Setting the Rules Dean Baker

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Setting the Rules Dean Baker Setting the Rules: Dean Baker in conversation with The Straddler On Monday, February 7th, The Straddler traveled to Washington, D.C. to speak with Dean Baker at the Center for Economic and Policy Research, where he is co-director. Baker, an economist, is the author of numerous books and articles which challenge the terms of debate at play in economic discourse. Beat the Press, his blog, examines how economic issues are reported in major outlets like the New York Times, Washington Post, and Wall Street Journal. His most recent book, Taking Economics Seriously (MIT Press), argues that “market fundamentalism does not exist.” Rapidly rising inequality over the past thirty years has been the result, according to this view, of “conservative restructuring of the economy, not the natural workings of the market. ” Dean Baker, February 7, 2011 There is no such thing as just “the market.” You have to set the rules. Sometimes that might be fairly simple; often it’s very complicated. The idea that there is one group of people out there that wants an absolute free market—whatever that could possibly mean—versus another group that wants regulation is silly. The real debate is about how to structure markets. In other words, what are we trying to do? What are the goals? But we have a framing that says one side is for regulation and the other side is for deregulation. And yet, rarely does the side that says it’s for deregulation actually want deregulation. Take finance as an obvious example. When they were talking about removing restrictions on financial companies in the 1990s, you didn’t find a lot of people who wanted to get rid of deposit insurance. And you didn’t see a lot of people in September of 2008 saying get the government away from me. They didn’t want to get rid of “too big to fail.” And you didn’t see them saying they wanted to get rid of access to the Fed’s discount window. So I see a story where the side that is ostensibly for deregulation isn’t really for deregulation. In the case of finance, what they want is an insurance policy without paying for it. Corporations themselves are creations of the government. You and I could have a partnership and we’re going to go do business and if we get into trouble, we get sued. But if we set up a corporation that does x, and x goes badly, we’re off the hook. We’re not liable. They go after the corporation. That’s a rule made by the government. And that might be a good rule—I’m not saying it’s a bad thing to have corporations. But the point is, you can’t tell me you’re a strict free- market libertarian and you’re for corporations. Those are inconsistent views. Take the rules of corporate governance. One of the things that I’ve argued is that the rules of corporate governance have been exploited in recent years so that to a large extent corporations are run for the benefit of top management. That’s why you get people receiving tens of millions a year and sometimes hundreds of millions a year in pay. It’s not that they’re so brilliant—in many cases they’re wrecking their companies, we saw that with the financial crisis. But they basically pick the people who are deciding their pay. Your friends are on the board, why shouldn’t they pay you tens of millions of dollars? Those are rules of corporate governance. And we could have different rules of corporate governance that would make it very difficult for, say, General Electric or Citigroup to be run first and foremost for the benefit of top management. Another example is minority shareholder protection. Say we’ve got a great idea: we’re going to take over General Electric. We’re going to get 50.1 percent of the stock and tell the remaining 49.9 percent they’re out of luck, we own the company. You can’t just do that. There are very detailed rules that protect minority shareholders. There are all sorts of rules like this. So it’s hard to imagine how you could have corporations and not have rules. Economists and journalists often get very, very sloppy with their terms. Take free trade agreements, which are anything but. Usually, a trade agreement like NAFTA, or the one we’re currently talking about negotiating with Korea, frees up investment flows. But in almost all of these agreements, there is nothing about freeing up trade in highly paid professional services. I’ve had any number of arguments with economists who tell me that there is free trade in professional services because the doctor they see was born in India. It’s kind of the Mexican avocado theory of international trade. I can go to the grocery store and get an avocado that was grown in Mexico. Have I now proved that we have free trade in agriculture? Of course not. There are all sorts of restrictions, and the reality is that it’s very difficult for a person who was trained in India, even trained to U.S. standards, to come here and work as a doctor. And that’s quite deliberate. Now, if instead of focusing on making it easier for us to produce our cars, our steel, our textiles in Mexico or India, we wanted to make it easier for someone in India or China or whatever country it is to get the skills, train to our levels, learn English if they don’t know it, and come here and work as a doctor, we’d get lower cost health care. We’d have doctors who were willing to work for much less than the doctors that we have in the United States. But no free trade economists are interested in that. All big proponents of free trade who talk about lowering the wages of auto workers and textile workers don’t talk about lowering the wages of doctors, lawyers, and economists. They don’t want to talk about that. They can’t even think about that. So there’s this terminology of free trade that is picked up by economists and reporters, and behind it is this very important substantive point: what we’re calling free trade is pushing down the wages of a substantial segment of the workforce relative to those who are still protected. Now, there are a couple of issues here related to immigration. Some types of labor are space specific. So if we want people to pick crops in Ohio, they have to be in Ohio to do that. If we want to import finished products from Mexico, people can stay in Mexico. So that obviously brings up the issue of immigration. When we talk about the number of immigrants who come into the country it’s usually separated out from trade agreements. Very few people are willing to say, okay, we’re just going to have open borders, and I’m sympathetic to that because that would mean you’d have hundreds of millions of people coming to the United States because it’s a very attractive place relative to a lot of poorer countries. But the other issue is, insofar as you do have immigrants coming here, what are the terms on which they’re coming? The discussions about this haven’t always been totally honest. The fact that you have a lot of immigrants in low-wage areas—well, that’s because we let them in. You have a lot of people in the United States who want to blame the immigrants for driving down wages, but if you want to blame someone, blame the employers. This is conscious policy. Everyone in government knew that there were millions of people working in restaurants, working in people’s houses as nannies or gardeners or housekeepers.That wasn’t a secret. It was conscious policy to allow that. There’s interesting economic research on this. A lot of the research says many of these immigrants don’t compete with U.S. workers. Now, I’m skeptical of some of this research for reasons not worth going into, but accepting it at face value, the implication is that you’ve developed an underclass which is so far below U.S. wage standards that these jobs are no longer competing. That means two things. One is that we have this underclass—we’ve brought in people who are earning at a level that is so low that even our people who don’t graduate high school are not competing. Another point is that people who didn’t graduate high school used to have a lot of those jobs. So if we’ve brought in so many immigrants that the wages are so low that people who didn’t graduate high school won’t take them, that’s hardly reassuring. Still, you get this very strange discussion where people talk about a labor shortage. But if you believe in a market, what the market is telling you is that you have to raise wages. But instead of people saying raise wages, they say there’s a shortage. Of course, if you raise wages, costs go up. I sometimes make a joke: I can’t get a doctor to treat me for twenty bucks an hour. So is there a shortage of doctors? No, you have to pay a doctor more than twenty dollars an hour. It’s the same thing with restaurants.
Recommended publications
  • Mark Weisbrot Most Recent Work Is Social Security: the Phony Crisis
    I Mark W elsbrot Page 1 of 2 Mark Weisbrot Mark Weisbrot received his Ph.D. in economics from the University of Michigan, with specialization in international economics and political economy. He is author of “Globalization for Whom?” (Vol. 3 1, #3, 1998 Cornell International Law Journal) and co-authored “Writing the ConstitNtion of-3 Single Global Economy : A Concise Guide to the MA1 (Multilateral Agreement on Investment)“, (Washington, D.C. : Preamble Center,1997). He was a consultant to the Government of Haiti during the presidency of Jean-Bertrand Aristide. His most recent work is Social Security: The Phony Crisis, co-authored with Dean Baker (1999, University of Chicago Press). He is currently Research Director at the Preamble Center, and a research associate with the Economic F’glicy_!Is&tgt_e, both in Washington, D.C. His opinion p&es have appeared in the Los Angeles Times, the Boston Globe, the San Francisco Chronicle, the Chicago Tribune, and many other newspapers throughout the country. He has appeared on numerous television networks including CNN, PBS’ Nightly Business Report, Fox News, and a variety of other talk shows. RECENT PUBLICATIONS: “Globalization for Whom?” (Vol. 3 1, #3, 1998 Cornell International Law Journal) “Recent Experiences with International Financial Markets: Lessons for the Free Trade Area of the Americas,” with Neil Watkins, (Washington, D.C.: Preamble Center/CIEL, 1999) Social Security: The Phony Crisis, with Dean Baker (1999, University of Chicago Press) “The Impact of the MAI on Employment,Gro.~~l,ld lnconle r)i_~sibblion” (Washington, D.C. : Preamble Center, 1997) “Writing the Constitution of a Single Global Economy : A Concise Guide to the MAY, with Michelle Sforza and Scott Nova (Washington.
    [Show full text]
  • Robert Pollin, Ph.D
    Curriculum Vitae: Thomas Herndon November 2015 Placement Director: Robert Pollin, Ph.D. (413) 577-0126 [email protected] Thomas Herndon Ph.D. Candidate Department of Economics and Political Economy Research Institute University of Massachusetts Amherst Thompson Hall, Amherst, MA 01003, U.S.A. Tel: 512-669-8263 Email: [email protected] Education Ph.D. in Economics, University of Massachusetts Amherst. Expected completion date: Summer 2016 B.A. in Political Economy, The Evergreen State College, 2007 Awards John Kenneth Galbraith Prize for Dissertation Research. 2014. Department of Economics, University of Massachusetts Amherst. Leading 100 Global Thinkers. 2013. Foreign Policy. Albert O. Hirschmann “Albie” Award for Best Writing in Global Political Economy. 2013. Foreign Policy. Bostonian of the Year Honorable Mention. 2013. Boston Globe. Primary Fields: Political Economy, Macroeconomics, Money and Banking, Applied Econometrics, Heterodox Approaches to Economics Dissertation Title: Three Essays on U.S. Household Debt and the Sources of Financial Fragility Committee: . Robert Pollin (Chair), University of Massachusetts Amherst . Michael Ash, University of Massachusetts Amherst . Arindrajit Dube, University of Massachusetts Amherst . Gerald Epstein, University of Massachusetts Amherst . Jennifer Taub, Vermont Law School Publications Herndon, Thomas, Michael Ash, and Robert Pollin. 2014. “Does High Public Debt Consistently Stifle Economic Growth? A Critique of Reinhart and Rogoff.” Cambridge Journal of Economics 38 (2) pp. 257-279.
    [Show full text]
  • Who Are These Economists, Anyway?
    mm-T&A09GalbraithSF.qxp:Layout 1 11/10/09 3:40 PM Page 85 Who Are These Economists, Anyway? by James K. Galbraith Of course, there were exceptions to these trends: a few economists challenged the assumption of rational behavior, questioned the belief that financial markets can be trusted and pointed to the long history of financial crises that had devastating economic consequences. But they were swimming against the tide, unable to make much headway against a pervasive and, in retrospect, foolish complacency. —Paul Krugman, New York Times Magazine , September 6, 2009 Amen. While normal ecclesiastic practice places this word at the end of the prayer, on this occa - sion it seems right to put it up front. In two sentences, Professor Paul Krugman, Nobel Laureate in Economics for 2008 and in some ways the leading economist of our time, has summed up the failure of an entire era in economic thought, practice, and policy discussion. And yet, there is something odd about the role of this short paragraph in an essay of over 6,500 words. It’s a throwaway. It leads nowhere. Apart from one other half-sentence, and three passing mentions of one person, it’s the only discussion—the one mention in the entire essay— of those economists who got it right. They are not named. Their work is not cited. Their story remains untold. Despite having been right on the greatest economic question of a generation—they are unpersons in the tale. Krugman’s entire essay is about two groups, both deeply entrenched at (what they believe to be) the top of academic economics.
    [Show full text]
  • Why Is Productivity Growth So Low? 23 Economic Experts Weigh In
    Economic Forecasts from the World's Leading Economists undated Why is productivity growth so low? 23 economic experts weigh in Productivity is considered by some to be the most important area of economics and yet one of the least understood. Its simplest definition is output per hour worked, however, productivity in the real world is not that simple. Productivity is a major factor in an economy’s ability to grow and therefore is the greatest determinant of the standard of living for a given person or group of people. It is the reason why a worker today makes much more than a century ago, because each hour of work produces more output of goods and services. According to Ian Stewart, Deloitte’s Chief Economist, “It is hard to overstate the importance of productivity in driving improvements in living standards. Since 1850, UK GDP per head has risen 20-fold, transforming our standards of living. If productivity had remained flat over that period, GDP per head would only have doubled.” What is worrying about productivity today is that data shows that it has been growing at a snail's pace for the better part of a decade, having been deteriorating steadily dating all the way back to the 1970s. Just last month Christine Lagarde, Managing Director of the IMF, said in a speech that if “productivity growth had followed its pre-crisis trend, overall GDP in advanced economies would be about 5 percent higher today” and that “another decade of weak productivity growth would seriously undermine the rise in global living standards.“ Why is productivity growth dropping? The OECD has written extensively on the subject of productivity growth observing that productivity is pro-cyclical, meaning that in times of recession productivity tends to fall and in times of economic growth, productivity tends to increase.
    [Show full text]
  • Dean Baker 1
    ce pr Briefing Paper Center for Economic and Policy Research The Run-up in Home Prices: Is It Real or Is It Another Bubble? By Dean Baker 1 Center for Economic and Policy Research 1611 Connecticut Avenue, NW Suite 400 Washington, D.C. 20009 tel: 202-293-5380 fax: 202-588-1356 www.cepr.net 1 Dean Baker is co-Director of the Center for Economic and Policy Research. Andrea Blatchford, Debayani Kar, and Mark Weisbrot assisted with comments, research and/or the editing of this paper. Executive Summary In the last seven years home purchase prices have risen nearly 30 percent more than the rate of inflation. This run-up in housing prices has increased housing wealth by more than $2.6 trillion compared to a situation in which home prices had just kept place with inflation. This is an average of more than $35,000 of additional wealth for each of the nation’s 73.3 million homeowners. This paper examines whether the increase in home prices can be grounded in fundamental economic factors, or whether it is simply a bubble, similar to the stock market bubble. The paper notes: 1) There has been no clear upward trend in housing costs relative to other items in the post-war period. In general, housing prices move in step with the overall rate of inflation. This means that the recent spurt in housing prices is a departure from the prior history. 2) There is no clear link between the pace of income growth and the share of housing in consumption.
    [Show full text]
  • Kenneth Rogoff Harvard University October 1, 2013
    FAQ on Herndon, Ash and Pollin's Critique of "Growth in a Time of Debt" Kenneth Rogoff Harvard University October 1, 2013 On April 16, 2013, University of Massachusetts scholars Thomas Herndon, Michael Ash and Robert Pollin (HAP) released a paper claiming to find mission-critical coding errors in my 6- page 2010 American Economic Association proceedings note with Carmen Reinhart, that constituted our first explicit work on debt and growth. (We received their paper on the same day.) They suggested that their results called for a sweeping reassessment of “austerity” in the United States and Europe. As this FAQ shows, they make a number of claims based on misrepresentation, selective omission, and failure to cite the literature, including our later work, and the large body of supporting work by other scholars, as well as work by earlier critics. (1) Did our first 2010 paper contain a mistake? Yes, it contains a coding error that omits some countries from the overall averages. However, as HAP correctly state in the main body of their paper, and our Errata correction confirms, the coding error has relatively minor quantitative consequences. Most of the quantitative difference they highlight in one result is due to a different weighting scheme. Importantly, the coding error does not carry over to our main paper on growth and debt, “Public Debt Overhangs” (2012, joint with Vincent Reinhart), which is much longer and more complete. The 2012 paper appears as a full journal article, not as a conference proceedings note. Our 2012 paper, which HAP do not cite, had long superseded our short May 2010 paper in academic and policy research discussions, as noted for example in the June 2013 Bank for International Settlements annual report.
    [Show full text]
  • The Scorecard on Development: 25 Years of Diminished Progress
    Economic & Social Affairs DESA Working Paper No. 31 ST/ESA/2006/DWP/31 September 2006 The Scorecard on Development: 25 Years of Diminished Progress Mark Weisbrot, Dean Baker, and David Rosnick Abstract Th is paper examines data on economic growth and various social indicators and compares the past 25 years (1980-2005) with the prior two decades (1960-1980). Th e paper fi nds that the past 25 years in low- and middle-income countries have seen a sharp slowdown in the rate of economic growth, as well as a decline in the rate of progress on major social indicators including life expectancy and infant and child mortality. Th e authors conclude that economists and policy-makers should devote more eff ort to determining the causes of the economic and development failure of the last quarter-century. JEL Classifi cation: O10, O40, O11 Keywords: economic development, growth, social indicators, growth failure, developing countries, education, health Mark Weisbrot is Co-Director of the Center for Economic and Policy Research in Washington, D.C., e-mail: [email protected]. He received his Ph.D. in economics from the University of Michigan. He is co-author, with Dean Baker, of Social Security: Th e Phony Crisis (University of Chicago Press, 2000), and has written numerous research papers on economic policy. Dean Baker is a macroeconomist and Co-Director of the Center for Economic and Policy Research in Washington, D.C., e-mail: [email protected]. He previously worked as a senior economist at the Economic Policy Institute and an assistant professor at Bucknell University.
    [Show full text]
  • Download the Transcript
    TRADE-2019/02/01 1 THE BROOKINGS INSTITUTION SAUL/ZILKHA ROOM KIMBERLY CLAUSING: THE PROGRESSIVE CASE FOR FREE TRADE AND GLOBALIZATION Washington, D.C. Friday, February 1, 2019 PARTICIPANTS: Introduction and moderator: DAVID WESSEL Senior Fellow and Director, Hutchins Center on Fiscal and Monetary Policy The Brookings Institution Presentation: KIMBERLY CLAUSING Thormund Miller and Walter Mintz Professor of Economics Reed College Panelists: KIMBERLY ELLIOTT Visiting Fellow Center for Global Development SOUMAYA KEYNES U.S. Economics Editor The Economist LORI WALLACH Director, Global Trade Watch Public Citizen * * * * * ANDERSON COURT REPORTING 1800 Diagonal Road, Suite 600 Alexandria, VA 22314 Phone (703) 519-7180 Fax (703) 519-7190 TRADE-2019/02/01 2 P R O C E E D I N G S MR. WESSEL: Good morning. Welcome to Brookings and the Hutchins Center on Fiscal and Monetary Policy. I'm impressed to see that all of you have braved what passes for a blizzard in Washington. (Laughter) I want to assure you we have plenty of facilities here if you get trapped because we have an inch and a half of snow. We can take care of you for a few hours. I'm very pleased today to be helping celebrate Kim Clausing's new book, "Open: The Progressive Case for Free Trade, Immigration and Global Capital." The timing couldn't be better. We are, I think since the -- even before the last presidential election, engaged in a huge debate about whether globalization, immigration, free trade, flows of global capital are (a) responsible for everything good that's happened to the U.S.
    [Show full text]
  • The Us Labor Market Questions and Challenges for Public Policy
    THE US LABOR MARKET QUESTIONS AND CHALLENGES FOR PUBLIC POLICY Dean Baker Martin Feldstein Bhash Mazumder George J. Borjas Jason Furman Robert A. Moffitt Richard V. Burkhauser & Betsey Stevenson Casey B. Mulligan & Mary C. Daly Harry J. Holzer Pia M. Orrenius Peter Cappelli Glenn Hubbard & Madeline Zavodny Miles Corak Melissa S. Kearney Timothy M. Smeeding Tyler Cowen Robert Z. Lawrence Justin Wolfers Edited by Michael R. Strain AMERICAN ENTERPRISE INSTITUTE THE US LABOR MARKET QUESTIONS AND CHALLENGES FOR PUBLIC POLICY Dean Baker Martin Feldstein Bhash Mazumder George J. Borjas Jason Furman Robert A. Moffitt & Betsey Stevenson Richard V. Burkhauser Casey B. Mulligan & Mary C. Daly Harry J. Holzer Pia M. Orrenius Peter Cappelli Glenn Hubbard & Madeline Zavodny Miles Corak Melissa S. Kearney Timothy M. Smeeding Tyler Cowen Robert Z. Lawrence Justin Wolfers Edited by Michael R. Strain AMERICAN ENTERPRISE INSTITUTE ISBN-13: 978-0-8447-5007-1 (hardback) ISBN-10: 0-8447-5007-7 (hardback) ISBN-13: 978-0-8447-5008-8 (paperback) ISBN-10: 0-8447-5008-5 (paperback) ISBN-13: 978-0-8447-5009-5 (ebook) ISBN-10: 0-8447-5009-3 (ebook) © 2016 by the American Enterprise Institute. All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be used or reproduced in any man- ner whatsoever without permission in writing from the American Enterprise Institute except in the case of brief quotations embodied in news articles, critical articles, or reviews. The views expressed in the publications of the American Enterprise Institute are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the staff, advisory panels, officers, or trustees of AEI.
    [Show full text]
  • Asset Returns and Economic Growth
    DEAN BAKER Center for Economic and Policy Research J. BRADFORD DELONG University of California, Berkeley PAUL R. KRUGMAN Princeton University Asset Returns and Economic Growth IT is difficult to see how real U.S. GDP growth can be as rapid in the next half-century as it has been in the last. The baby boom is long past, and no similar explosion of fertility to boost the rate of labor force growth from natural increase has occurred since or is on the horizon. The modern feminist revolution is two generations old: no reservoir of potential female labor remains to be added to the paid labor force. Immigration will doubt- less continue—the United States is likely still to have only one-twentieth of the world’s population late in this century and to remain vastly richer than the world on average—but can immigration proceed rapidly enough to make the labor force grow as fast in the next fifty years as it did in the past fifty? Productivity growth, the other possible source of faster GDP growth, is a wild card: although we find very attractive the arguments of Robert Gordon for rapid future productivity growth,1 his is not the con- sensus view; this is shown most strikingly by the pessimistic projection of the Social Security trustees that very long run labor productivity growth will average 1.6 percent a year.2 A slowing of the rate of real economic growth raises challenges for the financing of pay-as-you-go social insurance systems that rely on a rapidly expanding economy to provide generous benefits for the elderly at relatively low tax rates on the young.
    [Show full text]
  • DEMOGRAPHIC TIDAL WAVES and OTHER MYTHS: SOCIAL SECURITY and MEDICARE Mark Weisbrot
    WEISBROT.DOC 6/20/2001 3:54 PM DEMOGRAPHIC TIDAL WAVES AND OTHER MYTHS: SOCIAL SECURITY AND MEDICARE Mark Weisbrot In this article based on his Elder Law Journal Lecture, presented March 1, 2001, at the University of Illinois College of Law, Mr. Weisbrot dispels the myths that Social Mark Weisbrot is currently Co-Director of the Center for Economic and Policy Re- search, in Washington, D.C. He writes a weekly column on economic and policy is- sues that is distributed to over 400 newspapers by Knight-Ridder/Tribune Media Services. His opinion pieces have appeared in the Washington Post, the Los Angeles Times, the Boston Globe, and the Chicago Tribune, among others. He has appeared on CNN, ABC World News Tonight, C-SPAN Washington Journal, Fox News, and many other national and local television and radio programs. Mr. Weisbrot received his Ph.D. in economics from the University of Michigan, with specialization in international economics and political economy. He has written on these topics for both academic and nonacademic publications. He was a consultant to the government of Haiti in 1995–96. He is coauthor, with Dean Baker, of Social Secu- rity: The Phony Crisis (University of Chicago Press, 2000) and author, most recently, of “One Year After Seattle: Globalization Revisited” (CEPR 2000); “Globalization for Dummies” (Harpers’ Magazine, May 2000); and coauthor of “The Emperor Has No Growth: Declining Economic Growth Rates in the Era of Globalization,” with Robert Naiman and Joyce Kim (Washington, D.C.: CEPR, 2000) The author would like to thank Dean Baker for his years of work on Social Security, stock market returns, and other issues, much of which is cited in this article.
    [Show full text]
  • NEOLIBERALISM, GLOBALIZATION, and INEQUALITIES Consequences for Health and Quality of Life
    NEOLIBERALISM, GLOBALIZATION, AND INEQUALITIES Consequences for Health and Quality of Life Edited by Vicente Navarro POLICY, POLITICS, HEALTH AND MEDICINE SERIES Vicente Navarro, Series Editor Baywood Publishing Company, Inc. Amityville, New York Contents Introduction 1 Vicente Navarro PART I What Is Neoliberalism? 1. Neoliberalism as a Class Ideology; Or, The Political Causes of the Growth of Inequalities 9 Vicente Navarro PART II Neoliberalism, Globalization, and the Welfare State 2. Is Globalization Undermining the Welfare State? The Evolution of the Welfare State in Developed Capitalist Countries during the 1990s 27 Vicente Navarro, John Schmitt, and Javier Astudillo 3. The Future of the Welfare State: Crisis Myths and Crisis Realities. 69 Francis G. Castles PART III The Growth of Inequalities 4. Should We Worry About Income Inequality? 95 Robert Hunter Wade 5. The Causes of Increasing World Poverty and Inequality; Or, Why the Matthew Effect Prevails 119 Robert Hunter Wade 6. Is Globalization Reducing Poverty and Inequality? 143 Robert Hunter Wade PART IV Consequences of Neoliberalism and Globalization for Health and Quality of Life 7. The Scorecard on Development: 25 Years of Diminished Progress. 179 Mark Weisbrot, Dean Baker, and David Rosnick v vi / Neoliberalism, Globalization, Inequalities 8. The World Health Situation 203 Vicente Navarro PART V European Integration and Its Consequences for Health and Quality of Life 9. Economic Efficiency versus Social Equality? The U.S. Liberal Model versus The European Social Model 215 Vicente Navarro and John Schmitt 10. Is the United States a Good Model for Reducing Social Exclusion in Europe? 233 John Schmitt and Ben Zipperer PART VI The Liberal Model in the United States and Its Social Consequences 11.
    [Show full text]