10. Euclidean Spaces

10. Euclidean Spaces

10. Euclidean Spaces Most of the spaces used in traditional consumer, producer, and general equilibrium theory will be Euclidean spaces—spaces where Euclid’s geometry rules. At this point, we have to start being a little more careful how we write things. We will start with the space Rn, the space of n-vectors, n-tuples of real numbers. When we are being picky, we write them vertically as if they are n 1 matrices. × x1 x2 x = . , . x n just as we did when writing linear systems as matrix products, Ax = b. The xi are referred to as the coordinates of the vector. 2 MATH METHODS 10.1 Vectors Vertical and Horizontal Sometimes, especially in text, we will be informal and write vectors horizontally, but this is not strictly correct. I will sometimes attach a transpose symbol to remind you they should be vertical. Truly horizontal “vectors” are called co-vectors or covariant vectors. They differ from vectors in how they transform if you change coordinates. Ordinary vectors are sometimes called contravariant vectors. We can see this distinction when thinking of commodity vectors and their associated price vectors. Suppose we decide to measure milk in quarts rather than gallons. The quantities of all the different types of milk (skim, 2% milkfat, whole, chocolate, etc.) would all have to be multiplied by 4 to reflect the change in measurement because there are 4 quarts in a gallon. This is not how this measurement change affects prices. No, no, no! Price “vectors” are actually covectors, and if milk costs 2.40 per gallon, that’s 0.60 per quart. We have to divide the prices by 4 rather than multiplying by 4. This is the essence of the distinction between vectors and covectors. If we were being really picky, which we won’t, the vectors would use superscripts for their coordinates and the covectors would use subscripts. Although that is a use- ful convention in geometry and physics, it conflicts with other useful conventions in economics. One such is to use superscripts to indicate ownership—which consumer a commodity vector belongs to or which firm is using inputs and producing outputs. 10. EUCLIDEAN SPACES 3 10.2 Vectors 1 In R2, a vector x = looks like this: 2 x2 x2 b x x x1 x1 Figure 10.2.1: Although we will mostly treat vectors as points in the plane, as in the left panel of Figure 10.2.1, it is often useful to think of them as indicating a direction, which x does in the right panel of Figure 10.2.1. In mathematics this is sometimes indicated by using vector bundles. A vector bundle indicates the starting point as well as the direction. We will not make explicit use of vector bundles. 4 MATH METHODS 10.3 Vector Addition Algebraically, vector addition is just matrix addition. We add the components. x1 y1 x1 + y1 x2 y2 x2 + y2 . + . = . . x y x + y n n n n When we add vectors on a diagram, we add them nose to tail, placing the starting point of the second vector at the end of the first. x2 a + b b a a b x1 Figure 10.3.1: Two ways to add vectors: Here we add a = (1, 2)T to b = (2, 1)T . The upper combination is a + b and the lower b + a. Of course, both end at the same point, (3, 3)T , because matrix and thus vector addition are commutative. The red vector is the sum (a + b). In fact, we can read off the diagram that a = (1, 2) and b = (2, 1). 10. EUCLIDEAN SPACES 5 10.4 Scalar Multiplication We can also multiply vectors by scalars. We still use the rules of matrix algebra so x1 αx1 x2 αx2 α . = . . x αx n n The diagram illustrates this graphically. x2 2a a x1 a − Figure 10.4.1: Vector Multiplication: Here a = ( 1.5, 1)T is multiplied by 2. Multiplying − by a larger number would extend the line further. Multiplying by a smaller number would shrink toward the origin. Finally, multiplying by a negative number goes in the opposite direction as illustrated by a. − 6 MATH METHODS 10.5 Coordinate Vectors in Rn n The standard basis vectors in R , ek, are defined by ek = (δik), so 1 0 0 0 1 0 . e1 = 0 , e2 = 0 , en = . . ··· . . 0 0 0 1 These vectors are also referred to as the canonical basis vectors. We can write any vector x as a sum of basis vectors, x1 n x2 x = . = x1e1 + x2e2 + + xnen = xiei. ··· i=1 x X n The sum can also be written as a matrix product. x1 x2 x = e1 e2 en . ··· . x n 1 0 0 x1 ··· 0 1 0 x2 = . ···. . . .. . 0 0 1 xn ··· = Inx. 10. EUCLIDEAN SPACES 7 10.6 Linear Transformations We are now ready to show that any linear transformation T : Rn Rm can be written in matrix form. Theorem 10.6.1. Let T : Rn Rm be a linear transformation. Then→ there is an m n × matrix A with T = TA. n n Proof. We can write x = →j=1 xjej. Then T(x)= j=1 xjT(ej) for any vector x. The vector T(e ) is in Rm. We denote its ith component by T(e ) , i = 1,...,m. j P P j i Define the m n matrix A by setting aij = T(ej)i. Thus A = T(ej)i . × n With this definition of A, T(x) = a x , so T(x) = Ax. This shows that i j=1 ij j T = TA. P This means that the matrix A = T(e ) T(e ) T(en) 1 2 ··· represents T. 8 MATH METHODS 10.7 Matrix Representations of Linear Transformations ◮ Example 10.7.1: Linear Transformation as Matrix. Suppose T : R2 R3 is a linear transformation with 1 1 − → T(e1)= 0 and T(e2)= 1 . 3 ! 2 ! Then it can be represented by the matrix 1 1 − A = 0 1 3 2 ! so that x x 1 − 2 Ax = x2 . 3x1 +2x2 ! ◭ 10. EUCLIDEAN SPACES 9 10.8 Row Vectors vs. Column Vectors I’m insisting on writing vectors as columns. One reason I gave earlier was that we can then write our linear systems with coefficient matrix A as Ax = b. But you might object that you could just take the transpose, obtaining xT AT = bT , and redefine the coefficient matrix to be AT . That may seen slightly unnatural because we would always put the variable on the left, but math is sometimes done that way, particular in some areas of algebra. The real issue is that we need to maintain a distinction between the row vectors and column vectors. Suppose we had a linear function f that maps Rn into R. Such a linear function is called a linear functional. As we just saw, that kind of linear function can be represented bya1 n matrix × A = f(e ) f(e ) f(en) . 1 2 ··· If we write the vectors as columns, the linear functionals become row vectors. Thus the row (covariant) vector (1, 3, 0, 1) defines a linear functional on (contravariant) vectors in R4 by x1 x2 1 3 0 1 = x1 +3x2 + x4. x3 x4 Which one is which is completely arbitrary. But the weight of mathematical tradition, stretching back at least to the 19th century, is to make the regular vectors columns, and the linear functionals rows. It’s implicit in the Ricci calculus that Einstein used to develop the general theory of relativity. In economics, vectors of goods should be represented as columns, but price vectors are properly represented as rows. Thus each set of prices defines a linear functional on the space of goods. If we purchase two different commodity bundles, the cost of them is the sum of the costs, and if we purchase a multiple of a particular commodity bundle under the same price system, its cost is the same multiple of the original. The cost of a bundle is both additive and multiplicative, so it is a linear functional on the commodity space. 10 MATH METHODS 10.9 Vector Spaces: Definition Both Rn and Cn, the set of complex n-tuples or n-vectors, are examples of vector spaces. But what are vector spaces? They are sets of things called vectors that can be added together and multiplied by scalars (numbers). The addition and multiplication has to obey certain rules. Vector Space. A vector space (V, +, ) over a number field F (the set of scalars) is a set of vectors V with two operations: vector· addition, which defines x + y V for all vectors x, y V; and scalar multiplication, which defines αx for any scalar∈ α F and any vector∈ x V. Scalar multiplication and vector addition obey the following∈ properties: ∈ 1. For all x, y V, x + y = y + x (addition commutes). ∈ 2. For all x, y, z V, (x + y)+ z = x + (y + z) (addition associates). ∈ 3. There exists a unique vector 0 V with x + 0 = 0 + x = x (additive identity). ∈ 4. For all x V, there is a unique vector x V with x + ( x) = 0 (additive inverse). ∈ − ∈ − 5. For all x V,1x = x (multiplicative identity). ∈ 6. For all α, β F and x V, α(βx) = (αβ)x (scalar multiplication associates). ∈ ∈ 7. For all α F and x, y V, α(x + y)= αx + αy (distributive law I). ∈ ∈ 8. For all α, β F and x V, (α + β)x = αx + βx (distributive law II).

View Full Text

Details

  • File Type
    pdf
  • Upload Time
    -
  • Content Languages
    English
  • Upload User
    Anonymous/Not logged-in
  • File Pages
    105 Page
  • File Size
    -

Download

Channel Download Status
Express Download Enable

Copyright

We respect the copyrights and intellectual property rights of all users. All uploaded documents are either original works of the uploader or authorized works of the rightful owners.

  • Not to be reproduced or distributed without explicit permission.
  • Not used for commercial purposes outside of approved use cases.
  • Not used to infringe on the rights of the original creators.
  • If you believe any content infringes your copyright, please contact us immediately.

Support

For help with questions, suggestions, or problems, please contact us