Fish Banks an Economic Model to Scale Marine Conservation

Fish Banks an Economic Model to Scale Marine Conservation

Marine Policy 73 (2016) 154–161 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Marine Policy journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/marpol Fish banks: An economic model to scale marine conservation Enric Sala a,n, Christopher Costello b, Jaime De Bourbon Parme c, Marco Fiorese d, Geoff Heal e, Kieran Kelleher f, Russell Moffitt g, Lance Morgan g, Jayne Plunkett h, Kristin D. Rechberger i, Andrew A. Rosenberg j, Rashid Sumaila k a National Geographic Society, Washington, DC 20036, USA b Bren School of Environmental Science & Management, UC Santa Barbara, Santa Barbara, CA 93106, USA c Ministry of Foreign Affairs of the Netherlands, 2500 EB The Hague, The Netherlands d Monaco-Asia Society, Monaco e Columbia Business School, Columbia University, New York, NY 10027, USA f The World Bank, Washington, DC 20433, USA g Marine Conservation Institute, Seattle, WA 98103, USA h Swiss Reinsurance Company, Geneva, Switzerland i Dynamic Planet, Washington, DC 20009, USA j Union of Concerned Scientists, Cambridge, MA, USA k Institute for the Ocean and Fisheries, University of British Columbia, Vancouver, BC, Canada V6T 1Z4 article info abstract Article history: Only 2.1% of the ocean is in actively managed marine protected areas (MPAs). Achieving the United Received 24 February 2016 Nations' target of 10% of the ocean protected by 2020 will require an aggressively implemented mix of Received in revised form large MPAs in remote areas, and small MPAs in inhabited coastal areas. Replication of small no-take MPAs 31 July 2016 (marine reserves) in coastal areas at the global scale is more likely to occur if reserves are designed as Accepted 31 July 2016 investment opportunities –‘fish banks’ that produce new profits based on ecosystem services such as tourism and fish production. Here a pro forma business plan for a marine reserve using private invest- ment and local management is presented. Total annual profit before the reserve was €254,000 (from fishing only); in year 8 after creation of the reserve, profit(fishingþtourism) was €3.3 million. Given the right conditions, the net present value of the reserve can be between 4 and 12 times greater than the no- reserve counterfactual. In our model, (1) the tourism sector covers the costs of creation and operation of the reserve as an investment in a profitable business; and (2) fishers become shareholders and receive income from tourist access fees; their profits increase as soon as one year after the creation of the re- serve. A series of financing mechanisms to create and manage fish banks is also proposed. If designed properly, fish banks can help restore marine biodiversity and ecosystem services, and can create jobs, help fishers, and bring in significantly greater economic profits than the absence of protection. & 2016 The Authors. Published by Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved. 1. Introduction protected areas (MPAs) in inhabited areas, and a smaller number of very large MPAs (100,000 s km2 each) in remote places. Creation While 14% of earth's land surface is protected from extractive of very large no-take marine reserves such as Chile's Nazca-Des- use, only 2.1% of the ocean is in actively managed Marine Protected venturadas Marine Park and the U.S. Pacific Remote Islands Marine Areas (MPAs) (Fig. 1). Declines in many of the world's fisheries, National Monument will boost the percentage of the ocean pro- combined with threats from invasive species, pollution, and ocean tected. However, there is no commonly-adopted formula for re- acidification recently led the parties of the UN Convention on plicating small-scale, locally-endorsed marine reserve successes to the global scale. Here a business approach whereby marine re- Biological Diversity (CBD) to set a target of 10% of marine and serves can be created and managed locally through private in- coastal areas protected by 2020 (Aichi Biodiversity Target 11 [1]). vestment is proposed. This approach will rely heavily on no-take How will this ambitious target be met? It could likely be achieved marine reserves, which have shown the biggest ecological and through a combination of tens of thousands of small marine economic benefits caused by the restoration of ecosystem services [2,3] (in addition to partially-protected MPAs). n fi Corresponding author. No-take marine reserves can act like nancial investments with E-mail address: [email protected] (E. Sala). a principal set aside that produces interest, if they are well http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.marpol.2016.07.032 0308-597X/& 2016 The Authors. Published by Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved. E. Sala et al. / Marine Policy 73 (2016) 154–161 155 Fig. 1. The marine protected areas (MPAs) of the world: partially-protected MPAs (orange areas), no-take marine reserves (green), and other protected areas (e.g., protected on paper but with insufficient legislation or enforcement; blue). Currently 2.1% of the ocean is in marine protected areas sensu lato, and only 1% of the ocean is in no-take marine reserves (mpatlas.org). The 15 largest MPAs that have been implemented are highlighted. It would take 17,600 more average-sized MPAs to achieve the UN Con- vention on Biological Diversity target of 10% of the ocean protected by 2020. (For interpretation of the references to color in this figure legend, the reader is referred to the web version of this article.) designed and managed. Marine reserves result in an average in- protection by providing exclusive access to local fishers, busi- crease of 446% in fish biomass within a decade, relative to un- nesses, or communities [10]. Establishing these access rights en- protected areas nearby [2]; the restoration of ecosystem services sures that a community benefits from its own conservation ac- such as fish production (through spillover of fish and in- tions, thus securing a platform for investment by other actors. vertebrates) that can benefit the adjacent fishing industry [4,5]; Here a pro forma business plan is developed to show how to im- and increased biodiversity that can attract more tourism, produ- plement fish banks and capitalize on the ecosystem services they cing up to 36 times more revenue than fishing [6]. In addition, the provide, and describe some financing mechanisms to create and protection of coastal ecosystems preserves important ecosystem manage fish banks. services such as efficient carbon sequestration [7], coastal pro- tection from storms [8], and replenishment of local fisheries [9]. Why have these bright spots not been replicated globally? The 2. Material and methods main reasons are lack of awareness among stakeholders, in- appropriate governance, and unsustainable funding models. Be- The creation of a marine reserve was modeled, exclusively with cause protection often results in short-run losses and fishers lack private investment, and managed by a local entity of shareholders secure and exclusive access to the spillover from marine reserves (fishers and tourist operators), using empirical data from the (which are a local public good in economic terminology), fishers Medes Islands (see below). For simplicity our model considers only rationally choose the status quo over the prospect of better fishing ‘ecotourists’ who visit the reserve to dive, snorkel, and/or tour the opportunities and livelihoods within a few years. reserve on glass bottom boats, as the new source of revenue By coupling institutional reform and private investment, mar- (though fishing remains a revenue source). In our model, all eco- ine reserves could be seen as ‘fish banks’–an investment in future tourists pay a reserve access fee (as opposed to only scuba divers prosperity rather than a foregone economic opportunity. Empirical currently); fishermen receive a percentage of these access fees as data show that the economic benefits of reserves can offset the compensation for foregoing a fraction of their traditional fishing costs of closure in as little as five years, in some cases doubling the grounds; and the tourism industry covers the establishment of the income of local fishers [4]. An important consideration for any reserve and part of its management costs, since they are likely to form of private investment involves securing the benefits of be the ones to benefit the most economically. Tourist activity 156 E. Sala et al. / Marine Policy 73 (2016) 154–161 increased over time after the creation of the reserve, and the T πt analysis captured their gradual increase, starting in year 0 when NPV = ∑ t (+)1 r ()1 the reserve is created and the management structure is put in t=0 place; tourism starts to arrive on year 1 after the creation of the where t is the year, and t¼0 is the year of creation of the reserve reserve (Table S1). Costs, revenues and profits were calculated for (there is no tourism yet); T is the timeframe for which NPV is fi the rst eight years after the creation of the reserve, when the calculated (8 years in our case); π is profit; and r is the discount total number of dives in the reserve reached equilibrium at the rate (we used 7% since typical discount rates for environmental maximum allowed quota [4]. Finally, the Net Present Value (NPV) projects are between 4 and 8%). of the reserve over an 8-year time horizon was calculated under To explore what could be the economically ideal size of the different scenarios of protection and compensation, for both reserve for both tourism industry and fishers our model used an fi tourism industry and shers. extension of Sala et al.'s [4] bioeconomic model. The model as- The Medes Islands Marine Reserve was protected in 1983, and sumed conservatively that costs and revenues (for tourism and fi tourist numbers increased as sh size and abundance increased reserve management) would increase linearly with an increase in within its boundaries [4,11] (Table S1).

View Full Text

Details

  • File Type
    pdf
  • Upload Time
    -
  • Content Languages
    English
  • Upload User
    Anonymous/Not logged-in
  • File Pages
    8 Page
  • File Size
    -

Download

Channel Download Status
Express Download Enable

Copyright

We respect the copyrights and intellectual property rights of all users. All uploaded documents are either original works of the uploader or authorized works of the rightful owners.

  • Not to be reproduced or distributed without explicit permission.
  • Not used for commercial purposes outside of approved use cases.
  • Not used to infringe on the rights of the original creators.
  • If you believe any content infringes your copyright, please contact us immediately.

Support

For help with questions, suggestions, or problems, please contact us