Decisive Factors for the Acceptability of Congestion Pricing

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Decisive Factors for the Acceptability of Congestion Pricing Decisive factors for the acceptability of congestion pricing Carl J. Hamilton CTS Working Paper Keywords: congestion pricing; acceptability JEL Codes: R41, R42, R Centre For Transport Studies SE-100 44 Stockholm Sweden www.cts.kth.se Decisive Factors For congestion pricing acceptability ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS In planning the Field work For this paper, designing the survey, carrying it out, gathering the data, and discussing its implications, I have had invaluable help From an international team consisting of Jonas Eliasson, Karin Brundell-Freij, Kati Kiiskilä, Jenny Källström, Charles Raux, Stephanie Souche, and Juha Tervonen, all whose expertise and experience Far overshadows my own. Without the support From these magniFicent people, this paper would not have been. The work has been Funded by ERA NET Transport and its Funding programme Surprice, dedicated to road pricing. 1 INTRODUCTION Among transportation economists and traFFic planners, there is broad support For congestion pricing. Most professionals in the Field recognise that the beneFits in terms of trafFic Flow and welFare improvements can be substantial, and that given low costs oF operation the policy instrument can be socially beneFicial. Still however, when speciFic schemes are being suggested, public acceptance turns out to be a critical issue, oFten preventing the systems From being implemented. Over the last decades a vast literature has sought to understand the causes oF the low level of acceptance. Several Factors have been identiFied as being inFluential, including the expected costs to the driver (e.g. Schade and Schlag, 2003), the stated use of the revenue (e.g. Schlag and Teubel, 1997), as well as practical experience of a congestion pricing system (e.g. Brundell-Freij and Jonsson, 2009). Most previous studies have however Focused on only one or a small set oF explanatory variables, and on a single population. In this study, a wide range oF explanatory Factors is tested by a common survey design used in three diFFerent cities, with varying degrees oF experience From congestion pricing. Respondents are asked For their preFerence to congestion pricing, and the influence of other factors on this ordinal dependent variable is then tested (mainly) by ordered logit regression. Thereby the diFFerent Factors can both be compared as to their relative inFluence on attitude, as well as tested For generality (by comparing across the three populations). The three cities used For comparison are Stockholm (Sweden), Helsinki (Finland) and Lyon (France). They are similar-sized European cities, but with distinctly diFFerent experiences oF congestion pricing. In each oF the three cities, a uniFied comprehensive survey has been issued, covering a wide array of questions. In the light oF previous research, the contents oF the survey can roughly be categorised in Four groups oF factors: a) Factors related mainly to selF-interest, including how much people pay or expect to pay in congestion charges, how much one values not being delayed 2 Decisive Factors For congestion pricing acceptability when travelling, and how the revenues From the system are recycled and made useFul For the population b) Factors related to perceived Fairness of the charging system, including the eFFect on income equity (rich-versus-poor), as well as the Fairness oF principles oF allocation and pricing (e.g. polluter pays or user pays principle). c) Factors related to other attitudes of principle or political inclination, including the natural environment and the role oF the state. d) Factors related to own experience From congestion pricing and belieF in its efFects. This categorisation is not without ambiguity. What is here labelled selF-interest – amount paid, time saved, and where the money is spent – may For some people be determined more by a concern For other people’s money, time, and useFulness oF government spending, thereby representing not selF-interest but a more general preFerence For justice. Likewise, what is labelled as Fairness here is overlapping with political inclination. Bearing these limitations in mind however, the categorisation made is convenient For analysis and allows For comparison with results previously published in the field. ReFerences to the existing literature are given in section 3, in conjunction with the results From the survey. BeFore that, in section 2, the method is presented in detail, followed by a brieF background oF the three cities together with some descriptive statistics to summarise the opinion and attitudes in each of the cities. In section 4 finally, the results are discussed. 2 BACKGROUND AND METHOD 2.1 Survey and data To collect data on people’s attitude to congestion pricing a generic survey has been designed, from which some deviations were made to adapt to local circumstance for the three cities. In addition to questions directly related to congestion pricing, respondents are asked For their opinion on a wide range oF topics, mostly pertaining to transport, but also a Few oF more general nature, such as preFerences related to taxation and environmental issues. In each survey a detailed congestion pricing scheme was presented, describing the charging area, and prices For driving in the system. In the case of Stockholm, the scheme presented was identical to the one in use; in Helsinki it was in line with a charging scheme put Forward and widely debated in media; while in Lyon, a scheme similar to the one used in Stockholm was presented, which was purely hypothetical and had not been up For debate in the general population. Then opinions about the scheme presented were solicited, and a question about how the respondent would vote iF there were a reFerendum on implementing (or in the case oF Stockholm, abolishing) such a scheme today. 3 Decisive Factors For congestion pricing acceptability In the survey, the questions are sorted in groups to make sense to the respondent, to cause less cognitive load when answering, as well as to reduce inclinations to answer strategically or to abandon the survey altogether. Sprinkled across the survey are questions pertaining to the key topics For this study, such as selF-interest, fairness, political inclination, expected eFFects oF a scheme etc. The survey was developed collectively by the three participating research teams, situated in Stockholm, Helsinki, and Lyon. In Stockholm and Helsinki, the survey was issued by post during Spring 2011 to a random sample of people 18-65 years of age in each city. AFter three weeks, one postal follow-up was made to non-respondents. The final response rate was 43% (N=1837) in Stockholm and 39% (N=1178) in Helsinki. In both places, a small but clear response bias was visible, with women and the elderly more likely to return the questionnaire. In Lyon, where a postal survey was ruled out based on previous experiences with very low response rates, a telephone survey was conducted instead. It was designed to meet predetermined quotas For, among other things, age and gender, thereby managing the response bias already at the collection stage. In order to ensure a suFFicient share oF respondents perceiving the survey as relevant, a deliberate additional bias was also introduced, by oversampling frequent car users and people living inside the hypothetical charging zone, to higher shares than would have been the case in a randomized sample oF the population oF Lyon. A total oF 10,241 calls were initiated, out oF which 53% picked up to answer. Out oF those answering, 37% agreed to start answering questions aFter having been introduced to the purpose of the call. Then, as the interview went along, some calls were prematurely terminated, either on request by the respondent, or when the caller system detected that some answer placed the respondent outside one oF the predetermine quotas. When 1,500 calls had led to a complete survey being answered and all quotas met, the calling was complete. When discussing attitudes and other attributes as shares of respondents answering in speciFic ways, each of the three local data sets has been reweighted to counterbalance the known biases. This has been done by giving a higher weight to respondents oF the under-represented groups (gender and age in Stockholm and Helsinki; car usage and inner city inhabitants in Lyon), so that their proportional weight in the response data is equal to their weight in the general population. Hence, the results are projections aiming to represent the true nature of each population, their attitudes, and habits. Data of this kind dominates section 2.2 and table 1, and appear to a lesser extent in section 3. 2.2 Quantitative analysis The majority oF the analysis in section 3 is made using ordered logit (proportional odds logistic regression) as implemented in the statistics program R (R Development Core Team, 2010) and its package MASS (Venables and Ripley, 2002). The dependent variable used is the answer to the question How would you vote if there was a referendum on the introduction (in Stockholm, abolishing) of congestion pricing today?, 4 Decisive Factors For congestion pricing acceptability and the options are Certainly yes, Leaning towards yes, Undecided, Leaning towards no, and Certainly no. In this part oF the analysis, the data is used as it is, each city population on its own and in combination, making no corrections for response biases. Throughout the analysis, a dummy category has been created to capture both those who tick the No opinion box oF a question and those who skip the question altogether. The coeFFicients For this dummy are leFt out oF the results table, as it lacks explanatory power in most cases. The beneFit oF treating skipped questions with a dummy category is that the remaining answers from that respondent can still be used. In one question oF the survey, respondents were asked first how they would vote today if there were a referendum on congestion pricing.
Recommended publications
  • Chapter 5 Conclusions and General Recommendations
    Conclusions and general recommendations Chapter 5 Chapter 5 Conclusions and general recommendations Economic Instruments have a long history – both in developed and developing countries. Transport has always been used to generate state revenues. Many instruments that have been discussed in this book, in fact, can be found in various forms of horse ownership charges, and road and bridge tolls in many countries’ economic histories. Many of these roots, however, have been neglected and forgotten in the recent debate about sustainable transport policy. By 1776, Adam Smith, in “The Wealth of Nations,” had already outlined the basic principles of a sound transport policy. These included most of the aforementioned principles and recommendations for taxation and financing schemes.1 Economic Instruments thus are not new transport policy “tools.” But these tools have too long been idle. It is time to relearn their use, and to use them wisely in order to meet the economic, social and ecological challenges that occur today. 1 An excellent modern outline of the principles formulated by Adam Smith can be found in Metschies 2001. 117 Chapter 5 Conclusions and general recommendations Eight basic insights In the face of diminishing public budgets but increasing internal and toward a wise use of external costs of infrastructure and environmental damage a rethinking Economic of transport policy is needed. In this rethinking, Economic Instruments Instruments. should play an important role. The existing experience with the use of Economic Instruments, as presented in this book, lead to a number of conclusions. These can be summarised as follows: 1. There is a diverse toolbox of Economic Instruments that can be used to address economic, ecological and social goals with tailor-made measures based on economic incentives.
    [Show full text]
  • The Marginal Cost of Traffic Congestion and Road Pricing: Evidence from a Natural Experiment in Beijing
    The Marginal Cost of Traffic Congestion and Road Pricing: Evidence from a Natural Experiment in Beijing Shanjun Li Avralt-Od Purevjav Jun Yang1 Preliminary and Comments Welcome December 2016 ABSTRACT Leveraging a natural experiment and big data, this study examines road pricing, the first-best policy to address traffic congestion in Beijing. Based on fine-scale traffic data from over 1500 monitoring stations throughout the city, this paper provides the first empirical estimate of the marginal external cost of traffic congestion (MECC) and optimal congestion charges based on the causal effect of traffic density on speed, a key input for measuring the MECC. The identification of the causal effect relies on the plausibly exogenous variation in traffic density induced by the driving restriction policy. Our analysis shows that the MECC during rush hours is about 92 cents (or $0.15) per km on average, nearly three times as much as what OLS regressions would imply and larger than estimates from transportation engineering models. The optimal congestion charges range from 5 to 38 cents per km depending on time and location. Road pricing would increase traffic speed by 10 percent within the city center and lead to a welfare gain of 1.4 billion and revenue of 40 billion Yuan per year. Keywords: Traffic Congestion, Road Pricing, Natural Experiment JEL Classification: H23, R41, R48 1 Shanjun Li is an Associate Professor in the Dyson School of Applied Economics and Management, Cornell University, [email protected]; Avralt-Od Purevjav is a doctoral student in the Dyson School of Applied Economics and Management, Cornell University, [email protected]; Jun Yang is a research fellow in Beijing Transportation Research Center, [email protected].
    [Show full text]
  • Glossary of Regional Transportation Systems Management and Operations Terms
    TRANSPORTATION RESEARCH Number E-C166 August 2012 Glossary of Regional Transportation Systems Management and Operations Terms Second Edition TRANSPORTATION RESEARCH BOARD 2012 EXECUTIVE COMMITTEE OFFICERS Chair: Sandra Rosenbloom, Professor of Planning, University of Arizona, Tucson Division Chair for NRC Oversight: C. Michael Walton, Ernest H. Cockrell Centennial Chair in Engineering, University of Texas, Austin Executive Director: Robert E. Skinner, Jr., Transportation Research Board Vice Chair: Deborah H. Butler, Executive Vice President, Planning, and CIO, Norfolk Southern Corporation, Norfolk, Virginia TRANSPORTATION RESEARCH BOARD 2012–2013 TECHNICAL ACTIVITIES COUNCIL Chair: Katherine F. Turnbull, Executive Associate Director, Texas Transportation Institute, Texas A&M University, College Station Technical Activities Director: Mark R. Norman, Transportation Research Board Paul Carlson, Research Engineer, Texas Transportation Institute, Texas A&M University, College Station, Operations and Maintenance Group Chair Thomas J. Kazmierowski, Manager, Materials Engineering and Research Office, Ontario Ministry of Transportation, Toronto, Canada, Design and Construction Group Chair Ronald R. Knipling, Principal, safetyforthelonghaul.com, Arlington, Virginia, System Users Group Chair Mark S. Kross, Consultant, Jefferson City, Missouri, Planning and Environment Group Chair Peter B. Mandle, Director, LeighFisher, Inc., Burlingame, California, Aviation Group Chair Harold R. (Skip) Paul, Director, Louisiana Transportation Research Center, Louisiana
    [Show full text]
  • Congestion Pricing and the Economics of Managing Traffic Robert Krol
    Tolling the Freeway: Congestion Pricing and the Economics of Managing Traffic Robert Krol MERCATUS RESEARCH Robert Krol. “Tolling the Freeway: Congestion Pricing and the Economics of Managing Traffic.” Mercatus Research, Mercatus Center at George Mason University, Arlington, VA, May 2016. ABSTRACT Highway congestion increases the cost of travel in most urban areas in the United States. This paper examines the economics of highway congestion pric- ing. Toll-free highways can be congested at certain times of the day. When addi- tional drivers entering the freeway slow traffic, they impose an externality, or cost, on other highway users. A congestion toll that varies with the level of traf- fic can correct that congestion externality. The evidence indicates that conges- tion tolls reduce congestion and increase driving speeds. Some policymakers are concerned that congestion taxes are regressive. Many factors, such as the proximity of residential communities to jobs, can influence this outcome. Also, the way toll revenues are used determines the degree to which the tax is regres- sive or progressive. Research suggests that congestion tolls are no more regres- sive than the fuel tax that is currently used to finance highways. To encourage and facilitate the adoption of congestion pricing in the United States, Congress should pass legislation making congestion tolls legal on all interstate highways. Experience with congestion tolling improves the public’s perception of tolling and increases drivers’ willingness to accept highway tolls. One tactic that has been successful is following a congestion-pricing experiment with a referen- dum on whether the system should be made permanent. JEL codes: H21, H22, L91, 018, R41, R48 Keywords: congestion externalities, peak-load pricing, tax incidence, tax regressivity Copyright © 2016 by Robert Krol and the Mercatus Center at George Mason University Release: May 2016 The opinions expressed in Mercatus Research are the authors’ and do not represent official positions of the Mercatus Center or George Mason University.
    [Show full text]
  • Dynamic, Stochastic Models for Congestion Pricing and Congestion Securities
    Dynamic, Stochastic Models for Congestion Pricing and Congestion Securities FINAL REPORT December 31, 2010 By Terry L. Friesz and Tao Yao Technical Report Documentation Page 1. Report No. 2. Government Accession No. 3. Recipient’s Catalog No. PSU-2009-01 4. Title and Subtitle 5. Report Date December 31, 2010 Dynamic, Stochastic Models for Congestion Pricing and Congestion Securities 6. Performing Organization Code 7. Author(s) 8. Performing Organization Report LTI 2011-17 Terry L. Friesz, Tao Yao 9. Performing Organization Name and Address 10. Work Unit No. (TRAIS) The Thomas D. Larson Pennsylvania Transportation Institute 11. Contract or Grant No. The Pennsylvania State University DTRT07-G-0003 201 Transportation Research Building University Park, PA, 16802-4710 12. Sponsoring Agency Name and Address 13. Type of Report and Period Covered US Department of Transportation Final Report 1/1/2010-12/31/2010 Research & Innovative Technology Administration 14. Sponsoring Agency Code UTC Program, RDT-30 1200 New Jersey Ave., SE Washington, DC 20590 15. Supplementary Notes 16. Abstract This research considers congestion pricing under demand uncertainty. In particular, a robust optimization (RO) approach is applied to optimal congestion pricing problems under user equilibrium. A mathematical model is developed and an analysis performed to consider robust, dynamic user equilibrium, optimal tolls based on the second-best problem known as the dynamic optimal toll problem with equilibrium constraints, or DOTPEC. Finally, numerical experiments and qualitative analyses are conducted to investigate the performance and robustness of the solutions obtained. 17. Key Words 18. Distribution Statement Robust Optimization, Dynamic Congestion Pricing, Dynamic User Equilibrium 19.
    [Show full text]
  • Congestion Pricing Sep Ash 6 Pst.NW 328- T Em in G 500 T B on E R 2006 0 Www , DC 200 .R
    September 2006 RFF DP 06-37 Congestion Pricing Long-Term Economic and Land-Use Effects Elena Safirova, Sébastien Houde, D. Abram Lipman, Winston Harrington, and Andrew Baglino 1616 P St. NW Washington, DC 20036 202-328-5000 www.rff.org DISCUSSION PAPER Congestion Pricing: Long-Term Economic and Land-Use Effects Elena Safirova, Sébastien Houde, D. Abram Lipman, Winston Harrington, and Andrew Baglino Abstract We employ a spatially disaggregated general equilibrium model of a regional economy that incorporates decisions of residents, firms, and developers integrated with a spatially disaggregated strategic transportation planning (START) model that features mode, time period, and route choice to evaluate economic effects of congestion pricing. First, we evaluate the long-run effects of a road-pricing policy based on the integrated model of land use, strategic transport, and regional economy (LUSTRE) and compare them with the short-term effects obtained from the START model alone. We then look at distributional effects of the policy in question and point out differences and similarities in the short run versus the long run. Finally, we analyze the mechanisms at the source of the economic and land-use effects induced by the road-pricing policy. Key Words: traffic congestion, welfare analysis, CGE modeling, cordon tolls, distributional effects JEL Classification Numbers: C68, D63, R13, R14, R41 © 2006 Resources for the Future. All rights reserved. No portion of this paper may be reproduced without permission of the authors. Discussion papers are research materials circulated by their authors for purposes of information and discussion. They have not necessarily undergone formal peer review. Contents Introduction............................................................................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • Reducing Urban Road Transportation Externalities: Road Pricing in Theory and in Practice Downloaded from Alex Anas* and Robin Lindseyy
    66 Symposium: Transportation and the Environment Reducing Urban Road Transportation Externalities: Road Pricing in Theory and in Practice Downloaded from Alex Anas* and Robin Lindseyy Introduction http://reep.oxfordjournals.org/ Urban road transportation causes several major negative externalities. First, the costs of green- house gas emissions from motorized private and public vehicles are borne globally. Second, other air pollutants and noise from urban road transportation affect road users and others locally. Third, while the costs of congestion (time delays and extra fuel consumption), accidents, and infrastructure damage are largely borne by motorists collectively, there is still an externality because individual motorists increase these costs for other motorists. Because of these exter- nalities, motorists do not bear the full social marginal costs of driving and they drive too much. Urban road transportation causes several other externalities as well, including water pollu- at Technical Services - Serials on October 6, 2016 tion, vibrations, and visual intrusion. Roads also create a barrier to bicyclists and pedestrians. Moreover, when parking is underpriced, the time spent searching for parking, excessive use of land for parking, the contribution to the urban heat island effect, and problems of drainage can besignificantinurbanareas(Shoup2005).Inaddition,fuelconsumptioncanimposecostsatthe national level due to monopsony power in the world oil market and energy insecurity, although by most estimates the average costs are small (Bickel et al. 2006; Delucchi and McCubbin 2009). Many policy instruments can be used to control road transportation externalities, but all have their limitations. In the United States, vehicle emissions standards and ceilings on regional air quality have helped reduce emissions per vehicle kilometer.
    [Show full text]
  • Finance, Taxation, Pricing, Economic Analysis, Socioeconomics
    122 TRANSPORTATION RESEARCH RECORD 1395 Understanding the Competing Short-Run Objectives of Peak Period Road Pricing DAVID BERNSTEIN AND JEROME MULLER The interest in peak period road pricing has grown considerably 1993 or 1994 and a full-scale program by 1997 (14); and Oslo in recent years both in the United States and abroad. This increase and Trondheim, Norway, and Stockholm and Gothenberg, in interest is usually attributed to worsening congestion and im­ Sweden, are all considering programs of one kind or another. proved electronic toll collection technologies. However, there may be a third reason as well: peak period pricing can be used Several reasons are usually given for this renewed interest. to generate revenues. This use of peak period road pricing is First, congestion is now much worse than it has ever been in explored and compared with programs that are designed to min­ the past. As two-income families have become more prevalent imize social cost. Using some simple examples, it is shown that and suburban rings have grown in both absolute population it is possible to increase toll revenues but at a significant cost to and area, the number of commuters using private automobiles society. In addition, it is shown that most of the revenues and in the United States has increased dramatically. In fact, from costs can be attributed to the length and end of the toll period. 1960 to 1980 the number of people driving to work nearly doubled (at a time when the number of people in the work Peak period pricing has been an accepted part of life in the force increased by only 50 percent).
    [Show full text]
  • The Efficacy of Congestion Pricing
    University of Tennessee at Chattanooga UTC Scholar Student Research, Creative Works, and Honors Theses Publications 5-2016 The efficacy of congestion pricing Zachary J. Ridder University of Tennessee at Chattanooga, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: https://scholar.utc.edu/honors-theses Part of the Economics Commons Recommended Citation Ridder, Zachary J., "The efficacy of congestion pricing" (2016). Honors Theses. This Theses is brought to you for free and open access by the Student Research, Creative Works, and Publications at UTC Scholar. It has been accepted for inclusion in Honors Theses by an authorized administrator of UTC Scholar. For more information, please contact [email protected]. The Efficacy of Congestion Pricing By Zack Ridder Departmental Honors Thesis The University of Tennessee at Chattanooga Economics Department Project Direction: Dr. Leila Pratt Examination Date: 3/30/16 Examination Committee: Dr. Leila Pratt Dr. Bruce Hutchinson Dr. James Guilfoyle Dr. David Giles The Efficacy of Congestion Pricing By Zack Ridder 1 I. Introduction As the number of vehicles continues to climb road congestion will become a more prominent feature of urban centers and will likely worsen over time. This thesis will show that the most simple and effective way to combat congestion is the implementation of road pricing schemes in and around major metropolitan areas. For the most part the benefits of such a system outweigh the potential costs. These tolling systems force commuters to internalize the marginal social cost of driving, as opposed to only paying the average social cost and incurring a deadweight loss. This paper will first provide a review of the literature, tracing the theoretical development of congestion pricing from its early roots to modern studies.
    [Show full text]
  • Economic Fundamentals of Road Pricing: a Diagrammatic Analysis
    ___ IS (070 Pollcy Research WORKING PAPERS L Transport Public Disclosure Authorized Infrastructureand Urban Development Department TheWorld Bank December1992 WPS1070 EconomicFundamentals of RoadPricing Public Disclosure Authorized A DiagrammaticAnalysis Public Disclosure Authorized TimothyD. Hau Most economists agree that road pricing benefits society by curtailingcongestion. Efficiency analysis demonstrates why the Public Disclosure Authorized public rejects congestionpricing. A dedicatedroad or transport fund is more viable whenthe road users are chargednot only for the damagecaused by heavyvehicles but also for congestion. PolicyRearchWoding PapsdismLataeth rmdingsofwoiprogrcsatncountgethccxchangeofideaunangB nkstaffand til othas iMacenedin de-volopnelttssues. Them papcgs cary thenanm of die autho, reflactealy theirviews, znd shel be usedand citedaccordingly. hefindn.inu cprcsttion, andconduws aretheauthoz' own Tley shouldnoto atttbutedtotheWeWd Bank, its Boardof Directos,its managment,or any of itsmember counties. PolicyResearchl Transport| WPS1070 This paper - a product of the TransportDivision, Infrastructure and Urban DevelopmentDepartment'- is part of a larger effort in the departmentto evaluateoptions for chargingfor roaduse. Copiesof the paper are availablefree from the WorldBank, 1818H StreetNW,Washington, DC 20433.Please contact Jennifer Francis,room S 10-063,extension 31005 or 35205 (December1992, 96 pages). Hau presentsa conceptualframework for road On urban roads with indivisibilitiesand pricing based on a rigorousdiagrammatic
    [Show full text]
  • How Fair Is Road Pricing? Evaluating Equity in Transportation Pricing and Finance
    How Fair is Road Pricing? Evaluating Equity in Transportation Pricing and Finance September 29, 2010 This paper was prepared by a consultant to the Bipartisan Policy Center’s National Transportation Policy Project (NTPP). The opinions and recommendations in this paper are those of the consultant alone and not of the Bipartisan Policy Center or the members of NTPP. How Fair is Road Pricing? Evaluating Equity in Transportation Pricing and Finance September 29, 2010 Prepared by Brian D. Taylor, PhD, AICP Professor and Chair of Urban Planning Director, Institute of Transportation Studies UCLA School of Public Affairs Acknowledgements The author thanks Alexandra Evans and Rebecca Kalauskas who conducted background research for this paper, Hiroyuki Iseki and Eric Morris for their comments and suggestions, and Deborah Kim and Kim Tran who helped with editing and formatting. Table of Contents Executive Summary . 1 Overview of Transportation Pricing, Finance, and Equity . 5 Putting Transportation Pricing and Finance Equity in Context . 5 Competing Views of Fairness and Equity . 6 From Theory to Practice: Transportation Pricing and Finance Equity . 7 Geography and Equity . 9 Equitable Transportation Programs versus Equitable Transportation Systems . 12 The Divorce of Pricing and Finance in Transportation Policy . 13 Why the Push to Reunite Pricing and Finance? . 13 Transportation Pricing Equity: Compared to What? . 14 Case Studies: Addressing Equity Concerns in Practice . 19 Dedicating revenues to transit service and road improvements in the tolled corridor . .20 Limited scale and phased, incremental implementation . .20 Public outreach and education . 21 Conclusion: What’s a Fair Price for Transportation? . .23 Bibliography . .25 Appendix: Five Case Studies of Equity in Electronic Road Tolling Projects .
    [Show full text]
  • The Welfare Effect of Road Congestion Pricing
    The Welfare Effect of Road Congestion Pricing: Experimental Evidence and Equilibrium Implications∗ Gabriel E. Kreindler† January 17, 2018 Abstract The textbook policy response to traffic externalities is congestion pricing. However, quanti- fying the welfare consequences of pricing policies requires detailed knowledge of commuter pref- erences and of the road technology. I study the peak-hour traffic congestion equilibrium using rich travel behavior data and a field experiment grounded in theory. Using a newly developed smartphone app, I collected a panel data set with precise GPS coordinates for over 100,000 com- muter trips in Bangalore, India. To identify the key preference parameters in my model – the value of time spent driving and schedule flexibility – I designed and implemented a randomized experiment with two realistic congestion charge policies. The policies penalize peak-hour depar- ture times and driving through a small charged area, respectively. Structural estimates based on the experiment show that commuters exhibit moderate schedule flexibility and high value of time. In a separate analysis of the road technology, I find a moderate and linear effect of traffic volume on travel time. I combine the preference parameters and road technology using policy simulations of the equilibrium optimal congestion charge, which reveal notable travel time bene- fits, yet negligible welfare gains. Intuitively, the social value of the travel time saved by removing commuters from the peak-hour is not significantly larger than the costs to those commuters of traveling at different, inconvenient times. ∗I am deeply grateful to Ben Olken, Esther Duflo, Frank Schilbach, and Edward Glaeser for their advice and generous support throughout this project.
    [Show full text]