Saving and the Real Interest Rate in Developing Countries

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Saving and the Real Interest Rate in Developing Countries Saving and the Real Interest Rate in Developing Countries JONATHAN D. OSTRY AND CARMEN M. REINHART to stimulate saving is unlikely to be success- rates. This feature of credit markets in the \AISING real interest ful in the poorest developing countries, least developed countries may itself make where consumption choices are heavily influ- saving less responsive to interest rates. rates has often been enced by subsistence considerations. Indeed, Another reason that might explain the cited as a way to the evidence suggests that the interest rate failure of existing studies to detect signifi- IN sensitivity of saving to real rates of return cant effects of interest rates on household I increase private saving, rises with a country's income level. Hence, saving in developing countries relates to the and thus provide the resources the same policies undertaken in different fact that—particularly in the poorest coun- countries could produce very different out- tries—subsistence considerations are likely for growth. But this may not be comes, depending on the country's level of to be a significant factor determining con- a viable approach in the development. sumption behavior. Given that, to be able to poorest developing countries, in save, households must first achieve a subsis- Is saving responsive? tence consumption level, the interest rate sen- which most people live at the There is little consensus in the empirical sitivity of private saving will be close to zero subsistence level. literature on the interaction between saving for countries where a large share of the popu- and the real rate of interest in developing lation lives at or near subsistence consump- countries. Some studies have concluded that, tion levels. Indeed, a subsistence model for a large number of developing countries, would predict a nonlinear relationship How does private saving respond to changes there does not appear to be any systematic between saving behavior and the level of in real interest rates in developing countries? relationship between rates of return and con- development, with the most significant The answer will influence judgments about sumption/saving behavior; others have sug- changes occurring when countries move from the effectiveness of a range of policies. For gested that there may be considerable low-income to low-middle-income status, and example, financial liberalizations, which gen- regional variation in this elasticity. relatively minor changes between middle- erate higher real interest rates, will result in One reason may simply be the poor qual- income and high-income countries. Of course, greater savings by households only if the lat- ity of the data in general and, more specifi- the interest rate sensitivity of saving could be ter decide to defer consumption; in other cally, the fact that there is considerable low even in middle-income countries if the words, if the sensitivity of consumption and variation in the economic significance and income distribution were sufficiently skewed saving to higher interest rates is significant. informational content of the data on real so that a large proportion of the population Similarly, when fiscal policy shocks con- rates of return. Lack of sophistication and lived at or near subsistence levels. tribute to movements in domestic interest depth in domestic financial markets or direct A frequently used proxy for the impor- rates, their impact on the external current regulation may result in interest rates that tance of subsistence in household budgets is account will depend on how responsive pri- do not adequately reflect expectations about the budget share going to food. It is indeed vate saving is to changes in real rates of the underlying economic fundamentals. In noteworthy that food consumption accounts return. many low-income developing countries, for a markedly lower share of total expendi- In this article, we present some evidence to there are few banks, and there is little scope ture in high-income than in low-income coun- suggest that raising domestic interest rates for true market determination of interest tries. As shown in Table 1, food consumption Jonathan D. Ostry, Carmen M. Reinhart, a Canadian national, is a Senior Economist in the IMF's Southeast Asia and a US national, is an Economist in the IMF's Western Hemisphere Department. Pacific Department. 16 Finance & Development / December 1995 ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution income developing countries, and the fact that tries than among the Latin American coun- Table 1 Food as a share of expenditure 1 the share of subsistence in total con- tries in the sample, despite similar income lev- (1990)' sumption—perhaps proxied by the food els. The more equitable income distribution share—declines as income increases. The sec- that characterizes the Asian countries may be Country groupings Percent ond prediction may also be related to subsis- a factor behind those differences. Institutional Low-income 55.6 tence considerations, since incentives to save arrangements (such as pension funds), which Lower-middle-income 32.1 over time should affect only that portion of the play a more prominent role in several Asian Upper-middle-income 30.5 budget left over after subsistence has been countries, may also be conducive to fostering High-income 13.0 achieved, that is, discretionary income. higher saving rates. Source: Judith Jones Putnam and Jane A. Allshouse, Among countries in various income groups, The role of real interest rates in saving Food Consumption, Prices and Expenditures, United the patterns of saving rates that emerge are behavior is more difficult to gauge. One prob- States Department of Agriculture, Statistical Bulletin No. 867. broadly consistent with the predictions of the lem—which is particularly important in 1 Expenditure on food as a percent of total personal subsistence model. As Table 2 shows, private Africa—is that financial markets remain thin expenditure. For details of the countries included in each country grouping, see World Bank, World saving is, on average, considerably lower for and governments often set interest rates at Development Report 1994: Infrastructure for the poorest developing countries, where the nonmarket levels. Nevertheless, there is some Development, Washington, DC, 1994. saving rate is about one half that of the high- evidence that financial saving increased as a 2 Data refer to averages for each country grouping. income group. In fact, such differences also result of the increase in real interest rates appear within regions. World Bank data show associated with liberalization of financial mar- that median gross domestic saving as a per- kets in developing countries, both in Africa accounts for an average of 13 percent of total centage of GDP (1987-91 average) was 5.6 per- and elsewhere. For example, increases in sav- expenditure in high-income countries and for cent for low-income African countries and 19 ing rates have been associated with higher only 8 percent of total consumption in the percent for middle-income African countries. real interest rates in Indonesia and the United States. For middle-income countries, Average gross domestic saving for both Republic of Korea and, more recently, in such as Mexico and Thailand, the share is groups was 7.7 percent of GDP. Argentina, Chile, and Pakistan. There is also often 30-40 percent while, for the poorest Furthermore, the relationship between the some evidence that reform programs in countries, the share of food is over 50 percent; level of income and the saving rate appears to Africa—which caused real interest rates to it is in the 60-70 percent range in some coun- be nonlinear, as the largest increases in saving move from sharply negative to mildly positive tries, such as Sierra Leone and Sudan. The rates occur in the transition from low- to levels—were successful in mobilizing domes- very sharp differences in food expenditure lower-middle-income levels, where the average tic savings. across countries with different per capita personal saving rate rises by 5.5 percentage income levels suggests that subsistence con- points. The average for the upper-middle- Empirical findings siderations may indeed be important in under- income countries is still 2.8 percentage points When households are assumed to maximize standing saving behavior, particularly in above that of the lower-middle-income group, utility, or welfare, subject to a resource con- low-income developing countries. but there appears to be relatively little differ- straint, the interest-rate sensitivity of house- There are, however, additional reasons why ence between the average saving rates in the hold saving depends on how easily saving may be less responsive to changes in high-income and upper-middle-income coun- households can substitute future consumption real interest rates in low-income than in mid- tries in the sample. for current consumption (technically known dle-income countries. Some have argued that It is noteworthy that liquidity constraints as the intertemporal elasticity of substitution low-income countries are characterized by and precautionary motives for saving could (IBS) in consumption). If a given change in pervasive liquidity constraints, which implies produce the opposite pattern in saving rates. real interest rates induces large shifts in con- that changes in consumption will be heavily If poor consumers cannot borrow but face sumption, then the IBS—one of the parame- influenced by changes in current income, an uncertain income stream, the demand ters describing household preferences—will rather than by changes in rates of return. for precautionary saving rises. Hence, the liquidity-con- Table 2 Savings and income straint/precautionary saving Income and personal saving rates Subsistence considerations offer two main hypothesis would predict that it predictions about saving behavior. First, sav- is the poorest consumers, who GNP per adult Personal saving as in 1985 dollars a percentage of GDP ing rates should increase with the level of real have no access to credit mar- Country groupings (1980-87 average) (1985-93 average) income at the initial stages of development, kets, who would save the most.
Recommended publications
  • REP21 December 1974
    World Bank Reprint Series: Number Twenty-one REP21 December 1974 Public Disclosure Authorized V.V. Bhatt Some Aspects of Financial Policies and Central Banking in Developing Countries Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Reprinted from World Development 2 (October-December 1974) World Development Vol.2, No.10-12, October-Deceinber 1974, pp. 59-67 59 Some Aspects of Financial Policies and Central Banking in Developing Countries V. V. BHATT Economic Development Institute of the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development mechanism and agency as provided by the existence of a Central Bank. What needs special emphasis at an international level is the rationale and urgency of evolving a sound financial structure through the efficient performance of the twin interrelated functions-as promoters and as regulators of the financial system-by Central Banks. 1. SOME ASPECTS OF FINANCIAL POLICIES .. ~~~The main object of this Section is to show the Economic development is not only facilitated but its . pace is quickened by the appropriate development of the significance of saving and flow-of-funds analysis as an financial system--structure of financial institutions, indicator of a set of financial policies-policies relating instruments and interest rates.1 to the structure of financial institutions, instruments and Instrumentsand interest rates.r interest rates-essential for resource mobilization and In any strategy of development, therefore, it is allocation consistent with a country's development essential to emphasize the evolution of a sound and . 6 c well-integrated financial system from the point of view objectives. In a large number of developing countries, the only both of resource mobilization and efficient allocation.2 reliable data available for understanding the trends in the In Section I of this paper, an attempt is made to economy and for policy purposes relate to monetary delineate the broad contours of a set of financial policies flows and the balance of payments.
    [Show full text]
  • Saving in a Financial Institution
    SAVING IN A FINANCIAL INSTITUTION i Silverback Consultants Ltd acknowledges the contributions of: Somkwe John-Nwosu Chinyere Agwu Nene Williams Temiloluwa Bamigbola The Consumer Protection Department of The Central Bank of Nigeria. Hajiya Khadijah Kasim Edited by Hajiya Umma Dutse Copyright © 2017 All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced, distributed, or transmitted in any form or by any means, including photocopying, recording, or other electronic or mechanical methods, without the prior written permission of the publisher, except in the case of brief quotations embodied in critical reviews and certain other non-commercial uses permitted by copyright law. ISBN This material was produced by the Consumer Protection Department of the Central Bank of Nigeria in Collaboration with Silverback Consultants Ltd. 1 01 Introduction 02 Importance of Saving 03 Where to Save Saving at Home (Advantages and Disadvantages) Saving in a Bank and Other Financial Institutions Types of Banks and Other Financial Institutions 04 How to Save What to Consider in Choosing a Bank or Other Financial Institutions Types of Accounts Operating Bank Accounts Electronic Payment Channels 05 Managing Accounts Reconciling Account Complaints Protecting Banking Instruments Protecting Electronic Transactions Rights and Responsibilities of a Bank Customer 06 Conclusion 07 Frequently Used Banking Terms 2 01. Introduction Almost everyone has an idea of what is saving and must have saved in one form or another. This could be towards buying something needed or towards a future project such as building a house, paying school fees, marriage, hospital bills, repay loans or simply for a rainy day. People set aside certain amounts or engage in contributions (esusu, adashe).
    [Show full text]
  • Some Unpleasant Monetarist Arithmetic Thomas Sargent, ,, ^ Neil Wallace (P
    Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review Some Unpleasant Monetarist Arithmetic Thomas Sargent, ,, ^ Neil Wallace (p. 1) District Conditions (p.18) Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review vol. 5, no 3 This publication primarily presents economic research aimed at improving policymaking by the Federal Reserve System and other governmental authorities. Produced in the Research Department. Edited by Arthur J. Rolnick, Richard M. Todd, Kathleen S. Rolfe, and Alan Struthers, Jr. Graphic design and charts drawn by Phil Swenson, Graphic Services Department. Address requests for additional copies to the Research Department. Federal Reserve Bank, Minneapolis, Minnesota 55480. Articles may be reprinted if the source is credited and the Research Department is provided with copies of reprints. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis or the Federal Reserve System. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review/Fall 1981 Some Unpleasant Monetarist Arithmetic Thomas J. Sargent Neil Wallace Advisers Research Department Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis and Professors of Economics University of Minnesota In his presidential address to the American Economic in at least two ways. (For simplicity, we will refer to Association (AEA), Milton Friedman (1968) warned publicly held interest-bearing government debt as govern- not to expect too much from monetary policy. In ment bonds.) One way the public's demand for bonds particular, Friedman argued that monetary policy could constrains the government is by setting an upper limit on not permanently influence the levels of real output, the real stock of government bonds relative to the size of unemployment, or real rates of return on securities.
    [Show full text]
  • Perceived Financial Preparedness, Saving Habits, and Financial Security CFPB Office of Research
    Perceived Financial Preparedness, Saving Habits, and Financial Security CFPB Office of Research SEPTEMBER 2020 The Consumer Financial Protection Bureau’s (CFPB, the Bureau) Start Small, Save Up initiative aims to promote the importance of building a basic savings cushion and saving habits among U.S. consumers as a pathway to increased financial well-being and financial security.1 Having a savings cushion or a habit of saving can help consumers feel more in control of their finances and allow them to weather financial shocks more easily. Indeed, previous research shows that many consumers experience financial shocks, and that savings can help buffer against shocks and provide financial security.2 Further, previous research has also found a relationship between savings and financial well-being that suggests that having savings can help consumers feel more financially secure.3 This brief uses data from the Bureau’s Making Ends Meet survey to explore consumers’ savings- related behaviors, experiences, and outcomes. We examine subjective experiences primarily as they relate to financial well-being and feelings of control over finances,4 while consumers’ objective financial situations are explored using self-reported responses to questions about difficulty paying bills, saving habits, and money in checking and savings accounts. Focusing on these and other financial factors, such as income, allows us to better understand how consumers 1 This Office of Research research brief (No. 2020-2) was written by Caroline Ratcliffe, Melissa Knoll, Leah Kazar, Maxwell Kennady, and Marie Rush. 2 McKernan, Ratcliffe, Kalish, and Braga (2016); Mills et al. (2016); Mills et al. (2019); Ratcliffe, Burke, Gardner, and Knoll (2020).
    [Show full text]
  • The-Great-Depression-Glossary.Pdf
    The Great Depression | Glossary of Terms Glossary of Terms Balanced budget – Government revenues equal expenditures on an annual basis. (Lesson 5) Bank failure – When a bank’s liabilities (mainly deposits) exceed the value of its assets. (Lesson 3) Bank panic – When a bank run begins at one bank and spreads to others, causing people to lose confidence in banks. (Lesson 3) Bank reserves – The sum of cash that banks hold in their vaults and the deposits they maintain with Federal Reserve banks. (Lesson 3) Bank run – When many depositors rush to the bank to withdraw their money at the same time. (Lesson 3) Bank suspensions – Comprises all banks closed to the public, either temporarily or permanently, by supervisory authorities or by the banks’ boards of directors because of financial difficulties. Banks that close under a special holiday declaration and remained closed only during the designated holiday are not counted as suspensions. (Lesson 4) Banks – Businesses that accept deposits and make loans. (Lesson 2) Budget deficit – When government expenditures exceed revenues. (Lesson 4) Budget surplus – When government revenues exceed expenditures. (Lesson 4) Consumer confidence – The relationship between how consumers feel about the economy and their spending and saving decisions. (Lesson 5) Consumer Price Index (CPI) – A measure of the prices paid by urban consumers for a market basket of consumer goods and services. (Lesson 1) Deflation – A general downward movement of prices for goods and services in an economy. (Lessons 1, 3 and 6) Depression – A very severe recession; a period of severely declining economic activity spread across the economy (not limited to particular sectors or regions) normally visible in a decline in real GDP, real income, employment, industrial production, wholesale-retail credit and the loss of overall confidence in the economy.
    [Show full text]
  • Inter-Relationship Between Economic Growth, Savings and Inflation in Asia
    Inter-Relationship between Economic Growth, Savings and Inflation in Asia 著者 Chaturvedi Vaibhav, Kumar Brajesh, Dholakia Ravindra H. 出版者 Institute of Comparative Economic Studies, Hosei University journal or Journal of International Economic Studies publication title volume 23 page range 1-22 year 2009-03 URL http://hdl.handle.net/10114/3628 Journal of International Economic Studies (2009), No.23, 1–22 ©2009 The Institute of Comparative Economic Studies, Hosei University INTER-RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN ECONOMIC GROWTH, SAVINGS AND INFLATION IN ASIA Vaibhav Chaturvedi 1 Brajesh Kumar 2 Ravindra H. Dholakia 3 Abstract The present study examines the inter- relationship between economic growth, saving rate and inflation for south-east and south Asia in a simultaneous equation framework using two stage least squares with panel data. The relationship between saving rate and growth has been found to be bi-directional and positive. Inflation has a highly significant negative effect on growth but positive effect on saving rate. Inflation is not affected by growth but is largely determined by its past values, and saving rate is not affected by interest rate. These findings for countries in Asia with widely divergent values of aggregates are very relevant for develop- ment policies and strategies4. JEL classification: C33; E21; E31; E60; O57 Keywords: Growth; Savings; Inflation; Asia; Simultaneity; Fixed-Effect 1. Introduction Growth experience in south-east and south Asia has generated keen interest among econ- omists and policy makers for the last two decades. Numerous macroeconomic factors affect- ing economic growth like inflation, savings, foreign exchange rate, etc. have widely varying values across these nations and so also their economic growth.
    [Show full text]
  • Does Monetarism Retain Relevance?
    Economic Quarterly—Volume 98, Number 2—Second Quarter 2012—Pages 77–110 Does Monetarism Retain Relevance? Robert L. Hetzel he quantity theory and its monetarist variant attribute significant reces- sions to monetary shocks. The literature in this tradition documents T the association of monetary and real disorder.1 By associating the oc- currence of monetary disorder with central bank behavior that undercuts the working of the price system, quantity theorists argue for a direction of causa- tion running from monetary disorder to real disorder.2 These correlations are robust in that they hold under a variety of different monetary arrangements and historical circumstances. Nevertheless, correlations, no matter how robust, do not substitute for a model. As Lucas (2001) said, “Economic theory is mathematics. Everything else is just pictures and talk.” While quantity theorists have emphasized the importance of testable implications, they have yet to place their arguments within the standard workhorse framework of macroeconomics—the dynamic, stochastic, general equilibrium model. This article asks whether the quantity theory tradition, which is long on empirical observation but short on deep theoretical foundations, retains relevance for current debates. Another problem for the quantity theory tradition is the implicit rejection by central banks of its principles. Quantity theorists argue that the central bank is responsible for the control of inflation. It is true that at its January 2012 meeting, the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) adopted an in- flation target. However, the FOMC did not accompany its announcement with The author is a senior economist and research adviser at the Federal Reserve Bank of Rich- mond.
    [Show full text]
  • The Spectre of Monetarism
    The Spectre of Monetarism Speech given by Mark Carney Governor of the Bank of England Roscoe Lecture Liverpool John Moores University 5 December 2016 I am grateful to Ben Nelson and Iain de Weymarn for their assistance in preparing these remarks, and to Phil Bunn, Daniel Durling, Alastair Firrell, Jennifer Nemeth, Alice Owen, James Oxley, Claire Chambers, Alice Pugh, Paul Robinson, Carlos Van Hombeeck, and Chris Yeates for background analysis and research. 1 All speeches are available online at www.bankofengland.co.uk/publications/Pages/speeches/default.aspx Real incomes falling for a decade. The legacy of a searing financial crisis weighing on confidence and growth. The very nature of work disrupted by a technological revolution. This was the middle of the 19th century. Liverpool was in the midst of a golden age; its Custom House was the national Exchequer’s biggest source of revenue. And Karl Marx was scribbling in the British Library, warning of a spectre haunting Europe, the spectre of communism. We meet today during the first lost decade since the 1860s. In the wake of a global financial crisis. And in the midst of a technological revolution that is once again changing the nature of work. Substitute Northern Rock for Overend Gurney; Uber and machine learning for the Spinning Jenny and the steam engine; and Twitter for the telegraph; and you have dynamics that echo those of 150 years ago. Then the villains were the capitalists. Should they today be the central bankers? Are their flights of fancy promoting stagnation and inequality? Does the spectre of monetarism haunt our economies?i These are serious charges, based on real anxieties.
    [Show full text]
  • Household Debt and Saving During the 2007 Recession
    Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports Household Debt and Saving during the 2007 Recession Rajashri Chakrabarti Donghoon Lee Wilbert van der Klaauw Basit Zafar Staff Report no. 482 January 2011 This paper presents preliminary findings and is being distributed to economists and other interested readers solely to stimulate discussion and elicit comments. The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors and are not necessarily reflective of views at the Federal Reserve Bank of New York or the Federal Reserve System. Any errors or omissions are the responsibility of the authors. Household Debt and Saving during the 2007 Recession Rajashri Chakrabarti, Donghoon Lee, Wilbert van der Klaauw, and Basit Zafar Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports , no. 482 January 2011 JEL classification: G01, D14, D12, D91 Abstract Using credit report records and data collected from several household surveys, we analyze changes in household debt and saving during the 2007 recession. We find that, while different segments of the population were affected in distinct ways, depending on whether they owned a home, whether they owned stocks, and whether they had secure jobs, the crisis’ impact appears to have been widespread, affecting large shares of households across all age, income, and education groups. In response to their deteriorated financial situations, households reduced their average spending and increased their saving. This increase in saving―at least in 2009―did not materialize through an increase in contributions to retirement and savings accounts. If anything, such contributions actually declined on average during that year. Instead, the higher saving rate appears to reflect a considerable decline in household debt, as households paid down mortgage debt in particular.
    [Show full text]
  • GROSS SAVING Economic Development Macroeconomic Performance
    GROSS SAVING Economic development Macroeconomic Performance 1. INDICATOR (a) Name: Gross saving (b) Brief Definition: Gross saving is disposable income less consumption. It can be calculated for each institutional sector and the total economy. (c) Unit of Measurement: $US or local currency. (d) Placement in the CSD Indicator Set: Economic development/ Macroeconomic performance. 2. POLICY RELEVANCE (a) Purpose: The indicator is a basic economic indicator and measures the level and extent of resources available for investment in capital assets. (b) Relevance to Sustainable/Unsustainable Development (theme/sub-theme): Saving is closely related to investment. By not using income to buy consumer goods and services, it is possible for resources to instead be invested in productive capital, such as factories and machinery. Saving can therefore be vital to increase the amount of capital available, contributing to sustainable future economic growth. (c) International Conventions and Agreements: None. (d) International Targets/Recommended Standards: National targets are generally included in government policy. (e) Linkages to Other Indicators: This indicator is closely linked with other measures of economic development, in particular gross capital formation and saving as percentage of GDP. 3. METHODOLOGICAL DESCRIPTION (a) Underlying Definitions and Concepts: Gross saving as described in the 1993 SNA can be derived in three ways: Firstly, it is the gross disposable income less consumption. It is also equal to the sum of gross capital formation, net capital inflows from the rest of the world and changes in foreign reserves. Finally, it can be derived from net lending/borrowing to/from the rest of the world by adding gross capital formation and net capital transfers to the rest of the world.
    [Show full text]
  • The Concept and Measurement of Savings: the United States and Other Industrialized Countries
    The Concept and Measurement of Savings: The United States and Other industrialized Countries Derek W. Blades and Peter H. Sturm* Introduction 1. It has long been recognized that conventionally measured saving ra- tios differ widely between countries, and that among the 24 member coun- tries of the OECD the U.S. economy is the one with the lowest national sav- ing ratio. It is also true--though probably less well publicized-- that any’ definition of saving is to some extent arbitrary, and that given a specific definition, institutional differences between countries may result in differ- ences in saving ratios between economies which otherwise display identical characteristics and behavior. The present paper analyzes the question of how important institutional differences are in explaining observed differ- ences in official saving ratios between the United States and other industri- alized countries, and how sensitive this difference is to alternative defini- tions of saving and income. This analysis will be carried out for both the aggregate national saving ratio and the household saving ratio. A separate treatment of the household sector seems justified, given the dominating share this sector contributes to total national savings in most countries, and the focus on household behavior in theoretical discussions of savings determinants. 2. The various possible modifications of the official definition of sav- ings discussed here result in a large number of alternative savings concepts. Which of these alternatives is the "correct" one will of course depend on the question analyzed. Special attention will be given in this paper to the savings concept most relevant for the analysis of economic growth.
    [Show full text]
  • Some Tables of Historical U.S. Currency and Monetary Aggregates Data
    WORKING PAPER SERIES Some Tables of Historical U.S. Currency and Monetary Aggregates Data Richard G. Anderson Working Paper 2003-006A http://research.stlouisfed.org/wp/2003/2003-006.pdf April 2003 FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS Research Division 411 Locust Street St. Louis, MO 63102 ______________________________________________________________________________________ The views expressed are those of the individual authors and do not necessarily reflect official positions of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, the Federal Reserve System, or the Board of Governors. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Papers are preliminary materials circulated to stimulate discussion and critical comment. References in publications to Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Papers (other than an acknowledgment that the writer has had access to unpublished material) should be cleared with the author or authors. Photo courtesy of The Gateway Arch, St. Louis, MO. www.gatewayarch.com Some Tables of Historical U.S. Currency and Monetary Aggregates Data Richard G. Anderson Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper 2003-006 April 2003 Abstract This paper includes revised and extended versions of tables of historical U.S. currency and monetary aggregates data compiled for the forthcoming work: Susan B. Carter et.al., editors, Historical Statistics of the United States, Colonial Times to the Present, Millennial Edition. Three volumes. Cambridge University Press, forthcoming. These tables, in part, update and extend tables that previously appeared in the 1976 Bicentennial Edition of Historical Statistics, with new descriptive notes. Keywords: historical monetary aggregates, historical statistics JEL Classifications: E4, N1, N2 Views expressed herein are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect official positions of the Federal Reserve Bank of St.
    [Show full text]