Asymptotically Well-behaved Demand Functions for Normal Goods by Mitsunobu MIYAKE Graduate School of Economics and Management Tohoku University, Sendai 980-8576, Japan ( E-mail: [email protected] ) June, 2004 Abstract: Marshallian demand functions are well-behaved (downward sloping and consistent to the consumer surplus) only if they are defined for neutral goods, i.e., the case of quasi-linear utility functions. This paper considers a possibility that Marshallian demand functions for normal goods become well-behaved when the initial income is sufficiently large. As a main result, this paper provides necessary and sufficient conditions for a standard utility function under which the derived Marshallian demand function becomes well-behaved for sufficiently large income levels. Moreover, a formula is provided to compute the well-behaved demand function directly from the utility function. Key words: Marshallian demand function, Consumer Surplus, Normal Good, Income effect. JEL classification: D11, D63 1 1. Introduction The well-behaved (downward sloping and consistent to the consumer surplus) Marshallian demand function forms a basis of the partial equilibrium analysis both in positive and normative perspectives, since the downward slopness and some other regularity conditions imply that there exists a competitive equilibrium uniquely in the partial equilibrium market and the consistency to the consumer surplus enable us to evaluate alternative policies in the market by means of the consumer surplus measure. It is well-known that Marshallian demand functions are well-behaved only if they are defined for neutral goods, i.e., the case of quasi-linear utility functions. This paper considers a possibility that Marshallian demand functions for normal goods become well- behaved when the initial income is sufficiently large. As a main result, this paper provides necessary and sufficient conditions for a standard utility function under which the derived Marshallian demand function becomes well-behaved for sufficiently large income levels. Moreover, a formula is provided to compute the well-behaved demand function directly from the utility function. In the next section, some basic concepts such as utility function, Marshallian demand function, equivalent variation and compensating variation are introduced in a simple two- good setting where one good is a specific good and the other good is money (numeraire), and the well-behavedness of Marshallian demand function is specified by two conditions: (i) Downward slopness ; (ii) Consistency to the consumer surplus, and a well-known fact for the well-behavedness is stated as Proposition 1 that the well-behaved Marshallian demand function derived only from a quasi-linear utility function, i.e., the specific good is a neutral good. In section 3, a weaker concept of well-behavedness of Marshallian demand function is proposed. Specifically, if a Marshallian demand function has a limit function when initial income is sufficiently large and if the limit function is well-behaved, then we call the Marshallian demand function “asymptotically well-behaved demand function”. If a 2 demand function is asymptotically well-behaved, then income effects are very small when the initial income is sufficiently large, which can be recognized as a formalization and proof of Marshall's assertion that income effects are very small when its budget share is sufficiently small.1 As a main result of this paper, necessary and sufficient conditions are provided for a standard utility function under which the derived Marshallian demand function is asymptotically well-behaved. The necessary and sufficient conditions are the replaceability and the regularity at the limit. The replaceability condition for utility function is that an amount of the specific good is replaceable by some fixed amount of numeraire, independent from the initial consumption level of numeraire. This condition implies that the marginal rate of substitution between the two goods are bounded when the consumption level of numeraire is sufficiently large. The regularity condition is that the limit marginal rate of substitution has smoothness properties, which is a technical condition. Under the two conditions, our main result implies that we can justify the well- behaved Marshallian demand function even for strictly normal goods if initial income is sufficiently large. Moreover, our main result also implies that we can not drop these conditions for the well-behavedness. In section 4, a formula is provided to compute the limit demand function directly from the utility function. Moreover, a numerical example is presented. 1 For Marshall's original arguments on the smallness of income effects, see Chipman (1990). Vives (1987 and 1999, Chapter 3) has shown the smallness of income effects if the number of commodities are sufficiently large, but his setting is essentially different from ours. 3 2. Globally well-behaved demand functions There are two types of consumption goods, x-good and y-good: x is a specific good and y 2 is numerare. Letting X = Y = Â +, the consumption set is given by X´ Y = Â+ . Let us consider a consumer whose initial endowment of y-good is I > 0 and the preferences are represented by a smooth (twice continuously differentiable) utility function U(x, y). We assume the following standard conditions: 1 Monotonicity: Ux(x, y) > 0 and Uy(x, y) > 0 for all (x, y) ³ (0, 0). 2 2 Strict quasi-concavity: 2·Ux(x,y)·Uy(x,y)·Uxy(x,y) – [Ux(x,y)] ·Uyy(x,y) – [Uy(x,y)] ·Uxx(x,y) > 0 for all (x, y) á (0, 0). Normalize the price of numerare as 1, and denote the price of x-good by p > 0. For each p, I > 0, Marshallian demand function D(p, I) is defined by D(p, I) = argmax U(x, I – px), where B(p, I) = { (x, y) Î X´ Y: p·x + y £ I }. x Î B(p, I) For price p > 0 and utility level u Î U(X´ Y), 2 the expenditure function e(p, u) is defined by e(p, u) = min pz + w, where F(u) = { (z, w) Î X´ Y: U(z, w) ³ u }. (z, w) Î F(u) For a pair of prices p0, p1 with p0 > p1 and initial income I > 0, the equivalent variation EV(p0, p1, I) and compensating variation CV(p0, p1, I) are defined by EV(p0, p1, I) = e(p0 , u1) – I and CV(p0, p1, I) = I – e(p1 , u0), where ui = U(D(pi, I), I – piD(pi, I)) for i = 0, 1. The pair of prices (p0, p1) is called regular if not only (D(p0, I), I – p0D(p0, I)) and (D(p1, I), I – p1D(p1, I)), but also the minimizers for e(p0 , u1) and e(p1 , u0) are strictly positive vectors. 1 The partial derivatives Ux(0, y) and Uy(x, 0) at the boundary should be regarded as the right + + partial derivatives Ux(0, y) and Uy(x, 0), respectively. 2 U(X´ Y) is the range of U, i.e., U(X´ Y) = { u Î Â : u = U(x, y) for some (x, y) Î X´ Y }. 4 A standard definition of well-behaved Marshallian demand function is given as follows: Definition: A Marshallian demand function D(p, I) is called well-behaved at I > 0 if D(p, I) has the following properties: (Downward slopeness): D(p, I) > D(p+d, I) for all p with D(p, I) > 0 and all d > 0. +¥ 3 (Consistency to the consumer surplus): òp D(p, I)dp < +¥ for all p > 0, and 0 1 p0 0 1 0 1 0 1 EV(p , p , I) = òp1 D(p, I)dp = CV(p , p , I) for all regular (p , p ) with p > p . A Marshallian demand function D(p, I) is called globally well-behaved if D(p, I) is well- behaved at all I > 0. The downward slopeness means that D(p, I) is a decreasing function, which is an important condition when one proves the existence and uniqueness of a competitive equilibrium in a partial equilibrium market model. The consistency to the consumer surplus implies that the consumer surplus is well-defined and it coincides with the finite integral of demand function. The following proposition is well-known: Proposition 1: Suppose that a utility function U(x, y) is monotone and strictly quasi- concave. Then the Marshallian demand function D(p, I) is globally well-behaved if and only if x-good is a neutral good, i.e., U(x, y) satisfies that ¶MRS(x, y)/¶y = Uy(x,y)·Uxy(x,y) – Ux(x,y)·Uyy(x,y) = 0 for all (x, y) á (0, 0), where MRS(x, y) is the marginal rate of substitution of x-good for y-good at (x, y) defined by MRS(x, y) = Ux(x,y)/Uy(x,y) . 3 +¥ q òp D(p, I)dp = lim q ® +¥ ò p D(p, I)dp. 5 3. Asymptotically well-behaved demand functions for normal goods In the previous section, we observe that the well-behaved demand functions are derived only from a class of quasi-linear utility functions and then the well-behaved demand functions can be applicable only for neutral goods, which is too restrictive. In this section, we will show that the (almost) well-behaved demand functions can be derived even under the condition that x-good is a normal good. At first, we additionally assume the following condition: Normal good: ¶MRS(x, y)/¶y = Uy(x,y)·Uxy(x,y) – Ux(x,y)·Uyy(x,y) > 0 for all (x, y) á (0, 0). This condition is equivalent to ¶D(p, I)/¶I > 0 (whenever D(p, I) > 0). Then the asymptotically well-behaved demand function is defined as follows: Definition: A Marshallian demand function D(p, I) is called asymptotically well-behaved if there exists a real valued function d(p) on P º Â++ such that: (Uniform convergence): D(p, I) converges to d(p) uniformly on compacta in P as I ® +¥ .
Details
-
File Typepdf
-
Upload Time-
-
Content LanguagesEnglish
-
Upload UserAnonymous/Not logged-in
-
File Pages20 Page
-
File Size-