Simon Kuznets and the Empirical Tradition in Economics

Simon Kuznets and the Empirical Tradition in Economics

This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: Political Arithmetic: Simon Kuznets and the Empirical Tradition in Economics Volume Author/Editor: Robert William Fogel, Enid M. Fogel, Mark Guglielmo, and Nathaniel Grotte Volume Publisher: University of Chicago Press Volume ISBN: 0-226-25661-8, 978-0-226-25661-0 (cloth) Volume URL: http://www.nber.org/books/foge12-1 Conference Date: n/a Publication Date: March 2013 Chapter Title: The Scientific Methods of Simon Kuznets Chapter Author(s): Robert William Fogel, Enid M. Fogel, Mark Guglielmo, Nathaniel Grotte Chapter URL: http://www.nber.org/chapters/c12917 Chapter pages in book: (p. 89 - 105) 5 :: The Scientifi c Methods of Simon Kuznets “Anyone can start a row in economics; it is much harder to fi nd out what is really happening to the economy.” Simon Kuznets made this statement during a conversation he had with Henry Rosovsky, who was then chairman of the Economics Department at Harvard Uni- versity and later became dean of the Faculty of Arts and Sciences, and Robert Fogel at Harvard in the early 1970s. Fogel was startled when he said it since their profession thrived on controversy. Indeed, to many economists, cleverness in debate, rather than the applicability of the debate to any issue of the real world, is what economics is all about. To Kuznets, however, there was a real economic world, and the task of the economist was to describe it accurately and to explain it in a way that would be helpful to those who had to make economic policy.1 Some Aspects of Kuznets’s Approach to Economics If there was any aspect of Kuznets’s approach to economics that may be said to have dominated all the others, it was his concern with the great policy issues of his age. Emphasis on this point may surprise those who are familiar with his work since he never became directly involved in those highly politicized disputes over economic policy that 1. For a general introduction to Kuznets’s scientifi c method, see Easterlin (1989), Abramovitz (1971, 1985), Patinkin (1976), Ben-Porath (1986), Bergson (1986), and Bergson, Leibenstein, Rosovsky, and Griliches (1987). 90 Chapter Five oft en split the profession into partisan camps. Moreover, many of the problems on which Kuznets worked, such as the relation between the rate of population growth and the rate of technological innovation, are hardly likely to be resolved or even aff ected signifi cantly by new legislation, nor did his fi ndings on such issues enter prominently into the shift ing partisan alignments of his age. Nevertheless, he recog- nized the importance of the points at issue in the political debates over economic policy, and he believed that the development of a reliable body of evidence bearing on these issues was an urgent task of econo- mists. He saw economics as an empirical science aimed at disclosing the factors that aff ect economic performance. It is important to keep in mind how new the issues with which Kuznets grappled during his career were when he fi rst began to ad- dress them in the mid- 1920s. The proposition that Western Europe and America had undergone an irreversible economic transforma- tion—an industrial revolution—was not eff ectively enunciated un- til the end of the 1880s. Although optimism about the economy was widespread during the fi rst three decades of the twentieth century, these years also spawned infl uential theories that economic progress was grinding to a halt. The notion of a general crisis for capitalism, set forth in the work of such socialist or radical theorists as J. A. Hobson of England, Rudolf Hilferding of Germany, and Vladimir Lenin, be- came widely accepted by professional economists during the 1930s.2 Alvin Hansen, in his 1938 presidential address to the American Eco- nomic Association, suggested that a correct fi scal policy could bring an end to secular stagnation. Despite a certain optimism, that speech seemed to endorse the view that secular stagnation was the natural condition of free market economies in the twentieth century and that capitalist economies could be kept afl oat only with massive govern- ment intervention (Hansen 1939; cf. Abramovitz 1952). When Kuznets fi rst began his work on economic growth in the mid- 1920s, not all the processes that he later identifi ed had worked 2. J.&A. Hobson (1858–1940) was an English political thinker and a promoter of “New Liberalism.” Rudolph Hilferding (1877–1941) was a Marxist theorist and the chief theoretician of the Social Democratic Party of Germany. Th e Scientifi c Methods of Simon Kuznets 91 themselves out. Europe and America were still passing through their demographic and epidemiological transitions (U.S. life expectancy at birth in 1920 was still under fi ft y- fi ve years), and the nature of these phenomena was not yet fully apparent. It would be another two de- cades before the theory of the demographic transition—which ex- plains that declines in the death rate lead, with a lag, to comparable declines in the birth rate—was formulated, and it would be another three to four decades before it became clear that the economic ad- vances of the last half of the nineteenth century were part of a new ep- och of economic growth that was about two centuries old and that was in the process of spreading from its origins in Western Europe and in certain countries of European settlement to the impoverished nations of Africa, Asia, and Latin America. Kuznets considered the acceleration of population growth during the nineteenth century as not only one of the most important con- sequences of economic growth but also a major factor contributing to it. A particularly important aspect of the phenomenon was the concentration of the decline of death rates at early ages, which con- tributed to the reduction in fertility rates. The reduced fertility rates released a large proportion of the female labor force to gainful occu- pations, accelerated the transition to modern families, mobile and responsive to economic incentives, and promoted new ideologies conducive to economic growth (Kuznets 1966, 56–62). In this con- nection, Kuznets noted the increase in the share of women in the U.S. labor force from 17 percent in 1890 to 27 percent in 1950, which he attributed to the lower fertility rates, the shift in employment oppor- tunities from manual to service- sector positions, and urbanization, which made organized labor markets more accessible to women. He also called attention to the fact that the most rapidly growing occupa- tions—those in the professional, technical, clerical, sales, and other services—were the ones in which women had made the greatest in- roads. Nevertheless, in the late 1950s and early 1960s, when the new women’s movement was still incipient, he anticipated neither the ex- plosive entry of women into the labor force during the next quarter century nor the new ideology that would facilitate that development (Kuznets 1966, 193–95). 92 Chapter Five Another aspect of Kuznets’s method was his approach to the es- tablishment of the priorities for empirical research in economics. At any moment, there are more issues and problems demanding the at- tention of economists than there are resources to address them. In Kuznets’s view, the priorities for research were determined by a com- plex interaction of three factors: (1) the needs of policymakers inside and outside the government, particularly, the issues that they consid- ered paramount for promoting economic growth, stability, and eq- uity; (2) the beliefs of economists and other social scientists regarding the most eff ective measures for resolving the problems on this social agenda; and (3) the availability of the data needed to address these is- sues and the eff ectiveness of the tools, both analytic and mechanical, required to process and analyze the data (Kuznets 1972, 39). In explaining both the enormous growth of economic research be- tween 1930 and 1970 and the direction that research took, Kuznets emphasized the importance of the interaction between these three factors, rather than the ascendency of any one over the other. This ex- pansion of economic research undoubtedly depended on the social agenda since it was largely through the government that the training of the scientifi c personnel, the collection of the primary data, and the fi nancing of individual research projects were directly or indirectly promoted.3 However, which direction this research took was heavily infl uenced by developments within the academic community. Thus, while the devastating impact of the Great Depression of the 1930s pro- moted greater government intervention in the economy, the direction that the intervention took, and the type of research that the govern- ment promoted, was greatly aff ected by Keynesian theory, which had gained such dominance in the scholarly community. In the absence of this infl uential theory, government policy “might have been lim- ited to new provisions for unemployment insurance, new plans for public works, and the like” (Kuznets 1972, 42). Since the theory indi- cated that depression conditions could recur unless the government was continuously concerned with ensuring a suffi ciently high level of fi nal demand, government policy moved heavily in a Keynesian direc- 3. Foundations and other private institutions also played an important role (Kuznets 1972, 42). Th e Scientifi c Methods of Simon Kuznets 93 tion. This interaction between social priorities and economic theory gave an enormous stimulus to the development of national income ac- counts, of measures of employment and unemployment, the size dis- tribution of income, and other macrovariables, as a means of moni- toring economic performance and guiding government intervention.

View Full Text

Details

  • File Type
    pdf
  • Upload Time
    -
  • Content Languages
    English
  • Upload User
    Anonymous/Not logged-in
  • File Pages
    18 Page
  • File Size
    -

Download

Channel Download Status
Express Download Enable

Copyright

We respect the copyrights and intellectual property rights of all users. All uploaded documents are either original works of the uploader or authorized works of the rightful owners.

  • Not to be reproduced or distributed without explicit permission.
  • Not used for commercial purposes outside of approved use cases.
  • Not used to infringe on the rights of the original creators.
  • If you believe any content infringes your copyright, please contact us immediately.

Support

For help with questions, suggestions, or problems, please contact us