Methodology and Radical Political Economics

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Methodology and Radical Political Economics RESEARCH INSTITUTE POLITICAL ECONOMY Methodology and Radical Political Economics Martin H. Wolfson October 2007 Gordon Hall 418 North Pleasant Street Amherst, MA 01002 Phone: 413.545.6355 Fax: 413.577.0261 Presented at [email protected] www.peri.umass.edu REBELLIOUS MACROECONOMICS: MARX, KEYNES & CROTTY A conference in honor of James Crotty Methodology and Radical Political Economics Martin H. Wolfson Department of Economics and Policy Studies University of Notre Dame Notre Dame, IN 46556 Prepared for the Conference in honor of Jim Crotty University of Massachusetts at Amherst October 19-20, 2007 Methodology and Radical Political Economics by Martin H. Wolfson 1. Introduction Radical political economics has always encompassed a wide variety of economic theories and perspectives. In fact, printed in each issue of the Review of Radical Political Economics is the following statement: "As the journal of the Union for Radical Political Economics, the Review publishes innovative research in political economy broadly defined as including, but not confined to, Marxian economics, post-Keynesian economics, Sraffian economics, feminist economics, and radical institutional economics." Given the broad purview of radical political economics, the question arises: do the various theories that make up radical political economics have some methodological coherence, or are they disjoint B united in their opposition to neoclassical economics, but with theoretical assumptions, principles and methods, i.e., methodologies, that are incompatible with each other? The argument of this paper is that there is coherence.1 In particular, there is an emerging heterodox macroeconomic framework that builds upon the perspectives of Karl Marx, John Maynard Keynes, and institutionalists like Wesley Clair Mitchell.2 A leader in the development of this framework is James R. Crotty. Throughout his career, Crotty has investigated, and sought an integration of, Marxian, Keynesian, and institutionalist perspectives. In particular, Crotty's contributions have been to 1) combine principles from the three perspectives into an integrated framework, 2) deepen our understanding of the three perspectives by indicating how they are more complementary than typically understood, and, 3) extend the basic principles to provide a coherent understanding of the current 2 global economy. In the next section of the paper, key assumptions and principles of the Marxian, Keynesian, and institutional perspectives, which form the building blocks for the new framework, will be discussed. In the third section, Crotty's contributions to combining, deepening, and extending these perspectives into a new framework will be addressed. Finally, the fourth section concludes with a statement of the new methodological framework. 2. Building Blocks: Marx, Keynes, and Mitchell Below are the building blocks, or starting points, for the new heterodox macroeconomic framework. They are basic methodological assumptions and principles from Marx, Keynes, and Mitchell. They are often taken to be representative of three separate theories, with little or no convergence. 2.1. Karl Marx 1) Historical Materialism This basic philosophical perspective of Marx's has been the subject of numerous books, articles, and treatises. At the risk of oversimplification, I take it to mean two basic concepts. First, people's "material conditions," especially the social relations of production (the relationships people enter into in the process of production), have an important influence on the ideas, culture, religion, politics, and other aspects of the "superstructure" of society. This materialist point of view should be distinguished from determinism, which claims that the material conditions determine the superstructure, and from the view that the superstructure has no effect or influence on the material conditions. An important implication of Marx's materialist philosophy is that one needs to make a "concrete analysis of concrete conditions," i.e., 3 thoroughly investigate the reality one is trying to explain. Second, historical analysis is an essential component of the Marxian perspective. One cannot understand current reality without analyzing the historical forces that have brought the present into being. 2) Dialectical contradiction The process that propels history forward is the working out of the contradictory relationship between two opposing forces. These opposing forces have different interests and are always in struggle with each other. This perspective has two important and related implications. First, the change that results from contradictions is endogenous. It is internal to the contradictory relationship being analyzed. Second, there is no permanent equilibrium. The two opposing forces within a contradiction can arrive at a temporary equilibrium, which is best understood as stabilization at a moment in time. But because the two forces continue to be in contradiction with one another, struggle will continue that will eventually disrupt that temporary equilibrium. This is not to say that exogenous events cannot play a role in Marxian analysis. But Marx's concept of dialectical contradiction rules out the neoclassical view of equilibrium as a permanent end point that can be disrupted only by exogenous "shocks." 3) Class conflict In Marx's analysis, the fundamental contradiction in capitalist society is between capital and labor. The historical working out of the contradiction between these two opposing forces is the key to understanding the dynamics of a capitalist economy. 4 Also important are intra-class conflicts, such as those between industrial and financial capital, among capitalist firms competing with each other, and also among segments of the working class. 4) Theory of the state In capitalist society the dominant class, i.e., the capitalist class, has a dominant influence on the "state," taken to be the apparatus of government broadly conceived: the legislative and executive branches, the courts, police, military, etc. Many Marxists view the state as a "contested terrain," in which labor can vie for influence, but in which the capitalist class usually dominates because of instrumental and structural influences. Because of its income and wealth, the capitalist class can influence the levers, or "instruments" of state power. For example, representatives of the capitalist class can be appointed or elected to positions of power, and their lobbyists can influence decisions. Also, capitalists hold a central structural position within a capitalist economy. They hire and fire workers and make decisions about the expansion of production and investment. Even governments sympathetic to labor are influenced by the powerful role capitalists play in a capitalist economy. 5) Evolution of economic systems Marx analyzed a progression of economic systems, from simple commodity production, slavery, feudalism, to capitalism. He predicted that capitalism would be replaced by socialism. In the contradiction between capital and labor, labor would become dominant and would change the institutional structures defining capitalism to those compatible with a socialist system. Aiding this transition would be the contradiction between the forces of production (such as plant 5 and equipment, technology, and human skills and abilities) and the social relations of production. Marx thought that capitalist social relations would increasingly become obstacles to further growth of the forces of production, and would be transformed. Despite continuing controversies about Marx's prediction of socialism, his theory that class struggle, and the contradiction between the forces and social relations of production, would lead to a new institutional structure is a key building block of the new macroeconomic framework, as discussed below. 2.2. John Maynard Keynes 1) Fundamental uncertainty Nobel laureate Niels Bohr said Ait is difficult to make predictions, especially about the future.@ As Keynes stressed, about much of the future, we simply do not know. Note that this is much different from the neoclassical concept of risk, which enables one to know all possible future events and establish a probability for each. 2) Financial crises and speculation Because of fundamental uncertainty, financial markets are subject to crises and speculation. Herd behavior leads to euphoric booms and sudden panic, when the optimistic expectations that fueled the boom are not fulfilled. 2.3. Wesley Clair Mitchell 1) Endogenous business cycle Mitchell, the founder of the National Bureau of Economic Research, was a leading institutional economist of the early twentieth century. He pioneered quantitative research on the business cycle. Based on his research, he hypothesized an endogenous business cycle with 6 various stages, such as recovery, expansion, crisis, panic, and depression. Mitchell's business cycle is endogenous in the sense that it traces a process of cumulative change in which one stage of the cycle is transformed into the next. 2) Institutional methods Mitchell's methods were both quantitative and institutional. He accumulated data on hundreds of data series and then analyzed the data inductively to create his theoretical concepts. He focused on quantitative data. Other institutionalists have used other methods, such as surveys, participant-observer techniques, pattern models, historical analysis, etc. But like all institutionalists, he understood that a concrete, detailed investigation of institutional conditions was a necessary element to the understanding
Recommended publications
  • Political Economy Research Institute, University of Massachusetts at Amherst, December
    RESEARCH INSTITUTE POLITICAL ECONOMY Does Heterodox Economics Need a Crisis Theory? From Profit-Squeeze to the Global Liquidity Meltdown Gary A. Dymski October 2007 Gordon Hall 418 North Pleasant Street Amherst, MA 01002 Phone: 413.545.6355 Fax: 413.577.0261 Presented at [email protected] www.peri.umass.edu REBELLIOUS MACROECONOMICS: MARX, KEYNES & CROTTY A conference in honor of James Crotty Does Heterodox Macroeconomics Need a Crisis Theory? From Profit-Squeeze to the Global Liquidity Meltdown Gary A. Dymski August 21, 2007∗ What has yet to be accomplished and what is perhaps the most pressing task presently confronting macroeconomists is the development of a theoretical framework that can adequately incorporate both of these set of contributions [those of Keynes and Marx] and model the complex and rapidly evolving structure of mutual interaction and codetermination between the real and financial sectors. (James Crotty, 1990, p. 541) Introduction Is there a need for a heterodox macroeconomic theory of crisis? If so, what are its elements, and how can these be used to make sense of developments in the world’s economies? Among James Crotty’s definitive contributions to heterodox theory are his forceful answers to these questions. Crotty’s writings on macroeconomics and crisis have had three distinct phases. The centerpiece of his first phase was the paper on the political business-cycle he wrote with Boddy, which is discussed below. In the 1980s, Jim deepened his theoretical understanding of the sources, forms, and trajectories of economic crises. This involved him in extended readings of Marx, Keynes, Schumpeter, and Kalecki.
    [Show full text]
  • Why Keynes-Minsky Theory Must Replace Efficient Market Theory As the Guide to Financial Regulation Policy
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Crotty, James Working Paper The realism of assumptions does matter: Why Keynes-Minsky theory must replace efficient market theory as the guide to financial regulation policy Working Paper, No. 2011-05 Provided in Cooperation with: Department of Economics, University of Massachusetts Suggested Citation: Crotty, James (2011) : The realism of assumptions does matter: Why Keynes-Minsky theory must replace efficient market theory as the guide to financial regulation policy, Working Paper, No. 2011-05, University of Massachusetts, Department of Economics, Amherst, MA This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/64225 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents
    [Show full text]
  • Accumulation and Crisis, Theory of See Crisis Theory Agent Choice
    Index Accumulation and crisis, theory of see Bank of England, 119, 133, 135, 142 Crisis theory Banking Review, 111 Agent choice Banks generally, 27 bonus-driven incentive system, use of see consciousness of ignorance, 46, 47 Bonus-driven incentive system macrotheory, relationship to, 39–49 capital requirements see Capital path dependency, 26, 42–44, 161, requirements 282, 312 deregulation of, 30–31 residual hypothesis, 45 excessive leverage, 32 subjectivist and objectivist approaches failures, number of, 113–114 to, 40–41 hiring practices, 156 Aglietta, Michel, 279 large banks, growth of, 113–116 Aglietta and Breton study, 279 Baran, Paul, 10, 204 AIG, 131, 136, 141 Baran and Sweezy study, 10, 204, 236 Am I a Liberal?, 310, 315 Basle Committee, 121 Amromin, G., 27 Basle Rules, 132, 135 Amromin and Sharpe study, 27 Bear Stearns Animal spirits, 50, 53, 54 generally, 119, 120, 136 Annuities, 123 compensation practices of, 153 Armey, Dick, 364 Beaver, W., 20 Arrighi, Giovanni, 279 Bebchuk, Cohen and Spamann study, Arrighi and Silver study, 279 153 Asian Development Bank, 392 Bebchuk, Lucian, 153 Asymmetric information Becker, J., 146 generally, 14, 33, 253 Becker and Morgenson study, 146 New Keynesian theory, in, 175–189 Behaviorists, 14–15 passim Berle, Adolf, 206 Athenaeum, 308 Berle and Means study, 206 Austerity policies Bernstein, J., 262 generally, 1–3, 10, 263, 269, 274 Black, Fischer, 24 European resistance to, 383 Blankfein, L., 139 public employees as target, 377 Blinder, Allan, 59 South Korea, in see South Korean Block, F., 63 crisis
    [Show full text]
  • Was the IMF's Imposition of Economic Regime Change in Korea Justified
    Was the IMF’s Imposition of Economic Regime Change in Korea Justified? A Critique of the IMF’s Economic and Political Role in Korean During and After the Crisis By James Crotty University of Massachusetts, Amherst And Kang-Kook Lee Ritsumeikan University Japan Second Draft June 2004 James Crotty would like to thank the Political Economy Research Institute at the University of Massachusetts, Amherst campus, for research support. We are grateful to Jerry Epstein for comments on an earlier draft. Abstract As late as October 1997 the IMF declared that the Korean economy was experiencing a temporary liquidity squeeze, not a solvency problem. Yet in December 1997 Deputy Managing Director Stanley Fischer declared that Korea suffered from a systemic “breakdown of economic relations” so complete that only radical economic restructuring could restore prosperity. The IMF attached what it called “extreme structural conditionality” to its loan agreements with Korea, demanding a complete and rapid transition from Korea’s traditional East Asian economic model to a globally integrated neoliberal model. We subject the IMF’s assertion that the allocative efficiency of the Korean economy had collapsed by 1997 to a number of empirical tests, including time series and cross-section analyses of capital productivity and corporate profitability, and firm and industry level econometric tests of the proposition that investment spending was excessive and misallocated in the pre-crisis period. This evidence does not support the IMF’s systemic breakdown claim. We conclude that the IMF’s imposition of “extreme structural conditionality” on Korea is best understood as an illegitimate and anti-democratic exercise of power designed to meet the needs of the IMF’s key constituents rather than those of the majority of Korea’s people.
    [Show full text]
  • Why There Is Chronic Excess Capacity Crotty
    Why There Is Chronic Excess Capacity Crotty THE MARKET FAILURES ISSUE trolled financial markets, and built social welfare systems. They also began to regulate aggregate demand in pursuit of high employment and fast growth, a phenomenon known as the “Keynesian revolution.” Business and financial interests accepted Why There Is Chronic Excess these changes in part because strong capital controls and low levels of trade and investment flows after the war left them with- Capacity out a credible “runaway” threat to undercut government eco- nomic policies they disliked. The global prosperity that characterized the quarter century following the war—the so- James Crotty called “Golden Age” of modern capitalism—reinforced the be- lief that market economies need strong social regulation to function effectively. Why is there excess capacity in the world today? The Contradictions inherent in Golden Age capitalism led in time neoclassical economics that came to power in the 1970s to the end of prosperity.1 Economic instability began in the late argues essentially that supply should create its own 1960s and erupted full force in the 1970s with two Organization demand—Say’s Law. But it has not worked out that of the Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC) oil price shocks, way. This economist returns to the work of early the collapse of the Bretton Woods fixed exchange rate system, theorists to explain what happened, and why the de- and the buildup of excessive debt in the third world. These prob- emphasis of demand-oriented policies has failed to work. lems created a powerful movement, led by business and espe- cially financial interests, to roll back the economic regulatory power of national governments, replacing conscious societal N THE AFTERMATH OF THE GREAT DEPRESSION AND WORLD WAR II, control with the “invisible hand” of unregulated markets, and national economies, even those in which markets played a to eliminate restrictions on the flow of goods and money across Ivery powerful role, were placed under the ultimate control borders, creating an integrated global economy.
    [Show full text]
  • Financialization and Capital Accumulation in the Nonfinancial
    Munich Personal RePEc Archive Financialization and Capital Accumulation in the Nonfinancial Corporate Sector: A Theoretical and Empirical Investigation on the US Economy, 1973-2004 Orhangazi, Ozgur Roosevelt University, Political Economy Research Institute University of Massachusetts Amherst 1 October 2007 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/7724/ MPRA Paper No. 7724, posted 13 Mar 2008 00:47 UTC RESEARCH INSTITUTE POLITICAL ECONOMY Financialization and Capital Accumulation in the Non-Financial Corporate Sector: A Theoretical and Empirical Investigation of the U.S. Economy: 1973-2003 Özgür Orhangazi October 2007 Gordon Hall 418 North Pleasant Street Amherst, MA 01002 Phone: 413.545.6355 Fax: 413.577.0261 [email protected] www.peri.umass.edu WORKINGPAPER SERIES Number 149 FINANCIALIZATION AND CAPITAL ACCUMULATION IN THE NON-FINANCIAL CORPORATE SECTOR A Theoretical and Empirical Investigation of the U.S. Economy: 1973-2003 Özgür Orhangazi Department of Economics Roosevelt University 430 S. Michigan Ave. Chicago IL, 60605 [email protected] 312.322.7113 December 2006 FINANCIALIZATION AND CAPITAL ACCUMULATION IN THE NON-FINANCIAL CORPORATE SECTOR A Theoretical and Empirical Investigation of the U.S. Economy: 1973-2003 Abstract Recent research has explored the growing ‘financialization’ process in the U.S. and other advanced economies. The term is a catch-all phrase used to denote important changes in the structure of non- financial corporations’ balance sheets, including the growth of income from financial subsidiaries and investment as well as growth in the transfer of earnings to financial markets in the forms of interest payments, dividend payments and stock buybacks. This paper seeks to empirically explore the relationship between financialization in the U.S economy and real investment at the firm level.
    [Show full text]
  • The Profit Doctrine
    The Profit Doctrine The Profit Doctrine Economists of the Neoliberal Era Robert Chernomas and Ian Hudson First published 2017 by Pluto Press 345 Archway Road, London N6 5AA www.plutobooks.com Copyright © Robert Chernomas and Ian Hudson 2017 The right of Robert Chernomas and Ian Hudson to be identified as the authors of this work has been asserted by them in accordance with the Copyright, Designs and Patents Act 1988. British Library Cataloguing in Publication Data A catalogue record for this book is available from the British Library ISBN 978 0 7453 3586 5 Hardback ISBN 978 0 7453 3585 8 Paperback ISBN 978 1 7837 1993 8 PDF eBook ISBN 978 1 7837 1995 2 Kindle eBook ISBN 978 1 7837 1994 5 EPUB eBook This book is printed on paper suitable for recycling and made from fully managed and sustained forest sources. Logging, pulping and manufacturing processes are expected to conform to the environmental standards of the country of origin. Typeset by Stanford DTP Services, Northampton, England Simultaneously printed in the United Kingdom and United States of America To Anwar Shaikh and the late David M. Gordon for cultivating my appreciation for theory in historical context. RC To Lisa Johnston. For everything. IH Contents List of Boxes, Figures and Tables viii List of Abbreviations ix Acknowledgements xi 1 Prophets and Profits 1 2 The Contest of Economic Ideas: Survival of the Richest 12 3 The Consequences of Economic Ideas 35 4 Milton Friedman: The Godfather of the Age of Instability and Inequality 55 5 The Deregulationists: Public Choice and
    [Show full text]
  • What Is Stagnation?
    6 What Is Stagnation? JOHN BELLAMY FOSTER INTRODUCTION For a majority of mainstream and radicftl economists, the answer to the question "What is Stagnation"? is fairly simple and straightforward and devoid of any real theoretical significance in and of itself. Either it is seen as a period of longer and deeper than average recessions, or it stands for a long-cycle downturn, which will be followed more or less automatically, after some 25 years duration, by a long-cycle upturn. However, in the case of most of those thinkers on the left who continue to emphasize the primacy of demand-side constraints on the accumulation process in ''the present as history,'' the search for an answer to the above question is nothing less than an attempt to address the central contradiction of the mature monopoly capitalist system. The purpose of this article is to uncover the complex historical logic through which the phenomenon of stagnation is manifested in modern capitalism, as explained in the work of such radical demand-side theorists as Michal Kalecki, Josef Steindl, Paul Baran, Paul Sweezy and Harry Magdoff. Beginning with the reasons why a condition of stagnation (the main traits of which are widening underemployment, stop-and-start investment and slow growth) has come to represent the normal trend-line of the modem economy around which the recurrent fluctuations of the business cycle occur, the analysis will then shift to a consideration of the various self-limiting forces that sparked the expansionary wave of the 1960s; and how a waning of these forces, or of their positive effects, has led in the 1970s and 1980s to a resurfacing of stagnation and a doubling-over of economic contradictions.
    [Show full text]
  • Political Economy Research Institute
    RESEARCH INSTITUTE POLITICAL ECONOMY POLITICAL ECONOMY RESEARCH INSTITUTE University of Massachusetts Amherst Slow Growth, Destructive Competition, and Low Road Labor Relations: A Keynes-Marx-Schumpeter Analysis of Neoliberal Globalization James Crotty 2000 10th floor Thompson Hall University of Massachusetts Amherst, MA, 01003-7510 Telephone: (413) 545-6355 Facsimile: (413) 545-2921 Email:[email protected] Website: http://www.umass.edu/peri/ WORKINGPAPER SERIES Number 6 Slow Growth, Destructive Competition, and Low Road Labor Relations: A Keynes-Marx-Schumpeter Analysis of Neoliberal Globalization James Crotty Economics Department University of Massachusetts, Amherst Second Draft: November 2000 This paper was written for presentation at the KDEA-KSESA Joint International Conference on The Future of the Korean Economy in the Context of Globalizing Capital, held at Suanbo, Korea, June 22, 2000. I am grateful to the Ford Foundation and the Political Economy Research Institute at the University of Massachusetts for generous support of my research. A central lesson drawn from the experience of the decades between the World Wars was that the economic and political fate of the world could not safely be entrusted to unregulated, free market national and global economic systems. History warned that this was a path to economic instability, global depression and political chaos. In the aftermath of World War II, national economies, even those in which markets played a very powerful role, would be placed under the ultimate control of governments, while international economic relations would be consciously managed by the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and World Bank. Trade was expected to rise in importance, but it was thought at the time that the degree of global financial integration would remain modest, with cross border money flows under tight government control.
    [Show full text]
  • Capitalism on Trial Edited by Jeannette Wicks-Lim and Robert Pollin
    Capitalism on Trial edited by Jeannette Wicks-Lim and Robert Pollin Edward Elgar 2013 Downloaded from Elgar Online by not authorized at 07/16/2013 09:47:19AM Contents ___________________________________________________ List of contributors ix Acknowledgments xi Introduction 1 Robert Pollin and Jeannette Wicks-Lim PART 1: REFLECTIONS ON THOMAS E. WEISSKOPF’S CONTRIBUTIONS TO POLITICAL ECONOMY 1. Three’s a crowd: my dinner party with Karl, Leon, and Maynard 17 Samuel Bowles 2. Theses on Weisskopf 42 Robert Pollin 3. Comment 60 Diane Flaherty PART 2: ISSUES IN DEVELOPING ECONOMIES 4. The military and economic development in Pakistan 67 Shahrukh Khan 5. Socialism: the twentieth century and the twenty-first century 81 Minqi Li 6. Economic growth: the great slowdown (1980–2000) and recovery 99 (2000–2010) Mark Weisbrot 7. Comment 114 James K. Boyce PART 3: POWER DYNAMICS IN CAPITALISM 8. The wealth–power connection 123 Arthur MacEwan 9. The rise and decline of patriarchal capitalism 140 Nancy Folbre v Downloaded from Elgar Online by not authorized at 07/16/2013 09:47:19AM vi Capitalism on trial 10. Comment 156 Andrew Zimbalist PART 4: TRENDS IN US LABOR MARKETS 11. The rising strength of management, high unemployment, and slow growth: revisiting Okun’s Law 165 Michael Reich 12. Reducing growth to achieve environmental sustainability: the role of work hours 187 Kyle Knight, Eugene A. Rosa, and Juliet B. Schor 13. Comment 205 Michael Ash PART 5: DISCRIMINATION AND THE ROLE OF AFFIRMATIVE ACTION POLICIES 14. Confronting those affirmative action grumbles 215 William Darity Jr 15. Screening for honesty and motivation in the workplace: what can affirmative action do? 224 Elaine McCrate 16.
    [Show full text]
  • Keynes Against Capitalism University of Novi Sad, Faculty of Technical Sciences, Department of Social Sciences, by James Crotty Serbia
    PANOECONOMICUS, 2020, Vol. 67, Issue 2, pp. 265-275 Book review Received: 31 March 2020. Alpar Lošonc Keynes against Capitalism University of Novi Sad, Faculty of Technical Sciences, Department of Social Sciences, by James Crotty Serbia [email protected] Routledge, 2019. How is it possible that John Maynard Keynes’ theory has been misunderstood for dec- ades? How could “virtually all post World War II Keynesian economists” (Crotty) fail to understand the critical aspects of Keynes’ work? Is it really possible that likely the most influential economist of all times has been constantly exposed to the acts of mis- representation? How could it be that even Joseph Schumpeter did not comprehend Keynes’ dynamics of business cycles? These are, in short, the central issues of James Crotty’s book, an American econ- omist who bears the imprint of heterodoxy. First, a closer look at Keynes’ theoretical and political work is necessary in order to analyze some elements of his work so that the critical argument can be developed against mainstream Keynesianism. Namely, a number of interpreters aiming to interpret Keynes as part of the same old academic economic theory simultaneously misclassified him, that is, disregarded the most pro- vocative parts of his work. In other words, the tamed Keynes has become the prey of mainstream Keynesianism. Even though Keynes successfully fought the classical the- ory, he could not influence the course of reception after his death. Second, the standard assumption that the author of The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money is a certified and persistent savior of the collapsed capitalism must be rethought.
    [Show full text]
  • Interview with Professor James Crotty Umass Amherst June 3, 2016 1 Of
    Interview with Professor James Crotty UMass Amherst June 3, 2016 This is an edited version of the transcript of an interview carried out with Professor James Crotty, Emeritus Professor of Economics, University of Massachusetts, Amherst at his home in Amherst in May 2016 by J.W Mason and Arjun Jayadev. ON HIS CHILDHOOD GROWING UP CATHOLIC WORKING CLASS IN THE BRONX Interviewer: Tell us a little about your childhood and growing up Catholic in the Bronx… and how do you think that’s shaped you in the years that have followed? Crotty: To quote Steve Martin, I was born at a very young age. It was fun growing up in the Bronx when I grew up. I grew up in a working class area, somewhat ethnically segregated except for the Italian neighborhoods. It was tons of kids together. You can do whatever you want. You get in trouble if you wanted. You can go play ball all the time. The transportation system in New York was phenomenal and cheap. So, as soon as you got to be ten or eleven years old you could get a quarter and go down to Manhattan. You could do whatever you wanted. And so I enjoyed that. It was completely working class area. I sincerely believe that I never met a professional person until I was 30. Till I left New York, there were mostly only people like me, like our family. My father was a bus driver for the city, a trade union guy. And he was active - he didn’t have a leadership role.
    [Show full text]