Justifying an Analysis of the Ecclesiological Development Of

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Justifying an Analysis of the Ecclesiological Development Of Seton Hall University eRepository @ Seton Hall Seton Hall University Dissertations and Theses Seton Hall University Dissertations and Theses (ETDs) Fall 2007 Justifying an Analysis of the Ecclesiological Development of Subsidiarity via Civil and Common Law Jurisprudential Epistemology William Pieratt eD mond Seton Hall University Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarship.shu.edu/dissertations Part of the Civil Law Commons, Common Law Commons, European Law Commons, and the Religion Law Commons Recommended Citation Demond, William Pieratt, "Justifying an Analysis of the Ecclesiological Development of Subsidiarity via Civil and Common Law Jurisprudential Epistemology" (2007). Seton Hall University Dissertations and Theses (ETDs). 2359. https://scholarship.shu.edu/dissertations/2359 Justifying An Analysis of the Ecclesiological Development of Subsidiarity via Civil and Common Law Jurisprudential Epistemology William Pieratt Demond∗ Seton Hall University The Whitehead School of Diplomacy Masters Thesis – OMEGA Professor Moremen Fall 2007 ∗ I would like to thank my family, friends, and professors for both tolerating and supporting me while I was completing this project. Specifically, I would like to thank Professor Defeis of Seton Hall University School of Law for both her confidence in my abilities and her unyielding willingness to provide me with incomparable opportunities; Professor Baker of Seton Hall University School of Law for his attempts to teach me European Union law; Professor Moremen of Seton Hall University School of Diplomacy for his guidance and direction throughout the drafting process; Father Nicholas Gengaro of Seton Hall University School of Law for his time, compassion, friendship, support, and efforts to educate a non-Catholic; the librarians and security staff at Seton Hall University School of Law for letting me reside in their domain for days at a time; John Heywood from American University's Washington College of Law for helping me locate the Treaty of Maastricht's unofficial travaux; Meagan Hassan for providing limitless logistical and moral support; and my parents, Walter Demond, John Pieratt, and Ann Pieratt; without their various forms of support, I would not have acquired either the education or the drive necessary to complete a project of this magnitude. This paper is dedicated to my grandfather John Arthur Moss for encouraging me throughout my life to attend law school; it was probably the best decision I've ever made. Thank you all for everything. Justifying an Analysis of the Ecclesiological Development of Subsidiarity via Civil and Common Law Jurisprudential Epistemology Abstract This article seeks to justify an examination of subsidiarity's development within Catholicism. Due to the fact that the European Union ["EU"] codified subsidiarity via the Treaty of Maastricht, subsidiarity is now a part of EU law. Although seemingly intended to resolve questions concerning the proper allocation of powers, its codification has generated substantial debate concerning the proper meaning(s) (if any) and/or application(s) of subsidiarity within the EU. Due to the facts that 1) the EU's legal traditions are heavily influenced by both the civil and common law traditions, 2) both of these traditions advocate the use of established jurisprudential methodologies to interpret ambiguities, and 3) subsidiarity can reasonably be classified as ambiguous within EU law, utilizing these methods can foreseeably generate insight into subsidiarity's meaning. Furthermore, an examination of these methods arguably authorizes civil and/or common law jurists to investigate the ecclesiological development of subsidiarity even if the term itself is not deemed ambiguous. A cursory examination of 1) (at least some of) these jurisprudential methodologies, 2) the development of subsidiarity within Catholicism, and 3) the development of subsidiarity within the EU appears to reveal several material similarities and no material dissimilarities. As a consequence, this article concludes that a more detailed examination of subsidiarity's development within Catholicism may potentially resolve pending questions about its application(s) and/or meaning(s) within EU law. William Pieratt Demond 25 April 2008 "For what can be explained, investigated, or demonstrated about the nature of things without the assistance of speech and words which signify things? Or without the ministry of interpretation?"1 1 Johannes Goeddaeus, Commentarius repetitae praelectionis in tit. XVI libri L. Pandectarum de verborum et rerum significatione (1591), quoted by IAN MACLEAN, INTERPRETATION AND MEANING IN THE RENAISSANCE: THE CASE OF LAW 87 (1992). I. INTRODUCTION AND THESIS STATEMENT Although arguably a principle of common sense,2 the principle of subsidiarity appears to be one of the most popularly discussed3 yet ambiguous4 topics within EU 2 Commission of the European Communities, The Principle of Subsidiarity: Communication of the Commission to the Council and the European Parliament at Annex, ¶ 2, SEC(92) 1990 final, Brussels 27 October 1992 (“The subsidiarity principle as applied in the institutional context is based on a simple concept: the powers that a State or a federation of States wields in the common interest are only those which individuals, families, companies, and local or regional authorities cannot exercise in isolation. This commonsense principle therefore dictates that decisions should be taken at the level closest to the ordinary citizen and that action taken by the upper echelons of the body politic should be avoided."). See also id. at 2 (“In practical terms it implies for the Community institutions, and in particular for the Commission, the application of the simple principle of good sense that, in the exercise of its competences, the Community should do only what is best done at this level.”); HELEN J. ALFORD, O.P. AND MICHAEL J. NAUGHTON, MANAGING AS IF FAITH MATTERED: CHRISTIAN SOCIAL PRINCIPLES IN THE MODERN ORGANIZATION 77 (2001) (“The term [subsidiarity]…rests on the commonsense truth that people simply do better at tasks they themselves plan and control.”); ANTONIO ESTELLA, THE EU PRINCIPLE OF SUBSIDIARITY AND ITS CRITIQUE 82 (2002) (“From a theoretical perspective, subsidiarity is so undefined that the concept amounts, at best, to a common sense principle of good government or a political objective.”); and John E. Linnan, C.S.V., Subsidiarity, Collegiality, Catholic Diversity, and Their Relevance to Apostolic Visitations, 49 THE JURIST 399, 421 (1989) (“[W]herever just relationships have existed in society, and wherever individuals and smaller groups have realized an appropriate liberty with respect to higher authority or larger societies, this principle [of subsidiarity], formulated or not, has been operative and at least implicitly recognized in practice, if not in theory.”). 3 A lexis search performed on 19 November 2007 reveals 1,378 law review articles containing the word "subsidiarity," 35 of which contain the term in the title. 4 See, e.g., REPORT OF THE COUNCIL ON THE FUNCTIONING OF THE TREATY ON EUROPEAN UNION 9 (1995) (“Admittedly, first experience shows that the institutions and the Council are occasionally having difficulties in agreeing how it [subsidiarity] is to be evaluated and applied.”); A.G. Toth, A Legal Analysis of Subsidiarity, in LEGAL ISSUES OF THE MAASTRICHT TREATY 37 (O'Keeffe and Twomey eds., 1994) (“It is no exaggeration to say that there are few concepts in the Maastricht Treaty, or indeed in Community law as a whole, which are more elusive than the concept of subsidiarity.”); Jo Steiner, Subsidiarity under the Maastricht Treaty, in LEGAL ISSUES OF THE MAASTRICHT TREATY, supra note 4, at 49, citing Lord Mackenzie-Stuart, contribution to the Proceedings of the Jacques Delors Colloquium, Subsidiarity and the Challenge of Change (1991) at 39 (“Discussion of the principle…reveal [sic] that it is capable of no less than 30 different meanings.”); P.P. Craig and G. de Búrca, General Editors' Preface, in ESTELLA, supra note 2, at v (2002) (“[S]ubsidiarity is a concept that is notoriously fluid and difficult to define, something which promoted many commentators to dismiss its legal relevance at the time of its introduction.”); Nanette A. Neuwahl, A Europe Close to the Citizen? The 'Trinity Concepts' of Subsidiarity, Transparency, and Democracy, in A CITIZENS' EUROPE; IN SEARCH OF A NEW ORDER 39 (Allan Rosas and Esko Antola eds., 1995); George MacDonald Ross, In Defence of Subsidiarity, PHIL. NOW, 1993 (“The Philosophy Glossary defined subsidiarity as 'nobody agrees on what this word means' (p.32), and John Crosthwaite described its meaning as a 'grey area', and 'hand[ed] the question over to the real philosophers' (p.25).”), at http://www.philosophy.leeds.ac.uk/GMR/articles/subsid.html (last visited 2 July 2007); George A. Bermann, Taking Subsidiarity Seriously: Federalism in the European Community and the United States, 94 COLUM. L. REV. 332, 332-333 (1994) (“Subsidiarity has been criticized as 'inelegant…Eurospeak,' 'the epitome of confusion,' and simple 'gobbledegook.'”) (internal citations omitted); and Dennis J. Edwards, Fearing Federalism's Failure: Subsidiarity in the European Union, 44 AM. J. COMP. L. 537, 544 (1996) (“[Subsidiarity has been called] 'an empty shell devoid of concrete substance' and 'totally alien to...the 1 jurisprudence.5 Despite the considerable legal and ecclesiastical scholarship, however, a noteworthy body thereof appears to focus on either 1) examining subsidiarity's
Recommended publications
  • Distributism Debate
    The Distributism Debate The Distributism Debate Dane J. Weber Donald P. Goodman III Eds. GP Goretti Publications Dozenal numeration is a system of thinking of numbers in twelves, rather than tens. Twelve is much more versatile, having four even divisors—2, 3, 4, and 6—as opposed to only two for ten. This means that such hatefulness as “0.333. ” for 1/3 and “0.1666. ” for 1/6 are things of the past, replaced by easy “0;4” (four twelfths) and “0;2” (two twelfths). In dozenal, counting goes “one, two, three, four, five, six, seven, eight, nine, ten, elv, dozen; dozen one, dozen two, dozen three, dozen four, dozen five, dozen six, dozen seven, dozen eight, dozen nine, dozen ten, dozen elv, two dozen, two dozen one. ” It’s written as such: 1, 2, 3, 4, 5, 6, 7, 8, 9, X, E, 10, 11, 12, 13, 14, 15, 16, 17, 18, 19, 1X, 1E, 20, 21... Dozenal counting is at once much more efficient and much easier than decimal counting, and takes only a little bit of time to get used to. Further information can be had from the dozenal societies (http:// www.dozenal.org), as well as in many other places on the Internet. © 2006 (11E2) Dane J. Weber and Donald P. Goodman III, Version 3.0. All rights reserved. This document may be copied and distributed freely, provided that it is done in its entirety, including this copyright page, and is not modified in any way. Goretti Publications http://gorpub.freeshell.org [email protected] No copyright on this work is intended to in any way derogate from the copyright holders of any individual part of this work.
    [Show full text]
  • ABSTRACT Is “Social Justice” Justice? a Thomistic Argument For
    ABSTRACT Is “Social Justice” Justice? A Thomistic Argument for “Social Persons” as the Proper Subjects of the Virtue of Social Justice John R. Lee, Ph.D. Mentor: Francis J. Beckwith, Ph.D. The term “social justice,” as it occurs in the Catholic social encyclical tradition, presents a core, definitional problem. According to Catholic social thought, social justice has social institutions as its subjects. However, in the Thomistic tradition, justice is understood to be a virtue, i.e., a human habit with human persons as subjects. Thus, with its non-personal subjects, social justice would seem not to be a virtue, and thus not to be a true form of justice. We offer a solution to this problem, based on the idea of social personhood. Drawing from the Thomistic understanding of “person” as a being “distinct in a rational nature”, it is argued that certain social institutions—those with a unity of order—are capable of meeting Aquinas’ analogical definition of personhood. Thus, social institutions with a unity of order—i.e., societies —are understood to be “social persons” and thus the proper subjects of virtue, including the virtue of justice. After a review of alternative conceptions, it is argued that “social justice” in the Catholic social encyclical tradition is best understood as general justice (justice directed toward the common good) extended to include not only human persons, but social persons as well. Advantages of this conception are highlighted. Metaphysically, an understanding of social justice as exercised by social persons fits nicely with an understanding of society as non-substantial, but subsistent being.
    [Show full text]
  • Heinrich Pesch and the Anglo-German Divide in Economics
    Heinrich Pesch and the Anglo-German Divide in Economics William R. Hauk, Jr.∗ University of South Carolina May 2021 Abstract The Rev. Heinrich Pesch, S.J. was a German economist and social philosopher who was an active scholar from the 1890s to 1920s. His work had a significant impact on a generation of German Catholic social thinkers and particularly the papal encyclical Quadragesimo Anno. His method of social analysis, which he called Solidarism, was informed by Catholic Social Thought, but based on natural law principles that he argued were accessible to all people of good will. This article argues that, although his school of thought did not survive the Nazi and World War II years, many of his ideas had a lingering effect on Economic thought for the German center-right. This influence may be contrasted with the center- right in Britain, where there was a strong divorce between Christian social thinking and Economics. Consequently, a gap emerged between Economic policy in Germany and Britain, which contributes to tensions over economic policy that remain today. Keywords: Heinrich Pesch, Catholic Social Thought, Solidarism JEL Codes: B15, B31, F02, Z12 Word Count: 6479 1 Introduction The Rev. Heinrich Pesch, S.J. was a German economist and social philosopher who was active as a scholar between the 1890s and 1920s. While he is relatively little known in the English-speaking world today, his views influenced a generation of German Catholic social thinkers, culminating in Pope Pius XI's encyclical Quadragesimo Anno, which was published five years after his death. The social philosophy that he espoused, called Solidarism, proceeded from his study of Economics and the relatively nascent field of modern Catholic Social Thought.
    [Show full text]
  • Rupert J. Ederer
    FAITH & REASON THE JOURNAL of CHRISTENDOM COLLEGE Summer 1997 | Vol. XXIII, No. 2 John Paul II, Heinrich Pesch, and the Christian Virtue of Solidarity Rupert J. Ederer HIS IS NOT A THEOLOGICAL TREATISE, SINCE I AM NOT A THEOLOGIAN BUT AN economist. Nevertheless, it involves an appeal to competent theologians to lose no time in studying the Christian virtue, solidarity, so as to incorporate it into their theological works in a systematic man- ner. Otherwise this important concept could suffer the fate of the virtue, social justice, after that was introduced in 1931 by Pius XI in Quadragesimo Anno. It could be reduced to pietistic fluff, or it could even become a slogan expressive of antagonistic sentiments. Indeed, there are already indications that solidarity is slipping into platitudinous usage in popular discourse. Fortunately, in Sollicitudo Rei Socialis Pope John Paul II explained the meaning of the concept, solidar- ity, where he declared it to be “undoubtedly a Christian virtue” (40). Indeed, he took pains to indicate not only what it is, but also what it is not. Its essence is contained in the important 38’” paragraph of the encyclical where we find reference to “the positive and moral value of the growing awareness of interdependence among individuals and nations.” The Pope stated that “the correlative response as a moral and social attitude, as a ‘virtue,’ is solidarity.” He referred to the response to the “awareness” of that interdependence, as he talked also about “interdependence” becoming “recognized in this way.” “In this way” involves “a system determining relationships in the contemporary world, in its economic, cultural, political and religious elements.” Thus, if solidarity is nurtured as a virtue, “it is a firm and persevering determination to commit oneself to the common good.” On the other hand, it is “not a feeling of vague compassion or shallow distress at the mis- fortunes of many people, both near and far.” Such a reaction is little more than sentimentality.
    [Show full text]
  • Current European Interest in the Ordoliberal Tradition
    LAW 2018/03 Department of Law Dead man walking: Current European interest in the ordoliberal tradition Josef Hien & Christian Joerges European University Institute Department of Law DEAD MAN WALKING: CURRENT EUROPEAN INTEREST IN THE ORDOLIBERAL TRADITION Josef Hien & Christian Joerges EUI Working Paper LAW 2018/03 This text may be downloaded for personal research purposes only. Any additional reproduction for other purposes, whether in hard copy or electronically, requires the consent of the authors. If cited or quoted, reference should be made to the full name of the authors, the title, the working paper or other series, the year, and the publisher. ISSN 1725-6739 © Josef Hien & Christian Joerges, 2018 Printed in Italy European University Institute Badia Fiesolana I-50014 San Domenico di Fiesole (FI) Italy www.eui.eu cadmus.eui.eu Abstract Ordoliberalism became during the years of the financial crisis the target of a European-wide critical campaign. This school of thought is widely perceived as the ideational source of Germany’s crisis politics which has even led to an “ordoliberalisation of Europe”. The essay questions the validity of such assessments. It focuses on two aspects which are widely neglected in current debates. One is the importance of law in the ordoliberal vision of the ordering of economy and society. The second is its cultural and religious background in particular in German Protestantism. The influence of the ordoliberal school on European law, so the essay argues, is overrated in all stages of the integration project. Anglo- American neoliberalism rather than German Ordoliberalism was in the ideational driver seat since the 1980s.
    [Show full text]
  • Happiness and the Good Economy in Catholic Social Teaching
    The University of Southern Mississippi The Aquila Digital Community Honors Theses Honors College Spring 5-2015 On the Shoulders of Giants: Happiness and the Good Economy in Catholic Social Teaching Erin C. Wingerter University of Southern Mississippi Follow this and additional works at: https://aquila.usm.edu/honors_theses Part of the Economics Commons Recommended Citation Wingerter, Erin C., "On the Shoulders of Giants: Happiness and the Good Economy in Catholic Social Teaching" (2015). Honors Theses. 285. https://aquila.usm.edu/honors_theses/285 This Honors College Thesis is brought to you for free and open access by the Honors College at The Aquila Digital Community. It has been accepted for inclusion in Honors Theses by an authorized administrator of The Aquila Digital Community. For more information, please contact [email protected]. The University of Southern Mississippi On the Shoulders of Giants: Happiness and the Good Economy in Catholic Social Teaching by Erin Wingerter A Thesis Submitted to the Honors College of The University of Southern Mississippi in Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Degree of Bachelor of Arts in the Department of Economics May 2015 ii Approved by ________________________________________________ Edward Sayre, Ph.D., Thesis Adviser Associate Professor of Economics ________________________________________________ Edward Sayre, Ph.D., Chair Department of Political Science, International Development and International Affairs ________________________________________________ Ellen Weinauer, Ph.D., Dean Honors College iii Abstract The economic discipline, in studying humans, relies on economic philosophers’ theories and understanding of the human person. One of Adam Smith’s most basic tenants was that man is self-interested. This thesis explores the profound implications this has had on those who study economics and what research in behavioral economics implies about its effect on life satisfaction.
    [Show full text]
  • Thomas Haan ECON 43201-01 Topics in Political Economy Professor David Ruccio Ethics and the National Economy Fr. Heinrich Pesch
    Thomas Haan ECON 43201-01 Topics in Political Economy Professor David Ruccio Ethics and the National Economy Fr. Heinrich Pesch, S.J. 1 Introduction In his groundbreaking encyclical Rerum Novarum, released in 1891, Pope Leo XIII examined the question of economic responsibility. While never defining the ideal economic structure, Leo XIII articulates the ends for which all economic activity should direct itself, and rejects the prominent structures of unrestricted capitalism and socialism, seeing them flawed by their inaccurate picture of human nature. Meanwhile, a young German Jesuit priest named Heinrich Pesch, after the release of Rerum Novarum, makes a request to his superior that he devote himself to the study and solution of economic responsibility. To aid him in this pursuit, Pesch could rely on his background of studies at the University of Bonn, as well as his witness to the appalling conditions of English industrialization during his study there. One year before he died in 1926, Pesch’s main work is finished, Lehrbuch der Nationalokonomie, which consists of nearly 4,000 pages and five volumes. This great work leaves a lasting legacy in Catholic social thought, as Pope Pius XI follows Pesch’s principles nearly word for word in his 1931 encyclical Quadragisimo Anno. Pesch’s principle of subsidiarity is even added to the Catechism of the Catholic Church, published first in 1992. This same framework from Pesch allows Pope John Paul II to address crucial issues like distribution of resources and responsibility for the poor in his encyclical Centisimus Annus, released in 1991. The work of Pesch that will be focused upon in this paper is Ethics and the National Economy, which concisely outlines the principles for his solidaristic system of human work.
    [Show full text]
  • An Economic Personalist Perspective of Human Capital : a Compared
    Universidad Cardenal Herrera-CEU Departamento Derecho Privado y Disciplina Jurídicas Básicas An Economic Personalist Perspective on Human Capital: A Compared Anthropological Interpretation TESIS DOCTORAL Presentada por: Luca Sandonà Dirigida por: Prof. Dr. Stefano Solari Prof. Dr. Juan Nave Pineda Prof. Dr. Gerez Kramer VALENCIA 2010 TESIS DOCTORAL Luca Sandonà 2010 An Economic Personalist Perspective on Human Capital: A Compared Anthropological Interpretation Index Index of Figures Index of Tables Index of Formula Sintesi Presentation , by Stefano Solari, p. i Prefazione , p. 25 Introduzione , p. 31 First Section. Human Capital in the Classical School: An Embryonic Concept Chapter 1. Human Capital in the Italian Classical School: Interiorization of Moral Values and Practice of Civic Virtues 1) Introduction, p. 37 2) Human Capital in the Meridional Classical School, p.38 3) Human Capital in the First Generation of the Lombard- Venetian School, p. 43 4) Human Capital in the Second Generation of the Lombard-Venetian School, p. 46 5) Conclusions, p. 51 Chapter 2. Human Capital in the English Classical School: The Introduction of the “Homo Economicus” Paradigm 1) Introduction, p. 55 2) Human Capital in Smith, p. 56 2.1) Smith’s Human Capital and the Division of Labour, p. 60 2.2) Smith’s Human Capital and Social Control, p. 62 2.3) Smith’s Human Capital and Workers’ Training, p. 64 2.4) Smith’s Human Capital and the University System, p. 65 An Economic Personalist Perspective on Human Capital: A Compared Anthropological Interpretation 3) Human Capital in Ricardo, p. 68 4) Human Capital in Malthus, p. 70 5) Human Capital in McCulloch, p.
    [Show full text]
  • Dorothy Day's Distributism and Her Vision for Catholic Politics
    Louisiana State University LSU Digital Commons LSU Doctoral Dissertations Graduate School 2017 Dorothy Day's Distributism and Her Vision for Catholic Politics William Patric Schulz Louisiana State University and Agricultural and Mechanical College, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: https://digitalcommons.lsu.edu/gradschool_dissertations Part of the Political Science Commons Recommended Citation Schulz, William Patric, "Dorothy Day's Distributism and Her Vision for Catholic Politics" (2017). LSU Doctoral Dissertations. 4347. https://digitalcommons.lsu.edu/gradschool_dissertations/4347 This Dissertation is brought to you for free and open access by the Graduate School at LSU Digital Commons. It has been accepted for inclusion in LSU Doctoral Dissertations by an authorized graduate school editor of LSU Digital Commons. For more information, please [email protected]. DOROTHY DAY’S DISTRIBUTISM AND HER VISION FOR CATHOLIC POLITICS A Dissertation Submitted to the Graduate Faculty of the Louisiana State University and Agricultural and Mechanical College in partial fulfillment of the Requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy in The Department of Political Science by William Patric Schulz, Jr. B.G.S., Louisiana State University at Shreveport, 2007 M.A., Southeastern Louisiana University, 2009 M.A., Louisiana State University, 2011 J.D., Louisiana State University, Paul M. Hebert Law Center, 2016 August 2017 Table of Contents ABSTRACT .................................................................................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • The Dream of Christian Socialism an Essay on Its European Origins
    TRIM TAIL 6 1/8" FROM BACf OF SPINE ..LTRIM HEAD 3/16" ABOVE FINAL TRIM _____ FRONT EDGE OF SPINE TRIM FACE 6 1/8" FROM FRONT OF SPINE--+- The Dream of Christian Socialism An Essay on Its European Origins BERNARD MURCHLAND Among highly educated clergy and laymen in Britain, France, and Germany in the nineteenth century, religious socialism was a bright dream, which antedated and op­ posed Marxism. Religious socialists rebelled, for alto­ gether traditional reasons, against individualism in par­ ticular. Their movement contributed to the growth of Fabianism and non-Marxist socialism in Europe and America. Until now, there has been no easily accessible history of religious socialism. In this timely survey, Bernard Murchland relates a tale for the general reader that offers essential background for the current debate over the re­ ligious merits of competing political and economic sys­ tems. The author's notes and bibliography direct the reader to widely scattered materials on the subject. Bernard Murchland, professor of philosophy at Ohio Wesleyan University, has written many books and articles on religious and existential thought. He is the editor of Antaeus, a newsletter for the humanities. ISBN 0-8447-3470-5 ISBN 978-0-8447-3470-5 ~ American Enterprise Institute for Public Policy Research ~ 1150 Seventeenth Street, N.W., Washington, D.C. 20036 -" TRIM BOTTOM AT 91/2" FRONT EDGE OF SPINE ------j SMALL COVERS The Dream of Christian Socialism An Essay on Its European Origins Bernard Murchland The Dream of Christian Socialism An Essay on Its European Origins Bernard Murchland American Enterprise Institute for Public Policy Research Washington and London Distributed to the Trade by National Book Network, 15200 NBN Way, Blue Ridge Summit, PA 17214.
    [Show full text]
  • Heinrich Pesch (1854–1926)
    FRANZ H. MUELLER Heinrich Pesch (1854-1926) Social Philosopher and Economist The Currency of the Idea of Solidarism" Fifty years ago - on April 1, 1926, to be exact - Heinrich Pesch, S. ]., the world's greatest Catholic economist, died at the age of 71. It was an unstable and critical period when he departed this world. A sane plan under which action may be taken toward social peace and public tranquility was urgently needed. Pesch had set forth, clearly and per- suasively, the principal socio-philosophical and economic elements on which such a plan or system should be constructed. However, the political climate, tending as it did toward extreme "solutions", was not conducive to the dissemination and acceptance of balanced views. When, on May 15, 1931, the encyclical Quadragesimo anno appeared, Catholic social thinkers and actionists recognized at once in it Pesch's "Solidarism", that had in fact inspired the drafters - Frs. O. v. Nell- Breuning, S.]., and Gustav Gundlach, S. j., close associates of (the late) Fr. Pesch - of this papal letter. But one of its guiding concep- tions, namely that of a reconstruction of the social economy along the lines of corporate organization and functional representation, never received much more than an academic discussion. For the generation of German Catholics who grew up during the Nazi regime and World War II, Pesch and Solidarism, if they know any- thing at all about it, are things of the past, hardly more than an interesting event in the history of Catholic social thought. Surely, some five years after his death, his ideas, as was said above, still shone through the encyclical On Reconstructing the Social Order.
    [Show full text]
  • Ethics and the National Economy • Fr
    Ethics and the National Economy • Fr. • Economy National the and Ethics Ethics the National EconomyAND BY REV. FR. hEINRICh pESCh, S. j. TRANSLATEd BY dR. RUpERT EdERER “For those who are troubled by unfettered capitalist systems that spawn stock market bubbles, bloated executive salaries, shoddy merchandise, indifferent service, economic dislocation and insecurity, and abject poverty, especially in the southern hemisphere; and that separate wealth from work, assess humans according to their instrumental value, replace the virtues of jus- tice and charity with uninhibited self-interest and acquisitiveness, enshrine freedom as the only social value, and embrace compe- AND tition as the only principle organizing economic affairs, Rupert Ederer’s translation of Heinrich Pesch’s timeless Ethics and the National Economy is must reading. “All others needn’t bother.” —Edward J. O’Boyle, Ph.D. Mayo Research Institute West Monroe, Louisiana Heinrich Pesch, S. Pesch, Heinrich HEINRICh PESCh, S. J. (1854–1926) is one of the greatest of philosopher- economists, whose “Solidarism” is based upon the classical and Christian un- derstanding of man and socio-economic life, rooted in the teaching of Aristotle and perfected by St. Thomas Aquinas. His works include Liberalism, Socialism, and the Christian Social Order (1900) and the monumental Compendium of the National Economy, which ran to nearly four thousand pages and earned him recognition as the first Catholic to write a complete, scientific economic treatise. Volume I of his Compendium saw numerous editions and was a standard text in the social science curricula at many Catholic institutions of higher learning. DR. RUpERT EdERER was educated at St.
    [Show full text]