Structural Breaks and Portfolio Performance in Global Equity Markets Harry J

Structural Breaks and Portfolio Performance in Global Equity Markets Harry J

<p><a href="/goto?url=http://digitalcommons.georgefox.edu?utm_source=digitalcommons.georgefox.edu%2Fgfsb%2F52&amp;utm_medium=PDF&amp;utm_campaign=PDFCoverPages" target="_blank"><strong>Digital Commons @ George Fox University </strong></a></p><p></p><ul style="display: flex;"><li style="flex:1"><a href="/goto?url=http://digitalcommons.georgefox.edu/gfsb?utm_source=digitalcommons.georgefox.edu%2Fgfsb%2F52&amp;utm_medium=PDF&amp;utm_campaign=PDFCoverPages" target="_blank">Faculty Publications - School of Business </a></li><li style="flex:1"><a href="/goto?url=http://digitalcommons.georgefox.edu/business?utm_source=digitalcommons.georgefox.edu%2Fgfsb%2F52&amp;utm_medium=PDF&amp;utm_campaign=PDFCoverPages" target="_blank">School of Business </a></li></ul><p></p><p>2014 </p><p>Structural Breaks and Portfolio Performance in Global Equity Markets </p><p>Harry J. Turtle </p><p><em>West Virginia University </em></p><p>Chengping Zhang </p><p><em>George Fox University</em>, [email protected] </p><p>Follow this and additional works at: <a href="/goto?url=http://digitalcommons.georgefox.edu/gfsb?utm_source=digitalcommons.georgefox.edu%2Fgfsb%2F52&amp;utm_medium=PDF&amp;utm_campaign=PDFCoverPages" target="_blank">h</a><a href="/goto?url=http://digitalcommons.georgefox.edu/gfsb?utm_source=digitalcommons.georgefox.edu%2Fgfsb%2F52&amp;utm_medium=PDF&amp;utm_campaign=PDFCoverPages" target="_blank">t</a><a href="/goto?url=http://digitalcommons.georgefox.edu/gfsb?utm_source=digitalcommons.georgefox.edu%2Fgfsb%2F52&amp;utm_medium=PDF&amp;utm_campaign=PDFCoverPages" target="_blank">p://digitalcommons.georgefox.edu/gfsb </a><br>Part of the <a href="/goto?url=http://network.bepress.com/hgg/discipline/622?utm_source=digitalcommons.georgefox.edu%2Fgfsb%2F52&amp;utm_medium=PDF&amp;utm_campaign=PDFCoverPages" target="_blank">Business Commons </a></p><p>Recommended Citation </p><p>Turtle, Harry J. and Zhang, Chengping, "Structural Breaks and Portfolio Performance in Global Equity Markets" (2014). <em>Faculty </em></p><p><em>Publications - School of Business. </em>Paper 52. </p><p><a href="/goto?url=http://digitalcommons.georgefox.edu/gfsb/52?utm_source=digitalcommons.georgefox.edu%2Fgfsb%2F52&amp;utm_medium=PDF&amp;utm_campaign=PDFCoverPages" target="_blank">h</a><a href="/goto?url=http://digitalcommons.georgefox.edu/gfsb/52?utm_source=digitalcommons.georgefox.edu%2Fgfsb%2F52&amp;utm_medium=PDF&amp;utm_campaign=PDFCoverPages" target="_blank">t</a><a href="/goto?url=http://digitalcommons.georgefox.edu/gfsb/52?utm_source=digitalcommons.georgefox.edu%2Fgfsb%2F52&amp;utm_medium=PDF&amp;utm_campaign=PDFCoverPages" target="_blank">p://digitalcommons.georgefox.edu/gfsb/52 </a></p><p>is Article is brought to you for free and open access by the School of Business at Digital Commons @ George Fox University. It has been accepted for inclusion in Faculty Publications - School of Business by an authorized administrator of Digital Commons @ George Fox University. For more information, please contact <a href="mailto:[email protected]" target="_blank">[email protected]</a>. </p><p>© 2014 iStockphoto LP </p><p>Structural breaks and portfolio performance in global equity markets </p><p>HARRY J. TURTLE† and CHENGPING ZHANG‡* </p><p>†College of Business and Economics, West Virginia University, Morgantown, WV, USA <br>‡College of Business, George Fox University, Newberg, OR, USA </p><p>1. Introduction </p><p>of structural breaks in emerging equity markets due to increased world market integration. More recently, struc- <br>Traditional asset pricing models such as the Capital Asset&nbsp;tural break analysis by Berger et al. (2011) find that prePricing Model (CAPM) of Sharpe (1964), Lintner (1965), emerging&nbsp;or frontier, equity markets remained segregated and Mossin (1966); Merton’s (1973) Intertemporal Capital&nbsp;from other markets over time. </p><ul style="display: flex;"><li style="flex:1">Asset Pricing Model (ICAPM) and Fama and French’s </li><li style="flex:1">In general, structural breaks produce erroneous inferences </li></ul><p>three-factor model (1992, 1993, 1996) often require the&nbsp;and portfolio decisions due to model misspecification. As a assumption of stationary return distributions. Unfortunately,&nbsp;simple example, a structural shift in second moments will the extant literature provides substantial evidence that finan- produce&nbsp;a change in asset betas that might result in a spuricial time series might display structural changes.§ For exam-&nbsp;ously significant Jensen’s alpha, even when the true model ple, using a long history of aggregate stock returns in a&nbsp;displays no marginal performance benefit within regimes. Bayesian framework that incorporates uncertainty about&nbsp;Hillebrand (2005) documents this issue and shows that the structural break timing, Pastor and Stambaugh (2001) find sum&nbsp;of estimated autoregressive parameters will be heavily that the equity premium exhibits a sharp decline during the&nbsp;biased towards one in a GARCH model if parameter shifts 1990s. With regard to most emerging markets, Garcia and&nbsp;are not considered. Andreou and Ghysels (2008) point out Ghysels (1998) find that the parameter estimates of a CAPM&nbsp;that ignoring the presence of structural breaks can have with world factors show significant structural instability. Be-&nbsp;costly effects on financial risk management and may kaert et al. (2002) also provide strong evidence produce&nbsp;faulty inferences regarding credit risk. Recently, <br>Pettenuzzo and Timmermann (2011) find structural breaks cause model instability that impacts prediction, optimal </p><p>*Corresponding author. Email: <a href="mailto:[email protected]" target="_blank">[email protected] </a>xSee Andreou and Ghysels (2009) for an excellent review of struc-&nbsp;asset allocations and resultant investor utility. tural breaks in financial time series. </p><p>Structural breaks can often be used to describe general&nbsp;investments improve the location of the tangency portfolio financial market conditions. For example, Meligkotsidou&nbsp;from January 1988 to March 1997, the minimum variance and Vrontos (2008) find structural breaks in the hedge&nbsp;portfolio from April 1997 to March 2003 and both the minfund return series around the internet boom and the&nbsp;imum variance portfolio and the tangency portfolio from Long-Term Capital Management crisis. In addition, April&nbsp;2003 to January 2010. </p><ul style="display: flex;"><li style="flex:1">Gerlach et al. (2006) document a structural shift in the </li><li style="flex:1">Our analysis of structural breaks in global markets sug- </li></ul><p>integration of Asia-Pacific real estate markets due to the&nbsp;gests that disparate results observed in previous studies 1997 Asian financial crisis. The examination of structural&nbsp;might be due to differences in sample periods, the exclusion breaks in international financial markets remains impor-&nbsp;of particular markets, or both. We document the importance tant because studies by Hardouvelis et al. (2006), Carrieri&nbsp;of including even a small number of strongly performing et al. (2007), and Pukthuanthong and Roll (2009) find markets&nbsp;within a given sample and show that emerging evidence that integration of global stock markets has&nbsp;markets have not fully harmonized with other global mar- </p><ul style="display: flex;"><li style="flex:1">increased over time. </li><li style="flex:1">kets. Unrecognized inclusion of multiple market regimes in </li></ul><p>The potential benefits of adding international investments&nbsp;previous studies might be the cause of recent findings of to a well-diversified US-based portfolio have been debated&nbsp;diminishing benefits to diversification. </p><ul style="display: flex;"><li style="flex:1">since the seminal work of Solnik (1974b). For example, </li><li style="flex:1">Overall, we find a continued role for global diversifica- </li></ul><p>Harvey (1995) finds that including emerging market assets&nbsp;tion that does not uniformly diminish over time. Our in a mean-variance efficient portfolio significantly increases&nbsp;results suggest that multivariate return moments change expected returns and reduces volatility from March 1986 to&nbsp;over regimes, and that harmonization of global markets is June 1992. Bekaert and Urias (1996) show that, over a sim-&nbsp;not consistently demonstrated within regimes. For example, ilar timeframe, emerging market funds in the UK provide&nbsp;although US and emerging market sample means display diversification benefits whereas US emerging market funds&nbsp;similar patterns as we move from the first to second do not. De Santis and Gerard (1997) estimate that the&nbsp;regime, the third regime shows a dramatic increase in expected gain from international diversification is more than&nbsp;emerging market index returns as US market returns fall. 2% per year from 1970 to 1994. De Roon et al. (2001) find Intuitively,&nbsp;the positive relationship between means over strong evidence of diversification benefits from investing in&nbsp;the initial two regimes is consistent with integration of gloglobal emerging markets when market frictions are not&nbsp;bal markets, whereas the final period may be more indicataken into consideration, but the benefits largely diminish&nbsp;tive of a structural break in the relationship between the with short-sale constraints and transaction costs. In contrast,&nbsp;US and emerging markets. The difference is important for Li et al. (2003) show that international diversification bene-&nbsp;portfolio managers because integration suggests investment fits remain substantial for US investors even with short&nbsp;policy might be better structured solely within domestic selling constraints. Lewis (2007) finds that diversification markets,&nbsp;whereas a structural break interpretation suggests benefits, either from investing in foreign equities directly or&nbsp;global market diversification remains important for in American Depository Receipts (ADRs) traded in the US,&nbsp;asset allocation decisions. are diminishing due to increased world equity market integration. <br>The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. In <br>Section 2, we review the estimation and testing procedure <br>In this paper, our goal is to specify an empirical model&nbsp;for unknown breaks in a multivariate regression model and that admits linkages in the structural relationships between&nbsp;describe our mean-variance spanning test procedure. The global equity markets. Using a general multivariate regres-&nbsp;data are described in Section 3. Section 4 presents our sion model with unknown structural breaks, we examine&nbsp;empirical results. Conclusions are stated in Section 5. the diversification benefits in international market portfolios when global markets are subject to common structural changes. We apply the spanning tests of Kan and Zhou (2012) to disentangle the portfolio benefits available from </p><p>2. Econometric&nbsp;methodology </p><p>various asset classes. <br>We find two structural breaks (with three resultant regimes) in global equity markets from January 1988 through January 2010. These estimated breaks and their 95% confidence intervals are comparable across multiple beta risk models. We show that emerging markets provide significant marginal portfolio performance benefits to a well-diversified global investor prior to 1997 and post 2003 <br>We consider potential structural breaks in global financial markets comprised of US, developed and emerging markets. We examine the ability of regional emerging market returns to improve the performance of a well-diversified portfolio of US domestic holdings and developed market equities. We use the spanning tests of Kan and Zhou (2012) to analyse the potential of emerging markets to improve portfolio performance. <br>(post 2006 in our smallest model). </p><p>We also find that emerging markets significantly improve the mean-variance frontier relative to a broad set of bench- </p><p>2.1. Structural&nbsp;break testing and estimation </p><p>mark assets that include the Morgan Stanley Capital <br>The literature on testing, estimation and application of <br>International (MSCI) US equity index, the MSCI developed </p><p>structural break models is voluminous. Initial tests of strucmarket index and US small, big, value and growth </p><p>tural changes were restricted to the case of a single break in portfolios. In particular, Latin American emerging market a univariate regression model (see e.g. Andrews 1993). structural&nbsp;breaks, given an upper bound of M structural Later, Bai and Perron (1998, 2003, 2006) studied multiple&nbsp;breaks. The Qu and Perron test statistic may be written as break points in a univariate regression, while Bai et al. (1998) considered a single break in a multivariate context. Lien et al. (2003) identify structural changes in the Nikkei spot index and futures price using a nonparametric method. Berger et al. (2011) examine various frontier markets using univariate Quandt–Andrews breakpoint tests. Furno (2012) proposes a robust quantile regression test for structural breaks. <br>We adopt the generalized framework of Qu and Perron <br>(2007) who present the estimation, inference and computation of multiple potential structural breaks using linear multivariate regression models. Our initial multivariate linear specification includes the US market excess return, developed market excess return and emerging market excess return given two risk factors (global market risk and foreign exchange risk). With no structural breaks, our system is written as </p><p></p><ul style="display: flex;"><li style="flex:1">^</li><li style="flex:1">~</li></ul><p></p><p>supLR<sub style="top: 0.1219em;">T </sub>¼ 2½log L<sub style="top: 0.1219em;">T </sub>ð^s<sub style="top: 0.1219em;">1</sub>; . . .;^s<sub style="top: 0.1219em;">M </sub>Þ À log L<sub style="top: 0.1219em;">T </sub>Š </p><p>(3) </p><p>~<br>^</p><p>where log&nbsp;L<sub style="top: 0.123em;">T </sub>is the log-likelihood assuming no structural breaks, log&nbsp;L<sub style="top: 0.1226em;">T </sub>ð^s<sub style="top: 0.1226em;">1</sub>; . . .;^s<sub style="top: 0.1226em;">M </sub>Þ is the log-likelihood assuming M structural breaks and supLR<sub style="top: 0.1226em;">T </sub>represents the supremum of the likelihood ratios over all admissible partitions, ð^s<sub style="top: 0.1273em;">1</sub>; . . .;^s<sub style="top: 0.1273em;">M </sub>Þ, that determine the estimated breakpoints corresponding to the global maximization of the log-likelihood function. <br>Bai and Perron (1998) present a sequential procedure to test the null hypothesis of l structural changes vs. the alternative of l þ 1 breaks in a single regression model. Qu and Perron (2007) extend this sequential test to the multivariate case. The test procedure considers a model with l breaks under the null hypothesis vs. a less restrictive model with l + 1&nbsp;structural breaks. Bai and Perron (2003) provide critical values for these sequential test statistics. For a given system with ð^s<sub style="top: 0.1224em;">1</sub>; . . .;^s<sub style="top: 0.1224em;">M </sub>Þ estimated break points, the model </p><p></p><ul style="display: flex;"><li style="flex:1">2</li><li style="flex:1">3</li><li style="flex:1">2</li><li style="flex:1">3</li><li style="flex:1">2</li><li style="flex:1">3</li><li style="flex:1">2</li><li style="flex:1">3</li></ul><p></p><p>r<sub style="top: 0.1263em;">USt </sub>r<sub style="top: 0.1276em;">DMt </sub>r<sub style="top: 0.1276em;">EMt </sub>a<sub style="top: 0.1281em;">USi </sub>a<sub style="top: 0.1276em;">DMi </sub>b<sub style="top: 0.1942em;">USi </sub>b<sub style="top: 0.1937em;">DMi </sub>r<sub style="top: 0.1278em;">mt </sub>b<sub style="top: 0.1937em;">EMi </sub>c<sub style="top: 0.1939em;">USi </sub>c<sub style="top: 0.1937em;">DMi </sub>r<sub style="top: 0.1278em;">FXt </sub>c<sub style="top: 0.1937em;">EMi </sub></p><p></p><ul style="display: flex;"><li style="flex:1">4</li><li style="flex:1">5</li><li style="flex:1">4</li><li style="flex:1">5</li><li style="flex:1">4</li><li style="flex:1">5</li><li style="flex:1">4</li><li style="flex:1">5</li></ul><p></p><p>^</p><p></p><ul style="display: flex;"><li style="flex:1">¼</li><li style="flex:1">þ</li></ul><p></p><p>35</p><p>þ</p><p>admits regression coefficient estimates C<sub style="top: 0.1226em;">i </sub>and variance– covariance matrix estimates R<sub style="top: 0.1226em;">i </sub>for each regime </p><p>^</p><p>a<sub style="top: 0.1276em;">EMi </sub></p><p>2</p><p>e<sub style="top: 0.1278em;">USit </sub>e<sub style="top: 0.1276em;">DMit </sub>e<sub style="top: 0.1276em;">EMit </sub></p><p>iði ¼ 1; . . .; M þ 1Þ that may be estimated by a quasi-maxi- </p><p>4</p><p>þ</p><p>;</p><p>e<sub style="top: 0.1278em;">it </sub>ꢀ Nð0; R<sub style="top: 0.1278em;">i</sub>Þ </p><p>(1) mum likelihood procedure.‡ </p><p>Our estimation method allows multiple regimes with differing regression coefficients and covariance structures for s<sub style="top: 0.123em;">iÀ1 </sub>ꢁ t ꢁ s<sub style="top: 0.1228em;">i </sub>for i ¼ 1; . . .; M þ 1, s<sub style="top: 0.1228em;">0 </sub>¼ 1,s<sub style="top: 0.1228em;">Mþ1 </sub>¼ T; and&nbsp;across regimes. We recognize the importance of conditional where r<sub style="top: 0.1226em;">USt</sub>, r<sub style="top: 0.1228em;">DMt </sub>and r<sub style="top: 0.1228em;">EMt </sub>are monthly excess returns to the&nbsp;means and covariances in portfolio choice, and, therefore, MSCI US market, developed market and emerging market&nbsp;admit variability in our inputs. indices at time t, respectively; r<sub style="top: 0.1273em;">mt </sub>is the monthly excess return of the world benchmark portfolio, proxied by the excess return on the MSCI All Country World Index; and </p><p>2.2. Mean-variance&nbsp;spanning tests </p><p>r<sub style="top: 0.1221em;">FXt </sub>is the foreign exchange risk factor, proxied by the <br>A set of K risky assets spans a larger set of N risky assets </p><p>plus the original K assets if the minimum variance frontier of the K assets coincides with the frontier of the K þ N assets. The K risky assets are referred to as benchmark assets and the N assets are called test assets. Huberman and Kandel (1987) first formalized the notion of mean-variance spanning.§ They propose a regression-based likelihood-ratio test of the spanning hypothesis. If we define R<sub style="top: 0.1224em;">1t </sub>as the return on the vector of K benchmark assets and R<sub style="top: 0.1276em;">2t </sub>as the returns on the N test assets, we can examine spanning in the multivariate regression of R<sub style="top: 0.1273em;">2t </sub>on R<sub style="top: 0.1276em;">1t </sub>using the equation excess return on portfolio. </p><ul style="display: flex;"><li style="flex:1">a</li><li style="flex:1">trade-weighted foreign exchange </li></ul><p>For succinctness, we define r<sub style="top: 0.1221em;">t </sub>¼ ½r<sub style="top: 0.1228em;">USt</sub>; r<sub style="top: 0.1228em;">DMt</sub>; r<sub style="top: 0.1228em;">EMt</sub>Š<sup style="top: -0.4016em;">0</sup>, </p><p>X<sub style="top: 0.1226em;">t </sub>¼ ½1; r<sub style="top: 0.1226em;">mt</sub>; r<sub style="top: 0.1226em;">FXt</sub>Š<sup style="top: -0.4016em;">0</sup>; C<sub style="top: 0.1228em;">i </sub>¼ ½a<sub style="top: 0.1228em;">i</sub>; b<sub style="top: 0.1887em;">i</sub>; c<sub style="top: 0.1887em;">i</sub>Š, a<sub style="top: 0.1228em;">i </sub>¼ ½a<sub style="top: 0.1228em;">USi</sub>; a<sub style="top: 0.1228em;">DMi</sub>; a<sub style="top: 0.1228em;">EMi</sub>Š<sup style="top: -0.4016em;">0</sup>, b<sub style="top: 0.1937em;">i </sub>¼ ½b<sub style="top: 0.1937em;">USi</sub>; b<sub style="top: 0.1937em;">DMi</sub>; b<sub style="top: 0.1937em;">EMi</sub>Š<sup style="top: -0.3969em;">0</sup>, and c<sub style="top: 0.1937em;">i </sub>¼ ½c<sub style="top: 0.1937em;">USi</sub>; c<sub style="top: 0.1937em;">DMi</sub>; c<sub style="top: 0.1937em;">EMi</sub>Š<sup style="top: -0.3969em;">0</sup>. Similarly, </p><p>0</p><p>the vector e<sub style="top: 0.1273em;">it </sub>¼ ½e<sub style="top: 0.1276em;">USit</sub>; e<sub style="top: 0.1276em;">DMit</sub>; e<sub style="top: 0.1276em;">EMit</sub>Š is a 3 × 1 vector of disturbances that varies by date within regimes, with a regimespecific variance–covariance matrix, R<sub style="top: 0.1224em;">i</sub>. We consider M structural changes in the system and denote the break dates by the vector s ¼ ðs<sub style="top: 0.1224em;">i</sub>; . . .; s<sub style="top: 0.1224em;">M </sub>Þ. For a given number of M structural breaks, we have M þ 1 regimes.† Our general model admits potential shifts in intercepts, slope coefficients and variance–covariance elements. </p><p>R<sub style="top: 0.1223em;">2t </sub>¼ a þ bR<sub style="top: 0.1228em;">1t </sub>þ e<sub style="top: 0.1228em;">t </sub></p><p>(4) <br>Conditional upon a specific number of structural breaks, </p><p>M, and the definitions above, equation (1) may be written in matrix form as </p><p>‡The estimation procedure also requires a trimming parameter. Following Bai and Perron (2006), we set the trimming parameter to 0.15, implying a minimal length between breaks of at least 40 months. The use of alternative trimming parameters has little qualitative effect on our findings. </p><p>r<sub style="top: 0.1216em;">t </sub>¼ C<sub style="top: 0.1216em;">i</sub>X<sub style="top: 0.1216em;">t </sub>þ e<sub style="top: 0.1216em;">it</sub>: </p><p>(2) <br>Qu and Perron (2007) provide a testing procedure to </p><p>examine the null hypothesis of no structural breaks against&nbsp;§Spanning regressions and restrictions are closely related to the style regressions of Sharpe (1992) subject to the typical additional restrictions of positive betas for each of the K style portfolios. This approach has been especially helpful in studies of returns- </p><p>an alternative hypothesis of an unknown number of </p><p>†We follow the accepted usage in the structural break literature&nbsp;based style analysis, common in the field of portfolio management. and define the resultant periods with constant population parame-&nbsp;Approaches of this sort are valuable when underlying portfolio </p><ul style="display: flex;"><li style="flex:1">ters as regimes. </li><li style="flex:1">holdings are unobservable or only observed at discreet intervals. </li></ul><p></p><p>where Eðe<sub style="top: 0.1228em;">t</sub>Þ ¼ 0<sub style="top: 0.1228em;">N </sub>and Eðe<sub style="top: 0.1228em;">t</sub>R<sup style="top: -0.3213em;">0</sup><sub style="top: 0.2314em;">1t</sub>Þ ¼ 0<sub style="top: 0.1228em;">NÂK</sub>.† Following Kan&nbsp;weight in the N test assets. Intuitively, these tests allow and Zhou (2012), we note that when a ¼ 0<sub style="top: 0.1226em;">N </sub>and analysis&nbsp;of spanning rejections as in if they are due to the b1<sub style="top: 0.1276em;">K </sub>¼ 1<sub style="top: 0.1276em;">N </sub>, then EðR<sub style="top: 0.1276em;">2t</sub>Þ ¼ bEðR<sub style="top: 0.1276em;">1t</sub>Þ. Therefore, for each row&nbsp;test assets improving the optimal portfolio Sharpe ratio of EðR<sub style="top: 0.1273em;">2t</sub>Þ, there exists a combination of the K benchmark (i.e.&nbsp;the slope of the investment opportunity set [IOS]) or assets with the same expected return. Given standard regres-&nbsp;the location of the global minimum variance portfolio (i.e. sion assumptions, the covariance matrix of the test assets&nbsp;the vertex of the IOS). The distinction is important because may be written as VarðR<sub style="top: 0.1221em;">2t</sub>Þ ¼ VarðbR<sub style="top: 0.1221em;">1t</sub>Þ þ Varðe<sub style="top: 0.1221em;">t</sub>Þ. rejections&nbsp;due to improvements in the optimal Sharpe ratio Because Eðe<sub style="top: 0.1226em;">t</sub>R<sup style="top: -0.3215em;">0</sup><sub style="top: 0.2312em;">1t</sub>Þ ¼ 0<sub style="top: 0.1226em;">NÂK </sub>and Varðe<sub style="top: 0.1228em;">t</sub>Þ are positive definite, directly&nbsp;impact portfolio policy decisions, resultant portfolio for any conformable fixed weight vector, x, the portfolio&nbsp;performance and investor utility, whereas rejections due to variance from the N test assets will exceed the portfolio&nbsp;the location of the global minimum variance portfolio are variance from the K benchmark assets. That is, when&nbsp;likely of little interest to most well-diversified investors. </p><ul style="display: flex;"><li style="flex:1">a ¼ 0<sub style="top: 0.1269em;">N </sub>and b1<sub style="top: 0.1276em;">K </sub>¼ 1<sub style="top: 0.1276em;">N </sub>, the K benchmark assets dominate </li><li style="flex:1">The two component spanning tests may be applied </li></ul><p>the N test assets. Huberman and Kandel (1987) first demon-&nbsp;sequentially with the following F-tests strated that the hypothesis that the minimum variance frontier of K benchmark assets is coincident with the frontier of the universe of N þ K assets is equivalent to testing </p>

View Full Text

Details

  • File Type
    pdf
  • Upload Time
    -
  • Content Languages
    English
  • Upload User
    Anonymous/Not logged-in
  • File Pages
    15 Page
  • File Size
    -

Download

Channel Download Status
Express Download Enable

Copyright

We respect the copyrights and intellectual property rights of all users. All uploaded documents are either original works of the uploader or authorized works of the rightful owners.

  • Not to be reproduced or distributed without explicit permission.
  • Not used for commercial purposes outside of approved use cases.
  • Not used to infringe on the rights of the original creators.
  • If you believe any content infringes your copyright, please contact us immediately.

Support

For help with questions, suggestions, or problems, please contact us