Demand Functions 1/30/12 This Problem Set Is Due on Monday, 2/6

Demand Functions 1/30/12 This Problem Set Is Due on Monday, 2/6

DIRK BERGEMANN DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS YALE UNIVERSITY ECONOMICS 121B:INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS Problem Set 2: Demand Functions 1/30/12 This problem set is due on Monday, 2/6/12, in class. To receive full credit, provide a complete defense of your answer. 1. In class we defined the notion of a concave function, in particular a concave utility function. We said that n 0 n a function f : R ! R is concave if for all x; x 2 R , and all λ 2 (0; 1): f λx + (1 − λ) x0 ≥ λf (x) + (1 − λ) f x0 . (1) 1. See Figures1. If f is a concave function, for every x between z and y, the point (x; f(x)) on the graph of f is above the straight line joining the points (z; f(z)) and (y; f(y)) Figure 1: A concave function 2. If f 00 (x) ≤ 0, f 0 (x) is a decreasing function. Suppose f (x) is a utility function representing a decision maker’s preference, decreasing f 0 (x) corresponds to diminishing marginal utility. 3. See Figures2. If f is a quasiconcave function, for every x between z and y, the point (x; f(x)) on the graph of f is above the minimum of ff(z); f(y)g. 1 Figure 2: A quasi-concave function 4. Let’s start with the definition of concavity: f (λx + (1 − λ) y) ≥ λf (x) + (1 − λ) f (y) . Since, f(x) ≥ min ff(x); f(y)g f(y) ≥ min ff(x); f(y)g , we have f (λx + (1 − λ) y) ≥ λ min ff(x); f(y)g + (1 − λ) min ff(x); f(y)g ≥ min ff(x); f(y)g , which implies f (λx + (1 − λ) y) ≥ min ff(x); f(y)g , the definition of quasi-concavity. Figure2 also demonstrates that a quasiconcave function is not necessarily a concave function. We already show that it is a quasiconcave function. For z; y; λ as shown in the figure, we have f (λx + (1 − λ) y) < λf (x) + (1 − λ) f (y) (2) f (λx + (1 − λ) y) > min ff(x); f(y)g . (3) This counterexample shows that f(x) as depicted in figure2 is not a concave function. n 2. An equivalent description of a quasiconcave function is the following definition: f : R ! R is quasi- concave if for all y, the upper contour set U, defined as follows U (y) = fx 2 X jf (x) ≥ y g (4) is a convex set. 2 1. See Figures3. The circle on the left hand side is a convex set. The shape on the left is not since the convex combinations of two end points on the right are not in that set. Figure 3: A concave function 2. See Figure4. For any z 2 R, the upper contour set UC(z) is convex, which is the case in figure 4. Consider Figure5 where the upper contour set is not convex as a counterexample. Obviously this function is not quasi-concave. 3. Suppose the consumer’s preferences are represented by function u. For any two bundles x and x0, the following equivalence holds, x x0 , u(x) ≥ u(x0). We need to show that u is a quasiconcave function if the consumer’s preferences are convex. We first prove this statement for x; y such that x ∼ y and x 6= y. Since for all λ 2 (0; 1), λx + (1 − λ) y % x λx + (1 − λ) y % y, we have u(λx + (1 − λ) y) ≥ minfu(x); u(y)g. Next we prove the statement for bundles x; y such that x y. Without loss of generality, we assume that x % y. In this case, for all λ 2 (0; 1), we have λx + (1 − λ) y % y: Therefore, u(λx + (1 − λ) y) ≥ u(y) = minfu(x); u(y)g. To sum, we prove that convex preference implies that the utility function is quasiconcave. 3. A consumer’s preferences are represented by the following utility function: u(x; y) = lnx + 2lny: 3 Figure 4: Equivalence of the two definitions of strict quasi-concavity Figure 5: A non-convex upper contour set 4 1. Recall that for any two bundles Z and Z0 the following equivalence holds Z Z0 , u(Z) ≥ u(Z0) Calculate utility from each bundle. u(A) = u(1; 4) = ln 1 + 2 ln 4 = 0 + 2 ∗ 1:4 = 2:8 u(B) = u(4; 1) = ln 4 + 2 ln 1 = 1:4 + 2 ∗ 0 = 1:4 Thus, since u(A) > u(B) the consumer prefers bundle A to bundle B. 2. Convex preferences imply that for any three bundles X; Y; and Z, if Y X and Z X then αY + (1 − α)Z X. From the example above take Y to be bundle A, and X to be bundle B. Since preferences are reflexive B B, thus, we can take Z to be bundle B. Thus, convexity of preferences implies αA + (1 − α)B B Notice that C = 1=2A + 1=2B. Thus C B. To verify the answer, calculate utility from C u(C) = u(2:5; 2:5) = ln(2:5) + 2 ln(2:5) = 2:7 > 1:4 = u(B) 3. A bundle Z with consumptions given by (xZ ; yZ ) is indifferent to the given bundle B when it yields the same utility as bundle B. Utility that bundle Z yields u(Z) = u(xZ ; yZ ) = ln xZ + 2 ln yZ should be equal to u(B) = 1:4. Thus, an equation for the indifference through the bundle (xB; yB) = (4; 1) is ln xZ + 2 ln yZ = ln 4 2 ln xZ yZ = ln 4 2 xZ yZ = exp ln 4 2 4 yZ = xZ 2 y = Z 1=2 xZ 5 4. MU 1=x y MRS(x; y) = − x = − = − MUy 2=y 2x 2:5 1 MRS(2:5; 2:5) = − = − 2:2:5 2 MRS is the rate at which two goods should be exchanges to keep the overall utility constant. For example, at a point (2.5 ; 2.5) 1 unit of good x should be exchanged for 1/2 units of good y. 4. Graphically, the function f(x) = a − (x − b)2 look like this: f(x) 6 a b - x We want to maximize f(x) = a − (x − b)2, or more formally we want to solve: max a − (x − b)2: (5) x d ∗ Note that there is no constraint. To find the local maxima/minima we solve dx f(x ) = 0. For our problem we want to solve d f(x∗) = −2(x∗ − b) = 0 (6) dx and so the solution to our first-order condition (FOC) gives us x∗ = b. To make sure that we in fact have d2 ∗ a maximum and not a minimum we must check our second-order condition (SOC), or that dx2 f(x ) < 0. d2 In this case dx2 f(x) = −2 < 0 so our SOC is satisfied everywhere and our solution gives us a maximum. 5. Consider the same function f(x) = a − (x − b)2, and suppose now that the choice of the optimal x is constrained by x ≤ x, where x is an arbitrary number, satisfying 0 < x < b. (7) 1. Adding the constraint x ≤ x¯ to our graph looks like this: 6 f(x) x¯ 6 a b - x where everything to the left of the new vertical line at x¯ are feasible choices of x for the constrained optimization problem. 2. Our new constrained problem is: max a − (x − b)2 s:t: x ≤ x;¯ (8) x where 0 < x¯ < b. Let us define our Lagrangian as L(x; λ) = a − (x − b)2 + λ(¯x − x). The optimal conditions include one FOC and one complementary condition @ L(x∗; λ∗) = −2(x∗ − b) − λ∗ = 0 (9) @x λ∗(¯x − x∗) = 0: (10) There are two possibilities given our complementary slackness condition, λ∗(¯x − x∗) = 0. Either λ∗ > 0 and x¯ − x∗ = 0 or x¯ − x∗ > 0 and λ∗ = 0 should be the case. If λ∗ = 0 is the relevant case here, equation (9) implies that x∗ = b, but this contradicts our assumption that x∗ < x¯ since x¯ < b. Therefore, we have λ∗ = 0 and x∗ =x ¯, which gives us our optimal choice of x. Equation (9) implies that λ∗ = −2(x∗ − b), which can be combined with our first equation to give us λ∗ = 2(b − x¯) our optimal choice of λ. 3. Lagrange multiplier. The value of the Lagrangian evaluated at our solution is L(x∗; λ∗) = L(¯x; 2(b− x¯)) = a − (¯x − b)2. We can find the marginal effect of increasing our bound, x¯, by taking the partial derivative of our value function with respect to x¯. Namely, we are interested in @ L(x∗; λ∗) = −2(¯x − b) = 2(b − x¯); (11) @x¯ @ ∗ ∗ ∗ and we find that @x¯ L(x ; λ ) = λ . 4. Interpretation of Lagrangian multiplier. The price we would have to charge in order to get the decision maker to choose exactly x∗ =x ¯, even in the absence of a hard constraint, would be given by λ∗ = 2(b − x¯). 7 6. Comparative Statics. Substituting x∗ =x ¯ into function f, we get y∗ = f(x∗) = a − (¯x − b)2. To measure how y∗ varies with b, we simply take the derivative of y∗ with respect to b, dy∗(b) = −2(b − x¯): db We can get the same result using envelope theorem. We start off with y∗(b) = f(x∗(b); b); dy∗ @f dx @f @f (x; b) = + = : db @x db @b @b This is the envelope theorem which states that at the optimal solution, the impact of a marginal change in an exogenous parameter on the value of the objective function is equal to the direct marginal change that the exogenous variable has on the objective function.

View Full Text

Details

  • File Type
    pdf
  • Upload Time
    -
  • Content Languages
    English
  • Upload User
    Anonymous/Not logged-in
  • File Pages
    12 Page
  • File Size
    -

Download

Channel Download Status
Express Download Enable

Copyright

We respect the copyrights and intellectual property rights of all users. All uploaded documents are either original works of the uploader or authorized works of the rightful owners.

  • Not to be reproduced or distributed without explicit permission.
  • Not used for commercial purposes outside of approved use cases.
  • Not used to infringe on the rights of the original creators.
  • If you believe any content infringes your copyright, please contact us immediately.

Support

For help with questions, suggestions, or problems, please contact us