The Origins and Evolution of the Market for Mortgage-Backed Securities 1 2 John J. McConnell and Stephen A. Buser 1Krannert Graduate School of Management, Purdue University, West Lafayette, Indiana 47907; email: [email protected] 2Department of Finance, Fisher College of Business, The Ohio State University, Columbus, Ohio 43210 Annu. Rev. Financ. Econ. 2011. 3:173–92 Keywords First published online as a Review in Advance on collateralized mortgage obligations, subprime, mortgage agency August 19, 2011 The Annual Review of Financial Economics is Abstract online at financial.annualreviews.org The first mortgage-backed security (MBS) was issued in 1968. This article’s doi: Thereafter, the MBS market grew rapidly with outstanding issu- 10.1146/annurev-financial-102710-144901 Annu. Rev. Financ. Econ. 2011.3:173-192. Downloaded from www.annualreviews.org ances exceeding $9 trillion by 2010. The growth in the MBS market Copyright © 2011 by Annual Reviews. Access provided by ALI: Academic Libraries of Indiana on 02/10/16. For personal use only. was accompanied by numerous innovations such as collateralized All rights reserved mortgage obligations (CMOs) and the emergence of private label JEL: G21, G24, E24 alternatives to MBS issued by government-sponsored entities. We 1941-1367/11/1205-0173$20.00 trace the evolution of the MBS market and we review debates surrounding such questions as whether the MBS market has re- duced the cost of housing finance, whether the MBS market is a market for lemons, and what role, if any, MBS played in the run-up and subsequent decline of home prices during the decade of the 2000s. We also detail the evolution of models for MBS valuation as developed by academics and practitioners. 173 1. INTRODUCTION In the preface to the first Annual Review of Financial Economics Andrew Lo and Robert Merton observe that one of the most exciting aspects of financial economics as it has evolved over the past 50 years is the constant interplay between theory and practice (Lo & Merton 2009). The evolution of the market for mortgage-backed securities (MBS) is a prime example of this interplay. From the issuance of the first pass-through MBS in 1968 to the present, financial economists have worked hand in hand with institutional market makers to design new security structures, to develop pricing models to value those structures, and to experiment with econometric methods for analyzing large-scale data- bases. Indeed, it might even be argued that, for better or worse, the evolution of the market for MBS might not have been possible in the absence of the interplay between the theory and practice of financial economics. We insert the caveat “for better or worse” because more than one observer has attributed the difficulties experienced by the U.S. banking sector during 2006–2009 to the complexities inherent in MBS. These observers have further argued that it was precisely the failure of supposedly sophisticated financial models that led to these difficulties. We trace, in broad strokes, the evolution of the MBS market from 1968 through 2010. The evolution has been marked by numerous innovations. Further, innovations in the MBS market have had spillover effects that have translated into innovations elsewhere. For example, the first ever financial futures contract, initiated in 1974, had as its underlying asset the Government National Mortgage Association (GNMA) MBS. As of 2011, trading in financial futures comprised more than 90% of the total volume of all futures contracts traded in the United States. Similarly, other types of asset-backed securities (ABS) including securities backed by credit card debts, automobile loans, student loans, and equipment leases have followed the blueprint laid by MBS. Innovations have also occurred within the MBS market. These have taken one of two forms. The first is in the structure of MBS. The second is in the type of underlying collateral. As regards structure, collateralized mortgage obligations (CMOs), the first of which was issued in 1983, allocate the cash flows from the MBS into tranches that allow investors to choose among a wide array of payoff patterns. As regards collateral, the MBS market can be divided into two sectors: agency and nonagency (or private label) MBS. The agency market includes MBS sponsored by GNMA, the Federal National Mortgage Association (FNMA), and the Federal Home Loan Mortgage Corporation (FHLMC). The agencies are collectively known as Annu. Rev. Financ. Econ. 2011.3:173-192. Downloaded from www.annualreviews.org government-sponsored mortgage enterprises (GSEs). Only loans that meet certain Access provided by ALI: Academic Libraries of Indiana on 02/10/16. For personal use only. criteria are acceptable for securitization under the auspices of the GSEs. Such loans are referred to as conforming. All others are known as nonconforming loans. Among the nonconforming loans are so-called subprime and Alt-A loans (collectively nonprime loans). It is MBS supported by this latter set of loans that has been the subject of much recent research. A presumption supporting the intervention of the federal government into the MBS market is that securitization reduces the cost and increases the availability of mortgage credit. Whether that presumption is justified is the subject of a set of literature that attempts to empirically evaluate this question. On this point, as on many others, the literature is not settled. If anything, with the extreme difficulties confronted by the GSEs 174 McConnell Buser and the MBS market during 2006–2009, the presumption that securitization has had a beneficial impact on housing markets is even more fiercely debated. Difficulties experienced by the MBS market are the subject of continuing debates. One argument is that certain lenders with an operating strategy of originating and securitizing loans allowed their credit standards to slip, and the decline in standards was aided by credit rating agencies (CRAs) that inflated CMO ratings. Some critics have asserted that investors were duped into buying MBS supported by weak loans. The evidence on these points is far from conclusive. Indeed, the evidence appears to be that investors recognized the potential for increased risk embedded in certain securitized loans and, ex ante, demanded a higher yield for that risk. Ex post, given the rate of defaults and losses actually experienced, the yield was not high enough, but that does not mean that investors were duped. Mathematical models for the valuation of MBS offerings have also come under attack. In particular, some critics have argued that model inadequacies allowed banks and other investors to take on risk that they could not manage. We, thus, give attention to the evolution of such models for valuing MBS. In general terms, two types of models have been developed. The first of these is the structural models founded on the no-arbitrage principles of Modigliani & Miller (1958) as applied to option pricing by Black & Scholes (1973) and Merton (1973) coupled with models of the term structure of interest rates developed by Vasicek (1977), Cox et al. (1985), and Heath et al. (1992). Structural models assume that mortgagors optimize their borrowing decisions (i.e., the decision to make a monthly payment, to pay off their loan, or to default) at each point in time throughout the life of their loan subject to certain market frictions. The result of these optimizing decisions is a stream of cash flows (i.e., interest and principal payments) to MBS investors. A second type of model is commonly referred to as reduced form. These models also have as their starting point a no-arbitrage condition, and they are also based on one of the popular models of the term structure of interest rates. However, reduced form models diverge from structural models in that econometric estimates for payoff patterns based on historical data are used to specify the cash flows to MBS investors. Many avenues of inquiry remain for future research. Mathematical models may have lost some of their luster by virtue of their alleged failures during the recession of 2006– 2009. Nevertheless, investors require models of some sort to evaluate risks and possible returns. Development of better models is undoubtedly an area ripe for research. The Annu. Rev. Financ. Econ. 2011.3:173-192. Downloaded from www.annualreviews.org sorting out of factors that led to the crash of the MBS market during 2006–2009 is also Access provided by ALI: Academic Libraries of Indiana on 02/10/16. For personal use only. likely to require further investigation with an emphasis on policy implications. Perhaps the greatest policy question is what to do with the behemoth GSEs that have been taken into government conservatorship. The question is: What role, if any, should the federal govern- ment play in the market for securitized mortgage loans? Further research is, indeed, warranted. We proceed as follows. Section 2 describes the origins of mortgage banking and the mortgage securitization process. Section 3 reviews literature regarding whether the MBS market has reduced the cost and increased the availability of housing finance. Section 4 reviews literature devoted to the difficulties experienced by the MBS market during 2006–2009. Section 5 reviews MBS valuation models developed by academics and practi- tioners. Section 6 concludes. www.annualreviews.org The Market for Mortgage-Backed Securities 175 2. MORTGAGE BANKING, FEDERAL AGENCIES, AND MORTGAGE SECURITIZATION 2.1. Origins of Mortgage Banking A mortgage loan is a financial claim in which the mortgagor borrows money and uses real property as collateral against default. A mortgage banker is a lender who makes the loan. According to Frederiksen (1894), since at least the 1850s, mortgage bankers in the United States, typically located in the Midwest, have originated mortgage loans and sold the rights to receive principal and interest payments on the loans to distant investors.
Details
-
File Typepdf
-
Upload Time-
-
Content LanguagesEnglish
-
Upload UserAnonymous/Not logged-in
-
File Pages22 Page
-
File Size-