
Microeconomics The Roundtable Series in Behavioral Economics The Roundtable Series in Behavioral Economics aims to advance re- search in the new interdisciplinary field of behavioral economics. Behav- ioral economics uses facts, models, and methods from neighboring sci- ences to establish descriptively accurate findings about human cognitive ability and social interaction and to explore the implications of these findings for economic behavior. The most fertile neighboring science in recent decades has been psychology, but sociology, anthropology, biol- ogy, and other fields can usefully influence economics as well. The Roundtable Series publishes books in economics that are deeply rooted in empirical findings or methods from one or more neighboring sciences and advance economics on its own terms—generating theoretical in- sights, making more accurate predictions of field phenomena, and sug- gesting better policy. Colin Camerer and Ernst Fehr, editors Behavioral Game Theory: Experiments in Strategic Interaction by Colin F. Camerer Microeconomics: Behavior, Institutions, and Evolution by Samuel Bowles Advances in Behavioral Economics, edited by Colin F. Camerer, George Loewenstein, and Matthew Rabin The Behavioral Economics Roundtable Henry Aaron George Loewenstein George Akerlof Sendhil Mullainathan Linda Babcock Matthew Rabin Colin Camerer Thomas Schelling Peter Diamond Eldar Shafir Jon Elster Robert Shiller Ernst Fehr Cass Sunstein Daniel Kahneman Richard Thaler David Laibson Richard Zeckhauser Microeconomics behavior, institutions, and evolution Samuel Bowles russell sage foundation newyork princeton university press princeton and oxford Copyright ᭧ 2004 by Russell Sage Foundation Requests for permission to reproduce materials from this work should be sent to Permissions, Princeton University Press Published by Princeton University Press, 41 William Street, Princeton, New Jersey 08540 In the United Kingdom: Princeton University Press, 3 Market Place, Woodstock, Oxfordshire OX20 1SY And the Russell Sage Foundation, 112 East 64th Street, New York, New York 10021 All Rights Reserved Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data Bowles, Samuel. Microeconomics : behavior, institutions, and evolution / Samuel Bowles. p. cm. — (The roundtable series in behavioral economics) Includes bibliographical references and index. ISBN 0-691-09163-3 (alk. paper) 1. Microeconomics. 2. Institutional economics. 3. Evolutionary economics. I. Title. II. Series. HB172.B67 2003 338.5—dc21 2003049841 British Library Cataloging-in-Publication Data is available This book has been composed in Sabon Printed on acid-free paper. ϱ www.pupress.princeton.edu www.russellsage.org Printed in the United States of America 10987654321 List of Credits Quotation from “Mending Wall” by Robert Frost used with permission of Henry Holt and Company. Quotation from “16 tons” by Merle Travis used with permission of Warner-Chappell Music, a division of Warner Brothers. Map of Italy in the fifteenth century (Figure 13.1) adapted from Atlas of Medieval Europe by Donald Matthew, used with permission of Andromeda, Oxford, Ltd. Chapter 13 makes substantial use of work co-authored with Jung-Kyoo Choi and Astrid Hopfensitz that appeared in the Journal of Theoretical Biology (2003) 23:2, pp. 135– 47, and is used here with permission from Elsevier. For Libby and for Herb Contents Preface ix Prologue: Economics and the Wealth of Nations and People 1 Part I: Coordination and Conflict: Generic Social Interactions 21 Chapter One Social Interactions and Institutional Design 23 Chapter Two Spontaneous Order: The Self-organization of Economic Life 56 Chapter Three Preferences and Behavior 93 Chapter Four Coordination Failures and Institutional Responses 127 Chapter Five Dividing the Gains to Cooperation: Bargaining and Rent Seeking 167 Part II: Competition and Cooperation: The Institutions of Capitalism 203 Chapter Six Utopian Capitalism: Decentralized Coordination 205 Chapter Seven Exchange: Contracts, Norms, and Power 233 Chapter Eight Employment, Unemployment, and Wages 267 Chapter Nine Credit Markets, Wealth Constraints, and Allocative Inefficiency 299 Chapter Ten The Institutions of a Capitalist Economy 331 Part III: Change: The Coevolution of Institutions and Preferences 363 Chapter Eleven Institutional and Individual Evolution 365 viii • Contents Chapter Twelve Chance, Collective Action, and Institutional Innovation 402 Chapter Thirteen The Coevolution of Institutions and Preferences 437 Part IV: Conclusion 471 Chapter Fourteen Economic Governance: Markets, States, and Communities 473 Problem Sets 502 Additional Readings 529 Works Cited 537 Index 571 CHAPTER THREE Preferences and Behavior Political writers have established it as a maxim, that in contriving any system of government . every man ought to be supposed to be a knave and to have no other end, in all his actions, than his private interest. By this interest we must govern him, and, by means of it, make him, notwithstanding his insatiable avarice and ambition, cooperate to public good. —David Hume, Essays: Moral, Political and Literary (1742) Let us return again to the state of nature and consider men as if . sprung out of the earth, and suddenly, like mushrooms, come to full maturity without any kind of engagement to each other. —Thomas Hobbes De Cive (1651) Growing corn is big business in Illinois. Using highly capital-intensive technologies and computer-generated business plans, some farmers cul- tivate a thousand or more acres, much of it on plots rented from multi- ple owners. In the mid-1990s, over half of the contracts between farmers and owners were sharecropping agreements, and over four- fifths of these contracts stipulated a fifty-fifty division of the crop be- tween the two parties. In the southern part of the state where the soil is on average less fertile, there are counties where contracts giving the tenant two-thirds of the crop are common. In these counties there are few contracts of fifty-fifty or any division other than two-thirds, despite considerable variation in land quality within these counties. Rice cultivation in West Bengal in the mid-1970s seems light years away from Illinois. Poor illiterate farmers in villages isolated by impass- able roads much of the year, and lacking electronic communication, eked out a bare living on plots that average just two acres. We have already seen (in the Prologue) that they shared one similarity with Illi- nois’s farmers, however: the division between sharecroppers and owners was fifty-fifty in over two-thirds of the contracts. (Ibn Battuta, whose visit to Bengal was also mentioned in the prologue, had noted—and deplored—exactly the same division of the crop six centuries before.) Other contracts were observed, but none of them constituted more than The first epigraph is from Hume (1964:117–18), the second from Hobbes (1949:100). 94 • Chapter 3 8 percent of the total.1 An even more striking example is from the U.S. South following the Civil War, where sharecropping contracts divided the harvest equally between the landlord and tenant irrespective of the quality of the land or whether the tenant was a freeborn white or a newly freed slave: “This form of tenancy was established everywhere in the South. It flourished with all possible combinations of soil quality and labor conditions”(Ransom and Sutch 1977:91, 215). The puzzle of fifty-fifty sharecropping is the following: an equal split of the crop means that tenants on fertile land will have higher payoffs to their effort and other inputs than those on poor land. But if tenants are willing to work for the lower returns on the less good land, why should the owners of good land concede half of the crop to their ten- ants? The conventional economic theory of sharecropping predicts that the owner will capture the returns to land quality through variations in the crop share (Stiglitz 1974). But Burke and Young (2000) show that the Illinois sharecropping contracts allow the tenants on good land to capture a third of the differential return attributable to land quality, effectively transferring millions of dollars from owners to farmers. A plausible interpretation of these facts is that farmers and owners around the world have hit on fifty-fifty as a seemingly fair division, and that attempts by owners to capture all of the returns to high quality land through the use of variable shares would be defeated by the ten- ants’ retaliation. If true, this interpretation suggests that a predisposi- tion to fairness, as well as the desire to punish those who violate local norms, may be motives as powerful as profit maximization and the pur- suit of individual gain. John Stuart Mill (1965[1848]) noted the striking global pattern of equal division in sharecropping, as well as local conformity to alterna- tive shares in which fifty-fifty is not observed. Mill’s explanation? “The custom of the country is the universal rule” (149). Custom may well be the proximate cause, but this explanation begs the question: why fifty- fifty as opposed to fifty-two–forty-eight? Why did the Bengalis and the Americans come up with the same number? We know from the analysis of the division game in chapter 1 that any exhaustive division of the crop is a Pareto-efficient Nash equilibrium: why this particular one? Even more puzzling: why does it persist when there appear to be huge profits to be made by offering lower shares on higher quality land? And when the shares do change, as we have seen happened in West Bengal in the 1980s and 1990s, why do they all change at once, reflecting
Details
-
File Typepdf
-
Upload Time-
-
Content LanguagesEnglish
-
Upload UserAnonymous/Not logged-in
-
File Pages43 Page
-
File Size-