Chicago Workshop on Black–White Inequality: a Summary by Derek A

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Chicago Workshop on Black–White Inequality: a Summary by Derek A ESSAYS ON ISSUES THE FEDERAL RESERVE BANK APRIL 2007 OF CHICAGO NUMBER 237a Chicago Fed Letter Chicago Workshop on Black–White Inequality: A summary by Derek A. Neal, professor of economics, University of Chicago, and consultant, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago The Chicago Workshop on Black–White Inequality, funded by the Searle Freedom Trust, meets on a semiannual basis to explore the causes and consequences of economic inequality between blacks and whites in the U.S. On December 15, 2006, the second meeting of the workshop was hosted by the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago. During most of the twentieth century, looked at the effects of several govern- each successive generation of black ment policies on skill development in Americans came closer than their pre- children, as well as the measurement decessors to matching the educational challenges faced by social scientists who achievement and economic success of seek to quantify changes in the black– their white peers. However, the conver- white skill gap. gence in skills among children and in labor market success among adults stalled Education policy around 1990. The Chicago Workshop Education policy is at the forefront of Materials presented at the on Black–White Inequality is an effort many discussions of inequality in the to explore the reasons for the recent United States. The ongoing debate sur- December 15, 2006, meeting lack of progress for blacks relative to rounding the No Child Left Behind Act of the workshop are available whites. Workshop meetings focus par- of 2001 (NCLB) highlights the public at http://economics.uchicago. ticular attention on the black–white perception that disadvantaged commu- edu/Inequality_Workshop/ gaps in reading, math, and other basic nities, especially disadvantaged minority skills that appear to play such a large communities, receive poor service from Schedule_dec15.shtml. role in sustaining economic inequality. their public schools. Much recent re- Because the economy of the twenty- search on skill differences between black first century places a high premium on and white youth seeks to understand cognitive skills, black–white economic the relative importance of black–white inequality will persist as long as these differences in family resources and skill gaps persist. school quality as contributing factors to the skill gap. A first step in this re- Workshop meetings involve presentations, search is understanding how this skill prepared discussant remarks, and gen- gap changes as black and white children eral discussion among leading economists move through school. Numerous studies and other social scientists from around document that the black–white skill gap the country, as well as a core working is quite large when children enter school. group of six scholars, of whom I am one. If the gap widens as children age, we The other five are: James Heckman, cannot be sure that schools are playing Steven Levitt, and Kerwin Charles from a large role because differences in family the University of Chicago; Greg Duncan resources may exacerbate the gap even from Northwestern University; and as black and white children progress Roland Fryer from Harvard University. through the same school. However, if In this Chicago Fed Letter, I summarize the gap is stable as children progress the workshop’s second meeting, which through school, then differences in school quality are neither closing nor scores from each particular scale are the size of the black–white skill gap and widening the skill gap as children age. transformed into standardized units how it changes as students mature, but it While such a result would not imply that such that the mean score is zero and the also tackled how current policy decisions improving schools in minority neigh- overall standard deviation is one in each may affect the skills of disadvantaged chil- borhoods would do little to close the year. These results highlight the need dren, especially disadvantaged children black–white skill gap, it would imply that for better ways to describe the relative in minority communities. Congress will the current gap is not primarily the progress of black children. Because test take up the reauthorization of NCLB in result of any black–white disparities in scores have no natural units, Reardon’s 2007, and this debate is at the center of public school quality. presentation demonstrated that some current policy discussions concerning claims about the gap between black and strategies for improving the performance Measuring progress white children in terms of basic skills of public schools in disadvantaged com- One might assume that documenting could rest on arbitrary choices of the munities. Two cornerstones of NCLB are the facts about the relative progress of scale used to report the test scores. He that schools should be judged by student black children during school is a fairly did not have access to either the Texas performance on standardized tests and straightforward task. Black children or North Carolina data and thus could that students should have the option to either fall further behind their white not be sure that scaling choices played choose a different public school if the test peers as they progress through school a role in creating different results for the scores in their current school are consis- or not. However, the existing literature two states. However, his analyses raise tently below state proficiency standards. on this topic does not provide clear a broad methodological challenge for Two presentations examined the likely answers, and the first session of the education research. Researchers must consequences of these policy priorities. workshop meeting demonstrated that be able to discuss the size of skill gaps The first by Justine Hastings, Yale Uni- this issue is more perplexing than some in terms of a meaningful metric. In re- versity, and Douglas Staiger, Dartmouth might imagine. Scholars made presen- cent research, working group member College, used data from a public school tations based on administrative data James Heckman has argued for methods choice experiment in North Carolina from different states. Eric Hanushek, that seek to express skill gaps in terms to examine the determinants of school Stanford University, and Steven Rivkin, of the expected difference in potential choice decisions. They reported that public school choice programs are often most valuable for families that are white Because test scores have no natural units, it has been demon- and economically advantaged because strated that some claims about the gap between black and the best public schools tend to be pre- white children in terms of basic skills could rest on arbitrary dominately white and geographically distant from disadvantaged neighbor- choices of the scale used to report test scores. hoods. During the initial years of NCLB, there have been persistent problems Amherst College, used administrative adult earnings available to people of with students not being able to exercise data to show that in Texas public schools, different skill levels. In my capacity as their right to public school choice be- the standardized achievement gap be- workshop director, I have argued that cause the best public schools often face tween black and white students grows social scientists should focus more on excess demand. The work presented by substantially during elementary school. measures of skill gaps that describe how Hastings and Staiger suggests that, even In contrast, Charles Clotfelter, Duke members of one group rank in the skill if the best public schools are forced to University, presented results using data distribution of the other group. The expand to take in students from failing from North Carolina that suggested amount of overlap between two distri- schools, these high-performing schools the achievement gap between black butions of scores focuses on how a set will often be located far away from dis- and white children is large but constant of test scores ranks students from the advantaged communities, making it dif- between third grade and eighth grade. most to least proficient. Descriptions of ficult for students from such communities relative ranks and the overlap between to change schools. This feature of NCLB The subsequent discussion of the two the distributions of scores for two groups stands in stark contrast to voucher plans presentations highlighted many factors provide important information concern- or proposals to expand the number of that complicate these calculations, but ing how two different groups perform charter schools that are allowed. Both Sean Reardon, Stanford University, made with respect to a particular skill, and voucher plans and the expansion of the most telling point. Reardon dem- this information does not rely on any charters provide mechanisms for new onstrated that conclusions concerning arbitrary notion of scale for the scores. schools to open in communities with whether or not black children are fall- schools that are currently failing to meet ing further behind white children as they Recommendations for future policy the NCLB standards for test score perfor- progress through school can be greatly The workshop’s second meeting dealt mance. Nonetheless, Hanushek correctly affected by the scale used to measure not only with basic issues concerning pointed out that NCLB does expand test scores. Further, this is true even when resources available to disadvantaged However, once this announcement is of such a system will not be easy because, students
Recommended publications
  • Freakonomics: a Rogue Economist Explores the Hidden Side of Everything
    Freakonomics: A Rogue Economist Explores the Hidden Side of Everything By Steven D. Levitt and Stephen J. Dubner New York City, William Morrow 2005 242pp, $51.95, ISBN 0 06 073132X The University of Chicago has a tradition of producing economists that push the boundaries of the discipline. This is the school that nurtured innovative and iconoclastic thinkers such as Milton Friedman (on macroeconomic stabilisation policy), Robert Lucas (on the use of ‘rational’ rather than Keynesian ‘adaptive’ expectations) and Gary Becker (on the economics of the family). Steven Levitt and his journalist co-author, Stephen Dubner, appear to be following this tradition by publishing a book that deals with a range of topics that do not fall within the realm of mainstream economics—hence the book’s title. Freakonomics can best be described as a sort of Bill Bryson guide to applied social science. It considers a number of disparate behavioural phenomena and seeks to make sense of them, sometimes drawing on economic hypotheses but always relying heavily on data. It is the emphasis on data that is the book’s strongest feature. Levitt and Dubner discuss innovative techniques for identifying match-rigging by sumo wrestlers, cheating by Chicago school teachers, the impact of parents on children’s school test scores and other diverse topics. The approach used to test sumo match-rigging is especially fascinating and is compulsory reading for anyone planning to sit a graduate job interview for McKinsey. Levitt and Dubner explain that the top wrestlers compete in tournaments six times a year. Each tournament comprises fifteen matches.
    [Show full text]
  • Measuring the Impact of Crack Cocaine
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES MEASURING THE IMPACT OF CRACK COCAINE Roland G. Fryer, Jr. Paul S. Heaton Steven D. Levitt Kevin M. Murphy Working Paper 11318 http://www.nber.org/papers/w11318 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 May 2005 We would like to thank Jonathan Caulkins, John Donohue, Lawrence Katz, Glenn Loury, Derek Neal, Bruce Sacerdote, Sudhir Venkatesh, and Ebonya Washington for helpful discussions on this topic. Elizabeth Coston and Rachel Tay provided exceptional research assistance. We gratefully acknowledge the financial support of Sherman Shapiro, the American Bar Foundation, and the National Science Foundation. The views expressed herein are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research. ©2005 by Roland G. Fryer, Paul S. Heaton, Steven D. Levitt, and Kevin M. Murphy. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. Measuring the Impact of Crack Cocaine Roland G. Fryer, Paul S. Heaton, Steven D. Levitt, and Kevin M. Murphy NBER Working Paper No. 11318 May 2005 JEL No. J00 ABSTRACT A wide range of social indicators turned sharply negative for Blacks in the late 1980s and began to rebound roughly a decade later. We explore whether the rise and fall of crack cocaine can explain these patterns. Absent a direct measure of crack cocaine’s prevalence, we construct an index based on a range of indirect proxies (cocaine arrests, cocaine-related emergency room visits, cocaine- induced drug deaths, crack mentions in newspapers, and DEA drug busts).
    [Show full text]
  • THE WHITE/BLACK EDUCATIONAL GAP, STALLED PROGRESS, and the LONG-TERM CONSEQUENCES of the EMERGENCE of CRACK COCAINE MARKETS William N
    THE WHITE/BLACK EDUCATIONAL GAP, STALLED PROGRESS, AND THE LONG-TERM CONSEQUENCES OF THE EMERGENCE OF CRACK COCAINE MARKETS William N. Evans, Craig Garthwaite, and Timothy J. Moore* Abstract—We propose the rise of crack cocaine markets as a key explana- Figure 1A contains the race-specific high school completion tion for the end to the convergence in black-white educational outcomes in the United States that began in the mid-1980s. After constructing a rates for cohorts turning 18 between 1965 and 1997, while measure to date the arrival of crack markets in cities and states, we show figure 1B shows the white-black difference in these rates. that the decline in educational outcomes for black males begins with the Several features of the data are remarkable. First, the gap in start of the crack epidemic. We also show that there are higher murder and incarceration rates after the arrival of crack cocaine and that these are completion rates fell by 37% between 1965 and 1986, predictive of lower black high school completion rates, a result consistent decreasing from 15.3 to 9.6 percentage points. Second, with human capital theory. We estimate that effects related to crack mar- almost all of the convergence is due to rising black achieve- kets can account for approximately 40% to 70% of the fall in black male high school completion rates. ment—the completion rates of whites changed little over this period. Third, the convergence ends around 1986, and white- I. Introduction black completion rates diverge until 1997, when the gap was 14.4 percentage points.
    [Show full text]
  • Guns and Violence: the Enduring Impact of Crack Cocaine Markets on Young Black Males*
    GUNS AND VIOLENCE: THE ENDURING IMPACT OF CRACK COCAINE MARKETS ON YOUNG BLACK MALES* WILLIAM N. EVANS CRAIG GARTHWAITE TIMOTHY J. MOORE UNIVERSITY OF NOTRE DAME NORTHWESTERN UNIVERSITY PURDUE UNIVERSITY AND NBER, AND J-PAL AND NBER AND NBER December 2018 Abstract The emergence of crack cocaine markets in the 1980s brought a wave of violence to US cities that has repercussions today. Using cross-city variation in crack’s arrival and the experience of older cohorts, we estimate that the murder rate of young black males doubled soon after these markets were established, and that their rate was still 70 percent higher 17 years later. Using the fraction of gun-related suicides as a proxy for gun availability, we find that access to guns explains both the rise in young black males' murder rates after crack’s arrival and their elevated murder rates today. The authors wish to thank Michael Smith and Timothy Seida for excellent research assistance, and for seminar participants at Auburn University, Harvard University, Northwestern University, University of Georgia, University of Nebraska, Vanderbilt University, and University of Notre Dame for a number of helpful suggestions. Moore acknowledges financial support from an Australian Research Council fellowship (Discovery Early Career Research Award DE170100608). 0 1. Introduction Compared to other developed countries, the United States stands alone in its shockingly high murder rate. In 2015, the U.S. murder rate was 5.5 murders per 100,000 people, which is more than three times the rate of France, Canada, and the United Kingdom, and more than five times the rate of Italy, Germany and Spain.1 Despite being high relative to other developed countries, the U.S.
    [Show full text]
  • Lionel Robbins on Economic Generalizations and Reality in the Light of Modern Econometrics
    Economica (2009) 76, 873–890 doi:10.1111/j.1468-0335.2009.00805.x Robbins on Economic Generalizations and Reality in the Light of Modern Econometrics By ROGER E. BACKHOUSEw and STEVEN N. DURLAUFz wUniversity of Birmingham and Erasmus University Rotterdam zUniversity of Wisconsin–Madison Final version received 27 February 2009. This paper examines Lionel Robbins’ critical attitude towards formal empirical work from the standpoint of modern econometrics. It argues that his attitude towards empirical work rested on indefensible assumptions and that he failed to realise that the role he saw for empirical work undermined his belief in the primacy of economic theory. This matters because Robbins’ attitudes are echoed in modern economics, best exemplified by the calibration methodology of Kydland and Prescott, which is vulnerable to similar criticisms. INTRODUCTION Economists take widely different positions on the role that empirical evidence should play in the development of substantive propositions. Contemporary macroeconomics is split between those who give primacy to theory, whether they employ calibration methods to link theory to data (Edward Prescott) or regard theory and econometrics as complementary (Lars Hansen and Thomas Sargent), and those who regard atheoretical analyses as fundamental (Christopher Sims).1 Similar disagreements exist within microeconomics. On the microeconometrics side, one finds competing paradigms between James Heckman, whose work focuses on the use of economic assumptions to account for self-selection and heterogeneity, those who adopt the essentially statistical assumptions employed in Donald Rubin’s causal model, and Charles Manski’s emphasis on asking what may be learned under minimal assumptions of any type. Other microeconomic research, for example Steven Levitt’s work on crime, focuses on the identification of natural experiments, so that econometric analysis is reduced to a trivial role.
    [Show full text]
  • The Economics Of...Sumo Wrestling
    RESEARCHSPOTLIGHT The Economics of…Sumo Wrestling BY AARON STEELMAN f you asked a random person on the street what economists “The key institutional feature of sumo wrestling that study, you might get a response like inflation or unemployment. makes it ripe for corruption is the existence of a sharp non- IThe reason is pretty clear: such macroeconomic issues are crucially linearity in the payoff function for competitors,” the authors important and do, in fact, occupy the attention of many economists, write. A sumo tournament involves 66 wrestlers competing including those in the Federal Reserve System. But there is a group in 15 bouts each. A wrestler who has a winning record—that of microeconomists who are grappling with many issues beyond is, who has won at least 8 of his 15 matches—is guaranteed what is normally thought of as the purview of economics—issues to rise in the rankings, while a wrestler who has a losing such as crime, divorce, and abortion, among others. record is destined to fall. A wrestler’s rank determines his The pioneer in this regard is University of Chicago econo- prestige, salary, and the perks that he enjoys. For instance, mist Gary Becker. Among his best-known books are The Eco- the lowest-ranked wrestlers must rise early each morning to nomics of Discrimination (1957), The Economic Approach to Human clean the building and prepare meals. Behavior (1976), and A Treatise on the Family (1981). These books There is a strong incentive, then, to achieve that eighth apply the tools of economic analysis to issues that had long been victory in a tournament.
    [Show full text]
  • Curriculum Vitae for PAUL HEATON September 2020 CONTACT INFORMATION Address
    Curriculum Vitae for PAUL HEATON September 2020 CONTACT INFORMATION Address: University of Pennsylvania Law School 3501 Sansom St. Philadelphia, PA 19104 E-mail: [email protected] Phone: (215) 746-3353 Fax: (215) 573-2025 EMPLOYMENT University of Pennsylvania Carey Law School Senior Fellow July 2015- Academic Director, Quattrone Center for the Fair Administration of Justice July 2015- RAND Corporation Adjunct Economist July 2015- Senior Economist June 2013-July 2015 Economist Nov. 2010-June 2013 Associate Economist June 2007-Nov. 2010 Director, RAND Institute for Civil Justice Oct. 2012-July 2015 Acting Director, RAND Law, Business and Regulation Apr. 2012-Oct. 2012 Director for Research, RAND Institute for Civil Justice Oct. 2010-Apr. 2012 Professor, Pardee RAND Graduate School Sep. 2008-July 2015 OTHER PROFESSIONAL ACTIVITIES Member, Board of Advisors, UC-Berkeley/UC-Irvine Civil Justice Research Initiative Feb. 2017-present EDUCATION Ph.D, Economics, University of Chicago June 2007 Thesis Title: Essays on Crime and Corruption Thesis Committee: Steven Levitt (chair), Gary Becker, Kevin M. Murphy M.A, Economics, University of Chicago Dec. 2003 B.A, Economics, Summa Cum Laude and University Honors, Brigham Young University Dec. 2001 ARTICLES AND PEER-REVIEWED RAND REPORTS a. Criminal Justice/Drug Policy “Improving Pretrial Outcomes Without Actuarial Risk Assessment”, Indiana Law Journal (forthcoming). “A Natural Experiment to Test the Effect of Sanction Certainty and Celerity on Substance-Impaired Driving: North Dakota's 24/7 Sobriety Program” with Greg Midgette, Beau Kilmer, and Nancy Nicosia, Journal of Quantitative Criminology (forthcoming). CV for Paul Heaton--Page 1 of 7 “The Expansive Reach of Pretrial Detention” North Carolina Law Review 98: 369-377 (February 2020).
    [Show full text]
  • Loading “Print” 07/07/2005 03:42 PM
    Loading “Print” 07/07/2005 03:42 PM the dismal science A Roshanda by Any Other Name How do babies with super-black names fare? By Steven D. Levitt and Stephen J. Dubner Posted Monday, April 11, 2005, at 3:32 AM PT Which is more dangerous: a gun or a swimming pool? How much does campaign spending really matter? What truly made crime fall in the 1990s? These are the sort of questions raised—and answered—in the new book Freakonomics: A Rogue Economist Explores the Hidden Side of Everything. In today's excerpt, the first of two, authors Steven D. Levitt and Stephen J. Dubner explore the impact of a child's first name, particularly a distinctively black name. Tomorrow's excerpt shows how names work their way down the socioeconomic ladder. It has been well established that we live in an age of obsessive, even competitive, parenting. The typical parent is led to believe that her every move will greatly influence her child's future accomplishments. This belief expresses itself in the first official act a parent commits: giving the baby a name. Many parents seem to think that a child will not prosper unless it is hitched to the right one; names are seen to carry great aesthetic and even predictive powers. This might explain why, in 1958, a New York City father named Robert Lane decided to call his baby son Winner. The Lanes, who lived in a housing project in Harlem, already had several children, each with a fairly typical name. But this boy—well, Robert Lane apparently had a special feeling about him.
    [Show full text]
  • Understanding Why Crime Fell in the 1990S: Four Factors That Explain the Decline and Six That Do
    Journalof Economic Perspectives—Volume 18,Number 1—Winter 2004 — Pages163– 190 UnderstandingWhy Crime Fellin the 1990s:Four Factors that Explainthe Declineand Six that DoNot Steven D.Levitt rimefell sharply inthe United States in the 1990s, in all categories of crimeand allparts ofthe nation. Homiciderates plunged 43 percentfrom C thepeak in 1991 to 2001, reaching the lowest levels in 35 years. The FederalBureau of Investigation’s (FBI)violent and propertycrime indexes fell 34 and 29percent, respectively, over that sameperiod. These declines occurred essentiallywithout warning: leadingexperts were predicting an explosionin crime intheearly and mid-1990s,precisely the point when crimerates began to plunge. Although expertsfailed to anticipate the decline, there has beenno shortage ofhypotheses toexplain the drop incrimeafter the fact. Table1 presentsa tallyof aLexis-Nexissearch ofthe most frequently cited reasons forthe crime decline in articlesin major newspapers overthe period 1991– 2001. The single most frequent explanationgiven is the innovative policing strategies put intoplace. Thecrime declineis also frequentlyattributed to increased imprisonment, changes inthe marketfor crack cocaine, theaging of the population, toughergun controllaws, thestrong economy and increasesin the number of police. In this paper, Iattemptto sort out why crimedeclined in the 1990s. I begin witha reviewof the facts. Ithen analyzethe leading explanations forwhy crime fell, lookingat possibledeterminants that changed insome substantial wayin the1990s. Most ofthe supposed explanations listedin Table1 actuallyplayed little direct role inthecrime decline, including the strong economy of the 1990s, changing demo- graphics, betterpolicing strategies, gun controllaws, concealedweapons lawsand increaseduse ofthedeath penalty. Fourfactors, however,can account forvirtually y Steven D.Levittis theAlvin H.Baum Professorof Economics, University of Chicago, and ResearchFellow, AmericanBar Foundation,both in Chicago, Illinois.
    [Show full text]
  • John A. List Interview
    INTERVIEW John A. List In the 1950s, Vernon Smith — then teaching at Purdue University and influenced by the work of Edward Chamberlin, one of his instructors at Harvard University — began conducting experiments to see how people responded to various market incentives and structures in a laboratory-type environment. At first, many economists questioned the importance of those experiments’ results. But by the 1970s, others, including Charles Plott of the California Institute of Technology, began using experiments to better understand decisionmaking in various market settings, and in 2002 Smith was awarded the Nobel Prize in economics along with the psychologist Daniel Kahneman of Princeton University. In the mid-1990s, John List, who believed that experimental work had provided unique insights into human behavior, began conducting experiments of his own, but in the field rather than in the lab. By setting up carefully designed experiments with people performing tasks they are used to doing as part of their daily lives, List has been able to test how people behave in natural settings — and whether that behavior is consistent with economic theory. List’s field experiments, like Smith’s lab experiments, were initially greeted with skepticism by many economists, but that has changed over time. RF: Could you briefly describe what you mean when you List has published more than 150 articles in refereed speak about field experiments in economics — and what academic journals during the last 15 years, many on field methodological issues should economists be concerned experiments and related work. with in order to do field experiments well? List began his career at the University of Central Florida, with stops at the University of Arizona and the List: A good place to start is to think about how economists University of Maryland before arriving at the University have used measurement tools in the past.
    [Show full text]
  • What Can Be Done to Improve Struggling High Schools?
    Journal of Economic Perspectives—Volume 27, Number 2—Spring 2013—Pages 133–152 What Can Be Done To Improve Struggling High Schools? Julie Berry Cullen, Steven D. Levitt, Erin Robertson, and Sally Sadoff he task faced by high schools is perhaps the most diffi cult in all of educa- tion. High schools not only are charged with preparing students for college, T but also with serving the needs of the many students who will directly enter the workforce. High schools have to offer greater portfolios of options and sort students appropriately across those options. At the same time, compared with lower grade levels, high schools inherit student bodies with more discrepant abili- ties and competing outside options and infl uences uences (for (for example, example, Clotfelter, Clotfelter, Ladd, Ladd, and Vigdor 2009; Cascio and Staiger 2012). The balancing act is all the more chal- lenging at disadvantaged high schools, where resources are of lower quality and more scarce. The National Center for Education Statistics (Aud et al. 2012) provides a wealth of data showing that many US high schools are struggling. Across all public schools, only around 75 percent of students graduate on time, and approximately 8 percent of students drop out of high school altogether. In large urban school districts, like Chicago, New York City, and Los Angeles, cohort graduation rates hover around 60 to 65 percent. In the lowest income quintile, dropout rates are four times greater than in the highest income quintile. These statistics are especially shocking since ■ Julie Berry Cullen is Associate Professor of Economics, University of California–San Diego, La Jolla, California.
    [Show full text]
  • A Summary of Artefactual Field Experiments on Fieldexperiments.Com
    A SUMMARY OF ARTEFACTUAL FIELD EXPERIMENTS ON FIELDEXPERIMENTS.COM: THE WHO’S, WHAT’S, WHERE’S, AND WHEN’S John A. List1 July 2019 Back in January of this year I provided some data on all field experiments that were published on a website that I started nearly 20 years ago. Back then, I was trying to provide a service in the spirit of what Charlie Holt did for laboratory experiments. Charlie’s site compelled me to create my own bibliographical site http://www.fieldexperiments.com, which lists publications and discussion papers in experimental economics that make use of the "field" in some manner. The site remains quite active, with an open source that allows scholars to post their own work, and to download hundreds of field experimental papers. In my own work I have reserved the term "field experiment" for those cases where I observed subjects in their naturally occurring environments. I explicitly, therefore, discriminated between explorations in this environment and laboratory studies that used non-standard subject pools. In a JEL paper (Harrison and List, 2004), such important differences are accounted for via qualifiers. I followed this nomenclature on the site by placing studies into three groups: 1. Artefactual field experiments, which are the same as conventional lab experiments but with a non-standard subject pool (i.e., non-students). Running Peruvian borrowers through lab games (Karlan, 2005 AER) would be an example of an artefactual field experiment. 2. Framed field experiments, which are identical to artefactual field experiments but with field context in either the commodity, task, or information set that the subjects use.
    [Show full text]