from Richard van den Berg, Francesco Boldizzoni, Patrick O’Brien, Alexandre Mendes Cunha, Bertram Schefold and Arild Sæther. Corresponding author [email protected] The core and backbone of this publication consists of the meticulous work of Kenneth Carpenter, librarian of the Kress Library at Harvard Busi- ness School starting in 1968 and later Assistant Director for Research Resources in the Harvard University Library and the Harvard College 1 Library.
    [Show full text]
  • Creating Economy: Merchants in Seventeenth-Century England
    Georgia State University ScholarWorks @ Georgia State University History Theses Department of History 12-11-2017 Creating Economy: Merchants in Seventeenth-Century England Braxton Hall Georgia State University Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarworks.gsu.edu/history_theses Recommended Citation Hall, Braxton, "Creating Economy: Merchants in Seventeenth-Century England." Thesis, Georgia State University, 2017. https://scholarworks.gsu.edu/history_theses/116 This Thesis is brought to you for free and open access by the Department of History at ScholarWorks @ Georgia State University. It has been accepted for inclusion in History Theses by an authorized administrator of ScholarWorks @ Georgia State University. For more information, please contact [email protected]. CREATING ECONOMY: MERCHANTS IN SEVENTEENTH-CENTURY ENGLAND by BRAXTON HALL Under the Direction of Jacob Selwood, PhD ABSTRACT Between 1620 and 1700, merchants in England debated the economic framework of the kingdom. The system they created is commonly referred to as ‘mercantilism’ and many historians have concluded that there was a consensus among economists that supported the balance of trade and restricted foreign markets. While that economic consensus existed, merchants also had to adopt new ways of thinking about religion, foreigners, and naturalization because of the system they created. Merchants like Josiah Child in the latter part of the seventeenth century were more acceptant of strangers and they were more tolerant of religion that their predecessors
    [Show full text]
  • Expansion and Consolidation of Colonial Power
    Expansion and Consolidation of Colonial Power Subject: History Unit: Expansion and Consolidation of Colonial Power Lesson: Expansion and Consolidation of Colonial Power Lesson Developer : Prof. Lakshmi Subramanian College/Department : Professor, Centre for Studies in Social Sciences, Kolkata Institute of Lifelong Learning, University of Delhi Expansion and Consolidation of Colonial Power Table of contents Chapter 2: Expansion and consolidation of colonial power • 2.1: Expansion and consolidation of colonial power • Summary • Exercises • Glossary • Further readings Institute of Lifelong Learning, University of Delhi Expansion and Consolidation of Colonial Power 2.1: Expansion and consolidation of colonial power Introduction The second half of the 18th century saw the formal induction of the English East India Company as a power in the Indian political system. The battle of Plassey (1757) followed by that of Buxar (1764) gave the Company access to the revenues of the subas of Bengal, Bihar and Orissa and a subsequent edge in the contest for paramountcy in Hindustan. Control over revenues resulted in a gradual shift in the orientation of the Company’s agenda – from commerce to land revenue – with important consequences. This chapter will trace the development of the Company’s rise to power in Bengal, the articulation of commercial policies in the context of Mercantilism that developed as an informing ideology in Europe and that found limited application in India by some of the Company’s officials. This found expression until the 1750’s in the form of trade privileges, differential customs payments and fortifications of Company settlements all of which combined to produce an alternative nucleus of power within the late Mughal set up.
    [Show full text]
  • "Theater and Empire: a History of Assumptions in the English-Speaking Atlantic World, 1700-1860"
    "THEATER AND EMPIRE: A HISTORY OF ASSUMPTIONS IN THE ENGLISH-SPEAKING ATLANTIC WORLD, 1700-1860" BY ©2008 Douglas S. Harvey Submitted to the graduate degree program in History and the Graduate Faculty of the University of Kansas in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy. ____________________________________ Chairperson Committee Members* ___________________________________* ___________________________________* ___________________________________* ___________________________________* Date Defended: April 7, 2008 The Dissertation Committee for Douglas S. Harvey certifies that this is the approved version of the following dissertation: "THEATER AND EMPIRE: A HISTORY OF ASSUMPTIONS IN THE ENGLISH-SPEAKING ATLANTIC WORLD, 1700-1860" Committee ____________________________________ Chairperson ___________________________________* ___________________________________* ___________________________________* ___________________________________* Date Approved: April 7, 2008 ii Abstract It was no coincidence that commercial theater, a market society, the British middle class, and the “first” British Empire arose more or less simultaneously. In the seventeenth century, the new market economic paradigm became increasingly dominant, replacing the old feudal economy. Theater functioned to “explain” this arrangement to the general populace and gradually it became part of what I call a “culture of empire” – a culture built up around the search for resources and markets that characterized imperial expansion. It also rationalized the depredations the Empire brought to those whose resources and labor were coveted by expansionists. This process intensified with the independence of the thirteen North American colonies, and theater began representing Native Americans and African American populations in ways that rationalized the dominant society’s behavior toward them. By utilizing an interdisciplinary approach, this research attempts to advance a more nuanced and realistic narrative of empire in the early modern and early republic periods.
    [Show full text]
  • Oui2.Pdf (2.141Mb)
    COLONIAL CAPITALISM AND THE DILEMMAS OF LIBERALISM: LOCKE, BURKE, WAKEFIELD AND THE BRITISH EMPIRE A Dissertation Presented to the Faculty of the Graduate School of Cornell University in Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Degree of Doctor of Philosophy by Onur Ulas Ince August 2013 © 2103 Onur Ulas Ince Colonial Capitalism and the Dilemmas of Liberalism: Locke, Burke, Wakefield and the British Empire Onur Ulas Ince, PhD Cornell University 2013 This dissertation offers a historical investigation of liberalism as a unified yet internally variegated intellectual field that has developed in relation to “colonial capitalism.” I examine the impact of colonial economic relations on the historical formation of liberalism, which is often overlooked in the scholarship on the history of political thought. Focusing on the British Empire between the late-seventeenth and early-nineteenth centuries, I analyze three historical cases in which the liberal self-image of capitalism in Britain was contradicted by the manifestly illiberal processes of displacement and coercion in its imperial possessions. I situate this contradiction within the debates on property claims in American colonies, the trade relation between Britain and its Indian dominions, and the labor problem during the colonial settlement of Australia and New Zealand. Corresponding to the three nodal questions of “property,” “exchange,” and “labor,” I analyze the works of John Locke, Edmund Burke, and Edward Gibbon Wakefield as three prominent political theorists who attempted to reconcile the liberal image of Britain as a commercial and pacific society with the illiberal processes of conquest, expropriation, and extraction of British colonialism. Highlighting the global and colonial as opposed to the national or European terrain on which modern economic relations and their political theorization have emerged, I emphasize the need to situate the history of political thought in a global context.
    [Show full text]
  • Theories of Economic System
    Theories of Global Economic System 1 • Mercantilism deals with the economic policy of the time between the Middle Ages and the age of laissez faire or as some scholars put it, 16th to 18th century (Viner, 1968; Kuhn 1963). • The period under which mercantilism held sway was not uniform in Europe. • It began and ended at quite different dates in the various countries and regions of Europe (Heckscher, 1955). • Mercantilism promoted governmental regulations of a nation’s economy for the purpose of augmenting state power at the expense of rival national powers. • It was the economic counterpart of political absolutism. • The 17th century publicists, most notably - Thomas Mun in England, Jean-Baptiste Colbert in France, and Antonio Serra in Italy – never, however, used the term themselves; it was given currency by the Scottish economist, Adam Smith in his Wealth of Nations(1776) 2 • Eli Heckscher (1955) identified the environment out of which mercantilism evolved as: – The ruin or disintegration of the universal Roman Empire – the rise and consolidation of states, limited in territory and influence though sovereign within their own borders, which grew up on the ruins of the universal Roman Empire. – Henceforth, the state stood at the centre of mercantilist endeavours as they developed historically: the state was both the subject and object of mercantilist economic policy. – The state had to assert itself in two opposing directions. On the one hand, the demands of the social institutions of the confined territories had to be defended against the universalism characteristic of the Middle Ages. On the other hand , the state had to assert its economic independence.
    [Show full text]
  • The Birth of the Political Economy Or the Economy in the Heart of Politics Jacques Fontanel, Jean-Paul Hébert, Ivan Samson
    The birth of the political economy or the economy in the heart of politics Jacques Fontanel, Jean-Paul Hébert, Ivan Samson To cite this version: Jacques Fontanel, Jean-Paul Hébert, Ivan Samson. The birth of the political economy or the economy in the heart of politics: Mercantilism. Defence and Peace Economics, Taylor & Francis (Routledge), 2008, War and Peace Issues in the History of Economic Thought, 19 (5), pp.331-338. 10.1080/10242690802354279. hal-02059663 HAL Id: hal-02059663 https://hal.univ-grenoble-alpes.fr/hal-02059663 Submitted on 6 Mar 2019 HAL is a multi-disciplinary open access L’archive ouverte pluridisciplinaire HAL, est archive for the deposit and dissemination of sci- destinée au dépôt et à la diffusion de documents entific research documents, whether they are pub- scientifiques de niveau recherche, publiés ou non, lished or not. The documents may come from émanant des établissements d’enseignement et de teaching and research institutions in France or recherche français ou étrangers, des laboratoires abroad, or from public or private research centers. publics ou privés. The birth of the political economy or the economy in the heart of politics: Mercantilism Jacques Fontanel, Jean-Paul Hébert, Ivan Samson Mercantilist theories were expressed both in doctrinal works and by concrete measures of economic policy. Mercantilism did not produce a single and immutable thought; its analyses, if not its principles, have appreciably changed over time and space. Today, some divergences still remain about the interpretation of this school, particularly with regard to the importance of the relationship between power and economic development; but this first corpus of economic thought was built through two centuries of analyses on the relationship between the power of the state and national wealth.
    [Show full text]
  • Mercantilism
    ΕΘΝΙΚΟ & ΚΑΠΟΔΙΣΤΡΙΑΚΟ ΠΑΝΕΠΙΣΤΗΜΙΟ ΑΘΗΝΩΝ ΤΜΗΜΑ ΟΙΚΟΝΟΜΙΚΩΝ ΕΠΙΣΤΗΜΩΝ ΤΟΜΕΑΣ ΠΟΛΙΤΙΚΗΣ ΟΙΚΟΝΟΜΙΑΣ Ιστορία Οικονομικών Θεωριών Νίκος Θεοχαράκης Απρίλιος 2010 Ιστοσελίδες για τον Μερκαντιλισμό Bullionists “W.S.” (John Hales d.1571, Sir Thomas Smith ) A Discourse of the Common Weal of this Realm of England, 1581 or A Compendious; Or Briefe Examination of Certayne Ordinary Complaints of Diuers of Our Countrymen in These Our Dayes (Written 1541, not by William Shakespeare despite the 1751 edition) Thomas Milles, c.1550-1627. The Customers Replie, or Second Apologie :…, An Aunswer to a confused Treatise of Publicke Commerce . in favour of the . Merchants Adventurers,' &c., 1604 Gerard de Malynes, c.1586-1641 Saint George for England Allegorically Described, 1601. A Treatise on the Canker of England's Commonwealth, 1601. Consuetudo vel Lex Mercatoria or the Ancient Law- Merchant, 1622. The Maintenance of Free Trade, 1622. The Centre of the Circle of Commerce, 1623. Ν. Θεοχαράκης, ΕΚΠΑ, ΤΟΕ, Μερκαντιλιστές 1/5 Παραδοσιακοί Μερκαντιλιστές John Wheeler, c.1553-1611. Treatise on Commerce, 1601 Edward Misselden, 1608-1654. Free Trade and the Means to Make Trade Flourish, 1622 Circle of Commerce 1623. Thomas Mun, 1571-1641. A Discourse of Trade from England unto the East- Indies, 1621. in England's Treasure by Forraign Trade, 1664. (Written 1628) facsimile Lewis Roberts, 1596 – 1640 The Merchantes Mappe of Commerce , 1638 The Treasure of Traffike, 1640 John Locke, 1632-1704. A Letter Concerning Toleration, 1689. Two Treatises on Government, 1690. An Essay Concerning Human Understanding, 1690. pt 2 Some Considerations of the Consequences of the Lowering of Interest and Raising the Value of Money, 1692 Further Considerations Concerning Raising the Value of Money, 1695.
    [Show full text]
  • William Petty in Boston: Political Economy, Religion, and Money in Provincial New England
    William Petty in Boston: Political Economy, Religion, and Money in Provincial New England Mark Valeri Early American Studies: An Interdisciplinary Journal, Volume 8, Number 3, Fall 2010, pp. 549-580 (Article) Published by University of Pennsylvania Press For additional information about this article http://muse.jhu.edu/journals/eam/summary/v008/8.3.valeri.html Access Provided by University of Sheffield at 11/17/10 5:06PM GMT William Petty in Boston Political Economy, Religion, and Money in Provincial New England MARK VALERI Union Theological Seminary in Virginia abstract Transformations in Puritan ideas about God’s rule in the world, or Providence, spurred the reception of formal economic theories in New England from 1680 through the 1720s. English political econo- mists such as William Petty and Charles Davenant critiqued customary notions of money and credit as they promoted England’s competition with European powers. New Englanders turned to these thinkers to inform provincial monetary policy. They imported political economy through se- rial accounts of parliamentary debates about the Bank of England, the South Sea Bubble, and trade policies, as well as through merchant hand- books and literary accounts of merchants. Religious convictions informed this receptivity. Boston clergy such as Cotton Mather and civic leaders such as Samuel Sewall understood the British Empire to be a bulwark against Catholic hegemony. Taking the works of Petty and Davenant to be descriptions of an economic order that abetted Protestant empire, they reshaped Puritan moral convictions. Once hostile to treating credit as a commodity and money as a fungible good, they embraced the latest tech- niques for exchanging credit and abandoned prohibitions against usury.
    [Show full text]
  • Intoxicants and the Invention of 'Consumption'
    This is a repository copy of Intoxicants and the invention of 'consumption'. White Rose Research Online URL for this paper: http://eprints.whiterose.ac.uk/149897/ Version: Published Version Article: Withington, P. (2019) Intoxicants and the invention of 'consumption'. Economic History Review. ISSN 0013-0117 https://doi.org/10.1111/ehr.12936 Reuse This article is distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) licence. This licence allows you to distribute, remix, tweak, and build upon the work, even commercially, as long as you credit the authors for the original work. More information and the full terms of the licence here: https://creativecommons.org/licenses/ Takedown If you consider content in White Rose Research Online to be in breach of UK law, please notify us by emailing [email protected] including the URL of the record and the reason for the withdrawal request. [email protected] https://eprints.whiterose.ac.uk/ Economic History Review, 0, 0 (2019), pp. 1–25 Intoxicants and the invention of ‘consumption’ † By PHIL WITHINGTON∗ In 1600 the word ‘consumption’ was a term of medical pathology describing the ‘wasting, petrification of things’. By 1700 it was also a term of economic discourse: ‘In commodities, the value rises as its quantity is less and vent greater, which depends upon it being preferred in its consumption’. The article traces the emergence of this key category of economic analysis to debates over the economy in the 1620s and subsequent disputes over the excise tax, showing how ‘consumption’ was an early term in the developing lexicon of political economy.
    [Show full text]
  • Josiah Child, Interest Rates, and John Locke's “For a General Naturalization”
    Modern Intellectual History (2021), 1–20 doi:10.1017/S1479244321000494 ARTICLE Josiah Child, Interest Rates, and John Locke’s “For a General Naturalization” Brian Smith* Department of Political Science and International Relations, Nazarbayev University *Corresponding author. E-mail: [email protected] (Received 13 January 2021; revised 28 March 2021; accepted 23 July 2021) Throughout the 1690s there were several high-profile parliamentary debates about lowering inter- est rates from 6 to 4 percent. Locke’s involvement in these policy debates is significant. In this period, he circulated at least one important pamphlet on this issue to various Members of Parliament. The purpose of this article is to illuminate the links between Locke’s arguments against interest rate reduction and immigration policy. Locke’s essay “For a General Naturalization” (1693) employs some of the same pro-naturalization formulations that Josiah Child uses in A New Discourse of Trade (1693), a pamphlet that was ostensibly published in support of the parliamentary proposal for lower interest rates. Even though Locke had a long his- tory with pro-naturalization arguments, the framework of his essay on naturalization is very likely an extension of those debates with Child about interest rates from 1691/2. Introduction The purpose of this article is to situate Locke’s essay “For a General Naturalization” (1693) in the wider naturalization debates of the late seventeenth century and, more specifically, the economic debates about interest rates that were taking place in the 1690s.1 While this essay represents Locke’s most direct engagement with the issue of immigration, very little is known about the circumstances surrounding it.
    [Show full text]
  • Information, Scholarship, and the East India Company Settlements 1660-1720S Winterbottom, Anna E
    Company culture: information, scholarship, and the East India Company settlements 1660-1720s Winterbottom, Anna E. The copyright of this thesis rests with the author and no quotation from it or information derived from it may be published without the prior written consent of the author For additional information about this publication click this link. https://qmro.qmul.ac.uk/jspui/handle/123456789/376 Information about this research object was correct at the time of download; we occasionally make corrections to records, please therefore check the published record when citing. For more information contact [email protected] 1 Company Culture: Information, Scholarship, and the East India Company Settlements 1660-1720s Anna E. Winterbottom Submitted for PhD examination University of London July 2010 2 ABSTRACT I explore how knowledge was created and circulated in and between the settlements of the early English East India Company. I aim: to demonstrate connections between scholarship and early colonialism; to highlight the role of non-elite actors in transferring skills and techniques; and to map global knowledge networks based on systems of patronage that cut across national, ethnic, and social boundaries. Chapter 1 uses the life of Samuel Baron, a half-Dutch, half-Vietnamese factor, spy, and broker for the EIC, client of the rulers of Siam and Tonkin, and author of the Description of Tonqueen to examine the importance of passeurs culturels or go-betweens to both the European trading companies and Asian rulers in the period and their role in transmitting geographical and ethnographic information. Chapter 2 examines the local and international botanical and medical networks of two Company surgeons in Madras, based on collections in the Natural History Museum and the surgeons' correspondence with the apothecary James Petiver.
    [Show full text]