Majorization and Extreme Points: Economic Applications

Majorization and Extreme Points: Economic Applications

Majorization and Extreme Points: Economic Applications Andreas Kleiner, Benny Moldovanu, and Philipp Strack April 2020 Majorization and Extreme Points: Economic Applications April 2020 1 Recent Project on Majorization and its Applications to Economics “Auctions with Endogenous Valuations”, joint with Alex Gershkov, Philipp Strack and Mengxi Zhang (2019). “Revenue Maximization in Auctions with Dual Risk Averse Bidders: Myerson Meets Yaari”, joint with Alex Gershkov, Philipp Strack and Mengxi Zhang (2020) “Majorization and Extreme Points: Economic Applications”, joint with Andreas Kleiner and Philipp Strack (2020) Majorization and Extreme Points: Economic Applications April 2020 2 Main Results of the Present Paper 1 Extreme-points characterization for sets of non-decreasing functions that are either majorized by - or majorize a given non-decreasing function. 2 Applications: a Feasibility and optimality for multi-unit auction mechanisms. b BIC-DIC equivalence. c Welfare/revenue comparisons for matching schemes in contests. d Equivalence between optimal delegation and Bayesian persuasion + new insights into their solutions. e Rank-dependent utility, risk aversion and portfolio choice. Majorization and Extreme Points: Economic Applications April 2020 3 Majorization Preliminaries We consider only non-decreasing functions f , g :[0, 1] R such that f , g L1(0, 1). ! 2 We say that f majorizes g, denoted by g f if : 1 1 g(s)ds f (s)ds for all x [0, 1] x ≤ x 2 Z 1 Z 1 g(s)ds = f (s)ds. Z0 Z0 Let XF and XG be random variables with distributions F and G, defined on [0, 1]. Then 1 1 G F XG cv XF XF cx XG F G , ≤ , ≤ , XG ssd XF and E[XG] = E[XF] , ≤ Majorization and Extreme Points: Economic Applications April 2020 4 Convex Sets and their Extreme Points An extreme point of a convex set A is an element x A that cannot be represented as a convex combination of2 two other elements in A. The Krein–Milman Theorem (1940): any convex and compact set A in a locally convex space is the closed, convex hull of its extreme points. In particular, such a set has extreme points. Bauer’s Maximum Principle (1958): a convex, upper-semicontinuous functional on a non-empty, compact and convex set A of a locally convex space attains its maximum at an extreme point of A. An element x of a convex set A is exposed if there exists a linear functional that attains its maximum on A uniquely at x. Majorization and Extreme Points: Economic Applications April 2020 5 Orbits and Choquet’s (1960) Integral Representation Let m(f ) denote the (monotonic) orbit of f : m(f ) = g g f f j g Let m(f ) to be the (monotonic) anti-orbit of f : m(f ) = g f (0+) g f (1 ) and g f f j ≤ ≤ g Theorem 1 The sets m(f ) and m(f ) are convex and compact in the L norm topology. For any g m(f ) there exists a probability measure g 2 supported on the set of extreme points of m(f ), ext m(f ), such that g = h dg(h) Zext m(f ) and analogously for g m(f ). 2 Majorization and Extreme Points: Economic Applications April 2020 6 Orbits and their Extreme Points Theorem A non-decreasing function g is an extreme point of m(f ) if and only if there exists a countable collection of disjoint intervals [xi, xi) i I such that a.e. f g 2 f (x) if x / i I[xi, xi) x 2 [ 2 g(x) = i f (s)ds 8 xi if x [x , x ). xi x i i < R i 2 : Corollary Every extreme point is exposed. Majorization and Extreme Points: Economic Applications April 2020 7 Orbits and their Extreme Points: Illustration Figure: 1. Majorized Extreme Point Majorization and Extreme Points: Economic Applications April 2020 8 Anti-Orbits and their Extreme Points Theorem A non-decreasing function g is an extreme point of m(f ) if and only if there exists a collection of intervals [xi, xi) i I and (potentially empty) f g 2 sub-intervals [y , y ) [x , xi) such that a.e i i i f (x) if x / i I[xi, xi) 2 2 f (x ) if x [x , y ) 8 i Si i g(x) = > 2 >vi if x [y , yi) <> 2 i f (xi) if x [yi, xi) > 2 > where vi satisfies: :> xi (y y )v = f (s) ds f (x )(y x ) f (x )(x y ) i i i i i i i i i x Z i Majorization and Extreme Points: Economic Applications April 2020 9 Anti-Orbits and their Extreme Points: Illustration Figure: 2. Majorizing Extreme Point Majorization and Extreme Points: Economic Applications April 2020 10 Application: The SIPV Ranked-Item Allocation Model SIPV model with N agents. Types distributed on [0, 1] according to F, with bounded density f > 0. W.l.o.g. N objects with qualities 0 q1 ... qN = 1. Each agent wants at most one object. ≤ ≤ ≤ If agent i with type i receives object with quality qm and pays t for it, then his utility is given by iqm t. Let be the set of doubly sub-stochastic N N-matrices. N An allocation rule is given by :[0, 1] , where ij(i, i) is the probability with which agent i obtains! the object with quality j. Majorization and Extreme Points: Economic Applications April 2020 11 The SIPV Ranked-Item Allocation Model II N Let :[0, 1] denote the assortative allocation of objects to agents (highest! type gets highest quality, etc.) with ties broken by fair randomization. Let 'i(i) = [ i(i, i) q] f i( i) d i. N 1 · Z[0,1] denote agent i’s interim allocation (conditional on type) and let 1 i(si) = 'i(F (si)) be the interim quantile allocation. Majorization and Extreme Points: Economic Applications April 2020 12 Feasibility and BIC-DIC Equivalence Theorem 1 A symmetric and monotonic interim allocation rule ' is feasible if and only if its associated quantile interim allocation 1 (s) = '(F (s)) satisfies w where is the quantile interim allocation generated by the assortative allocation . 2 For any symmetric, BIC mechanism there exists an equivalent, symmetric DIC mechanism that yields all agents the same interim utility, and that creates the same social surplus. Majorization and Extreme Points: Economic Applications April 2020 13 The Fan-Lorentz (1954) Integral Inequality A functional V : L1(0, 1) R that is monotonic with respect to the majorization order is called! Schur-concave. Theorem Let K :[0, 1] [0, 1] R . Then ! 1 V(f ) = K(f (t), t) dt Z0 is Schur-concave if and only if K(u, t) is convex in u and super-modular in (u, t). Under twice-differentiability, the FL conditions become: @2K @2K 0 ; 0 @u2 ≥ @u@t ≥ Majorization and Extreme Points: Economic Applications April 2020 14 Application: Rank-Dependent Utility and Risk Aversion Utility with rank-dependent assessments of probabilities: 1 U(F) = v(s)d(g F)(s) Z0 where F is a distribution on [0, 1], v :[0, 1] R is continuous, strictly increasing and bounded, and g :[0,!1] [0, 1] is strictly increasing, continuous and onto. ! v transforms monetary payoffs; g transforms probabilities. g(x) = x yields von Neumann-Morgenstern expected utility, while v(x) = x yields Yaari’s (1987) dual utility. Theorem (Machina, 1982, Hong, Karni, Safra, 1987) The agent with preferences represented by U is risk averse if and only if both v and g are concave. Majorization and Extreme Points: Economic Applications April 2020 15 Linear Objectives and Schur-Concavity Theorem (Riesz, 1907) For every continuous, linear functional V on L1(0, 1), there exists a unique, essentially bounded function c L1(0, 1) such that for every f L1(0, 1) 2 2 1 V(f ) = c(x)f (x) dx Z0 Corollary By the Fan-Lorentz Theorem, the kernel K(f , x) = c(x)f (x) yields a Schur-concave (convex) functional V K is super-modular (sub-modular) in (f , x) c is non-decreasing, (non-increasing). , Majorization and Extreme Points: Economic Applications April 2020 16 Maximizing a Linear Functional on Orbits Consider the problem max c(x)h(x) dx. h m(f ) 2 Z 1 If c is non-decreasing, then f itself is the solution for the optimization problem. 2 If c is non-increasing, then the solution for the optimization 1 problem is the overall constant function g = 0 f (x) dx. This follows since g m(f ) and h g for any h m(f ). 2 2 R 3 If c is not monotonic, other extreme points of m(f ) may be optimal. They are obtained by an ironing procedure. Majorization and Extreme Points: Economic Applications April 2020 17 Application: Revenue Maximization The revenue maximization problem becomes 1 1 1 s1 max N F (s1) 1 (s1) ds1 m,w( ) f (F (s1)) 2 Z0 where is the interim quantile function induced by assortative matching. Result: the optimal solution is an extreme point of m( 1 ) · [s1,1] for some s1 [0, 1]. 2 Assuming that the virtual value is non-decreasing, we obtainb by the FL Theoremb that the optimal allocation satisfies: (s1) for s1 bs1 (s1) = ≥ . (0 otherwise b b Majorization and Extreme Points: Economic Applications April 2020 18 Application: Matching Contests Let F be the distribution of types, and G be the distribution of prizes, both defined on [0, 1]. If type obtains prize y and pays t, her utility is given by y t. 1 The assortative matching () = G (F()) is implemented by: t() = () (t)dt Z0 High match value and high waste.

View Full Text

Details

  • File Type
    pdf
  • Upload Time
    -
  • Content Languages
    English
  • Upload User
    Anonymous/Not logged-in
  • File Pages
    29 Page
  • File Size
    -

Download

Channel Download Status
Express Download Enable

Copyright

We respect the copyrights and intellectual property rights of all users. All uploaded documents are either original works of the uploader or authorized works of the rightful owners.

  • Not to be reproduced or distributed without explicit permission.
  • Not used for commercial purposes outside of approved use cases.
  • Not used to infringe on the rights of the original creators.
  • If you believe any content infringes your copyright, please contact us immediately.

Support

For help with questions, suggestions, or problems, please contact us