MACRO-ECONOMICS and REALITY by Christopher A. Sims Discussion

MACRO-ECONOMICS and REALITY by Christopher A. Sims Discussion

MACRO-ECONOMICS AND REALITY by Christopher A. Sims Discussion Paper No. 77-91, December 1977 Research for this paper was supported by NSF Grant Soc-76-02482. Lars Hansen executed the computations. The paper has benefited from comments by many people, especially Thomas J. Sargent and Finn Kydland. Center for Economic Research Department of Economics University of Minnesota Minneapolis, Minnesota 55455 MACRO-ECONOMICS AND REALITY The study of the business cycle, fluctuations in aggregate measures of economic activity and prices over periods from one to ten years or so, constitutes or motivates a large part of what we call macroeconomics. }wst economists would agree that there are nany macroeconoc.ic variables whose cyclical fluct,uations are of interest, and would agree further that fluctuations in these series are interrelated. It would seem to follow almost tautologically that statistical models involving large numbers of macroeconomic variables ought to be the arena within which Qacroeconomic theories confront reality and thereby each other. lnstead~ though large-scale statistical macroeconomic models exist and are by some criteria successful, a deep vein of skepticism about the value of these ~odels runs through that part of the economics pro­ fession not actively engaged in constructing or using them. It is still rare for empirical research in macroeconomics to be planned and executed within the framework of one of the large models. ~ this lecture I intend to discuss some aspects of this situation, attempting both to offer some explanations and to suggest aome means for improvment. I will argue that the style in which their builders construct claims for a connection between these models and reality -- the style in which "identification" is achieved for these models - is inappropriate, to the point at which claims for identification in these models cannot be taken seriously. This is a venerable assertion; and there are some -2- good old reasons for believing it;l but there are also some reasons . " which have been more recently put forth. After developing the eon- elusion that the identification claimed for existing large-scale models is incredible, I will discuss what ought to be done in con- sequence. The line of argument is: large-scale models do perform useful forecasting and policy-analysis functions despite their incredible identification; the restrictions imposed in the usual style of identi- fication are neither essential to constructing a model which can perform these functions nor innocuous; an alternative style of identification is available and practical. Finally we will look at some empirical work based on an alternative style of macroeconometrics. A six-variable dynamic system is estimated" without using restrictions based on economic theory, then is interpreted from two different theoretical perspectives. Under a sophisticated neo-monetarist interpretation, a restriction on the system which implies that monetary policy shocks could explain nearly all cyclical variation in real variables in the economy is tested and rejected. Under a more standard macroeconometric interpretation, a restriction which i~ treated as a maintained hypothesis in econometric work with Phillips Curve "wage equations" or paired wage and price equations is also rejected. I. Incredible Identification A. The genesis of "a priori restrictions". When discussing statistical theory, we say a model is identified if distinct points in the model's parameter space imply observationally ~. C. Liu (15) presented convincing arguments for the assertion in a classic article. -3- distinct patterns of behavior for the model's variables. If a parameterization lye derive from economic theory (which is usually what we mean by a "structural form" for a model) fails to be identified~ we can always transform the parameter space so that all points in the originaL parameter space which imply equivalent behavior are mapped into the same point in the new parameter space. This is called normalization. The obvious example is the case where~ not having an identified simultaneous equation model in structural form, we estimate a reduced form instead. Having achieved identification by normalization in this exacple, we admit that the individual equations of the modal are not products of distinct exercises in economic theory. Instead of using a reduced form, we could noroalize by requiring the residuals to be orthogonal across equations and the coefficient matrix of current endogenous variables to be triangular. The resulting normalization into Wold causal chain form is identified, but results in equations which are linear combinations of the reduced form equations. Nobody is disturbed by this situation of multiple possible normalizations. Similarly, when we estimate a complete system of demand equations, we recognize that the equations, in which each quantity appears only once, on the left-hand-side of one equation in the system, and all prices appear on the right of each equation, is no more than one of many possible normalizations for a system of equations describing demand behavior. In principle, we realize that it does not make sense to regard "demand for meat" and "demand for shoes" as the products of distinct categories of behavior, any more than it would make sense to regard "price of meat" and "price of shoes" equations as products of distinct categories of behavior if we normalized so as to reverse -4- the places of' prices and quantitites in the system. Nonetheless we do sometimes estimate a s~~ll part of a complete demand'system together with part of a complete supply system -- supply and demand for meat, say. In doing this, it is common and reasonable practice to make shrewd aggregations and exclusion restrictions so that our small partial­ equilibrium system omits most of the many prices we know enter the demand relation in principle and possibly includes a shrewdly selected set of exogenous variables we expect to be especially important in explaining variation in meat demand (an Easter dummy in regions where many people buy hams for Easter dinner, e.g.). While individual demand equations developed for partial equilibrium use may quite reasonably Llvolve an array of restrictions appropriate to that use, it is evident that a system of demand equations built up incrementally from such partial-equilibrium models may display very undesirable properties. In effect, the shrewd restrictions which are useful for partial equilibrium purposes, when concatenated across many categories of demand, yield a bad system of restrictions. This point is far from new, having been made, e.g., by Zvi Griliches ( 9) in his criticis~ of the consumption equations of the first version of the Brookings Model and by Brainard and Tobin ( 3) in relation to financial sector models in general. And of course this same point motivates the extensive work which has been done on econometri.cally usable functi.onal forms for complete systems of demand equations and factor demand equations. The reason for re-emphasizing the dangers of one-equation-at-a-time specification of a large model here is that the extent to which the distinctions among equations in large macro-models are normalizations, -5- rather than truly structural distinctions, has not received much emphasis. In the version of the FRB-NIT model reported in (2), for example, a substantial part of the interesting behavioral equations of the financial sector are demand equations for particular assets. Consumption, of course, is represented by demand equations» and the supply of labor and demand for housing also in principle represent components of a system of equations describing the public's allocations of their resources. Thus the strictures against one-equation-at-a­ time specification which are ordinarily applied to the financial or consumption equations of a model as a subgroup. really apply to this whole set of equations. If large blocks of equations, running across "sectors" of the model which are ordinarily treated as separate specification problems, are in fact distinguished from one another only by normalization, what "economic theory" tells us about them is mainly that any variable which appears on the right-hand-side of one of these equations belongs in principle on the right-hand-side of all of them. To the extent that models end up with very different sets of variables on the right­ hand-sides of these equations, they do so not by invoking economic theory, but (in the case of demand equations) by invoking an intuitive. econometrician's version of psychological and sociological theory. since constraining utility functions is what is involved here. Further­ more, unless these sets of equations are considered as a system in the process of specification, the behavioral implications of the restrictions on all equations taken together may be much less reasonable than the restrictions on anyone equation taken by itself. -6- The textbook paradigm for identification of a simultaneous equation system is supply and demand for an agricultural product. There we are apt to speak of the supply equation as reflecting the behavior of farmers, and the demand equation as reflecting the behavior of consumers. A similar use of language, in which labor supply equa- tions are taken to apply to "workers", consumption equations to "consumers", asset demand equations to "savers" sometimes obscures the distinction in macromodels between normalized and structurally identified equations.~/ On the other hand, the distinction between "employers" and "investors" on the one hand, and "consumers" and "workers" on the other, does have some structural justification. There certainly are policies which can drive a wedge between supply and demand prices for transactions between the "business" and "household" sectors, which is roughly the distinction we are concerned with. Furthermore, if business behavior is taken to be competitive, the business sector simply traces out the efficient envelope of available technology in response to demand shifts. Then the distinction between business and households becomes the distinction between "nature" and "tastes" on which identification in the supply-demand paradigm rests.

View Full Text

Details

  • File Type
    pdf
  • Upload Time
    -
  • Content Languages
    English
  • Upload User
    Anonymous/Not logged-in
  • File Pages
    77 Page
  • File Size
    -

Download

Channel Download Status
Express Download Enable

Copyright

We respect the copyrights and intellectual property rights of all users. All uploaded documents are either original works of the uploader or authorized works of the rightful owners.

  • Not to be reproduced or distributed without explicit permission.
  • Not used for commercial purposes outside of approved use cases.
  • Not used to infringe on the rights of the original creators.
  • If you believe any content infringes your copyright, please contact us immediately.

Support

For help with questions, suggestions, or problems, please contact us