Strategic Opposition and Government Cohesion in Westminster

Strategic Opposition and Government Cohesion in Westminster

American Political Science Review Vol. 105, No. 2 May 2011 doi:10.1017/S0003055411000050 Strategic Opposition and Government Cohesion in Westminster Democracies TORUN DEWAN London School of Economics and Political Science ARTHUR SPIRLING Harvard University ohesive government-versus-opposition voting is a robust empirical regularity in Westminster democracies. Using new data from the modern Scottish Parliament, we show that this pattern C cannot be explained by similarity of preferences within or between the government and opposition ranks. We look at differences in the way that parties operate in Westminster and Holyrood, and use roll call records to show that the observed behavior is unlikely to be determined by preferences on any underlying issue dimension. Using a simple variant of the agenda-setting model—in which members of parliament can commit to their voting strategies—we show that the procedural rules for reaching collective decisions in Westminster systems can explain this phenomenon: in the equilibrium, on some bills, members of the opposition vote against the government irrespective of the proposal. Such strategic opposition can reinforce government cohesiveness and have a moderating effect on policy outcomes. We introduce new data from the House of Lords, the Welsh Assembly, and the Northern Ireland Assembly to distinguish our claims from competing accounts of the data. pproximately 40% of those inhabiting that provide incentives to backbenchers to act cohe- democracies live in systems that have sively. Yet, this offers an incomplete explanation for AWestminster-style features, inter alia a fusion the general pattern of cohesive government-versus- of executive-legislative relations, strong norms opposition voting. The key elements of cohesion, on of majoritarian government, and few checks and one hand, and “government-versus-opposition” vot- balances on executive agenda-setting power (Lijphart ing, on the other, are not synonymous. In principle, 1999, 10–11).1 A central behavioral regularity observed opposition party leaders could enforce any voting strat- in such systems is a pattern of “government-versus- egy (including, for example, supporting rather than op- opposition” roll call voting, whereby government posing the government on every bill). Thus, although proposals are supported by a cohesive governing whipping may well militate party cohesion, the specific majority and opposed by a cohesive opposition pattern of unified roll call voting requires a separate minority. Indeed, it is only during periods of minority explanation. government or national emergency,2 when bills are The historical case for the claim is similarly lack- supported by heterogenous coalitions of legislators, ing: Cox (1992), for example, can find no evidence of that this pattern is broken. any official whipping before 1832; yet, contemporary What can account for this behavioral regularity in observers of parliament wrote of “government” and the pattern of legislative voting? An obvious answer is “opposition” forces and their behaviors well before this “whipping”: inducements and punishments are meted date (see Namier and Brooke 1964, 190–91). Indeed, out, ensuring attendance and enforcement of the party even the claim that whipping uniquely begets roll call line. As shown by Kam (2009), party leaders have at homogeneity is suspect in the Westminster context. In their disposal a range of formal and informal measures an authoritative study of the origins of party cohe- sion, Cox (1987, 25) writes that “cohesion increased markedly within the category of whipped votes, start- Torun Dewan is Professor of Political Science, Department of Government, London School of Economics and Political Science, ing in the late 1860s and 1870s. Thus, although it is Houghton Street, London, UK WC2A 2AE ([email protected]). true that the percentage of votes whipped increased Arthur Spirling is Assistant Professor, Department of Govern- in the 1870s, this does not in itself explain the trends ment, Harvard University, 1737 Cambridge Street, Cambridge, MA in cohesion.” In fact, the relative timing of the origins 02138 ([email protected]). these behaviors suggests that, if anything, the causal We gratefully acknowledge research advice and assistance from Amir Karger. We thank Jim Alt, Scott Ashworth, Amy Catalinac, process runs in the opposite direction, with whipping Andy Eggers, Indridi Indridason, Nolan McCartty, Bonnie Meguid, perhaps introduced as an implicit structural innovation Slava Mikhaylov, Paul Mitchell, and Howard Rosenthal; participants for opposition parties in the face of a government ma- at the annual meetings of both the APSA and the MPSA in 2010 and jority with agenda power. Indeed, Cox (1982) provides at the Political Institutions and Economic Policy workshop held at Harvard University; and, finally, three anonymous referees for their evidence that between 1832 and 1871, cohesion among comments on an earlier draft. We thank Micael Castanheira, Gary the opposition was on average higher for the opposition Cox, Jon Eguia, Simon Hix, Rafael Hortala-Vallve, Ken Shepsle, and Tories than the governing Whigs. David Myatt for helpful discussions A more subtle explanation for government-versus- 1 Our claim depends on the inclusion of India, a country whose opposition voting is that cohesion within government institutional heritage stems from Westminster, but that deviates from the classic model. and opposition ranks, and polarization between these 2 Ramsay MacDonald’s National Government in Britain is an exam- groups, are the result of a simple sorting process. That ple of this phenomenon. is, members of parliament (MPs) join parties that 337 Opposition and Cohesion in Westminster Democracies May 2011 advocate the policies they prefer and thus naturally outcomes and payoffs: “sincere voting” occurs when find themselves agreeing and opposing the same sets of each MP votes for a proposal as long as it does not policies when considered on the floor of the legislature. leave her worse off than she would be if the status Moreover, this pattern may be reinforced over time: quo remains in place, whereas “opposition voting” oc- parties develop reputations for standing on particular curs when each member of the opposition always votes policy issues; like-minded MPs are selected and stand against the government irrespective of the proposal. under the party label; and socialization between MPs We show that on some bills, “opposition voting” yields on the backbenches, and in the lobbies and clubs even- higher opposition payoffs than sincere voting. On such tually compounds the behavior. Put otherwise, “birds bills, the opposition binds itself to opposing any govern- of a feather flock together”: members of the govern- ment proposal. The equilibrium involves a convex com- ing and opposition parties vote cohesively primarily bination of “opposition” and “sincere” voting and fits because they share similar preferences.3 the stylized facts of government-opposition systems: We present evidence that strongly suggests that vot- (1) government and opposition tend to vote cohesively, ing patterns in Westminster-style democracies cannot (2) the opposition votes against the proposals put for- be explained by preference alignment alone. Using new ward by the government, and (3) the opposition votes data from the Scottish Parliaments between 1999 and against government proposals that leave them better 2003 and 2003 and 2007, we show that a pattern of off than they would be if the status quo remained in cohesive government-versus-opposition voting is ap- place. parent from the outset. This is hard to reconcile with Our analysis provides a simple strategic rationale for what one would expect given stated preferences on the government-versus-opposition voting. By committing underlying issues. To give an example, between 1992 to oppose the government, the opposition forces it into and 1997, the Scottish National Party (SNP) voted dif- proposals that appeal to a majority formed by its own ferently than the Labour Party on just 4% of bills in (i.e., government) backbenchers. This can benefit the the House of Commons. This congruence is exactly opposition. A necessary condition is that parliament as one might expect from two center-left parties in is not completely polarized. Specifically, we require opposition. In contrast, just two years later in the first that on some bills, there is a degree of “overlap” in Scottish Parliament, the Nationalists, now the main op- the preferences of government and opposition MPs: position party, were in disagreement with the Labour on some policies, the members of the opposition party Party 69% of the time. Moreover, our analysis of the have preferences closer to those of the agenda setter data shows that a single dimension can correctly predict than some members of government. This is a very weak 95% of the roll calls for Scotland. This dimension fits condition, almost certainly satisfied in all Westminster a government-opposition divide with the Labour Party systems, and we provide empirical evidence to demon- and the Liberal Democrats at one end, the SNP and strate that it holds in practice. An implication of this Scottish Socialists at the other, and the Conservatives finding is that the conditions that give rise to sincere and in between. We show that this pattern cannot be ex- strategic voting are not the same: sincere voting should plained by an underlying issue dimension. be (relatively) higher when government and opposi- We provide microfoundations

View Full Text

Details

  • File Type
    pdf
  • Upload Time
    -
  • Content Languages
    English
  • Upload User
    Anonymous/Not logged-in
  • File Pages
    22 Page
  • File Size
    -

Download

Channel Download Status
Express Download Enable

Copyright

We respect the copyrights and intellectual property rights of all users. All uploaded documents are either original works of the uploader or authorized works of the rightful owners.

  • Not to be reproduced or distributed without explicit permission.
  • Not used for commercial purposes outside of approved use cases.
  • Not used to infringe on the rights of the original creators.
  • If you believe any content infringes your copyright, please contact us immediately.

Support

For help with questions, suggestions, or problems, please contact us