Targets and Lags in a Two-Equation Model of US Stabilization Policy

Targets and Lags in a Two-Equation Model of US Stabilization Policy

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS WORKING PAPER SERIES Targets and Lags in a Two-Equation Model of US Stabilization Policy David Kiefer Working Paper No: 2011-03 August 2011 (revised November 2011) University of Utah Department of Economics 260 S. Central Campus Dr., Rm. 343 Tel: (801) 581-7481 Fax: (801) 585-5649 http://www.econ.utah.edu Targets and Lags in a Two-Equation Model of US Stabilization Policy David Kiefer * University of Utah November 2011 Abstract Carlin and Soskice (2005) advocate a 3-equation model of stabilization policy, the IS-PC-MR model. One of these is a monetary reaction rule MR derived by assuming that governments have performance objectives, but are constrained by a Phillips curve PC . Central banks attempt to implement these objectives by setting interest rates along an IS curve. We simplify their model to 2 equations ( PC and MR ), developing a state space econometric specification of this solution, and adding a random walk model of unobserved potential growth. This is an appropriate method because it incorporates recursive forecasts of unobservable state variables based on contemporaneous information measured with real-time data. Our results are generally consistent with US economic history. One qualification is that governments are more likely to target growth rates than output gaps. Another inference is that policy affects outcomes after a single lag. This assumption fits the data better than an alternative double-lag timing: one lag for output, plus a second for inflation has been proposed. We also infer that inflation expectations are more likely to be backward than forward looking. JEL codes: E3, E6 Keywords : new Keynesian stabilization, policy targets, real-time data * Department of Economics, 260 S. Central Campus Drive, Orson Spencer Hall, Rm 343, Salt Lake City, UT 84112-9150, Phone 801.581.7481 Fax 801.585.5649, Email: [email protected] . 2 1. Introduction Central to the new Keynesian conception of stabilization policy is the assumption that governments actively lean against the macroeconomic wind. Carlin and Soskice derive their monetary rule as rational behavior for a government constrained by a Phillips curve. 1 A number of alternative assumptions are consistent with this approach. One of these relates to the functional form of the government’s objective function. Starting with a quadratic form involving an inflation target, we highlight the differences implied by substituting an output growth target for the conventional an output gap target. Another issue is the timing of policy reactions. How quickly do policy makers respond to nominal and real shocks? Is there a delay before policy initiatives have an impact? Carlin and Soskice’s assumption is an inherent policy lag of one period, but plausible alternatives include an immediate response or a two- period lag, one for real output and two for inflation. We develop econometric specifications to distinguish among these possibilities. We apply state space methodology to specify a coherent model of stabilization, estimating its parameters by standard methods. This is an appropriate because our model includes unobserved state variables: the output gap and potential growth rate. We model potential growth as a random walk. By formalizing the relation between observables and unobservables, we obtain Bayesian forecasts of the unobservables conditioned on available information. A third modeling issue concerns how agents and governments make inflation forecasts; we explore several possibilities. For agents we begin with simple backward-looking expectations, and develop an extension to forward-looking ones using on a two-step estimation of a new Keynesian sticky-price model. Forward-looking expectations are appealing because they cohere with the notion of well-informed rational agents. We find, however, that the new Keynesian Phillips curve does not improve our statistical fit. 1 The original insight for this literature dates to Kalecki (1943). Modern versions begin with Kydland and Prescott (1977) who introduced the logic of rational expectations; Barro and Gordon (1983) further develop this logic. 3 2. Endogenous stabilization The monetary policy literature invariably invokes an augmented Phillips curve as a structural constraint on policy makers. Conventionally this is an inverse relation between the unexpected inflation and * the gap between actual and natural unemployment. Since the potential output Yt is conceptually related to the equilibrium or natural rate of unemployment, the output gap can be substituted for the unemployment gap as the measure of macroeconomic disequilibrium, E a x π t = t−1π t +ψ t +εt , (1) * where π t is the inflation rate, xt ≡ ln ()Yt − ln ()Yt is the output gap, Yt is real output and εt an inflation shock. Expected inflation E a π is interpreted as the forecast of a typical agent based on information t−1 t available in the previous year. Assuming expectations are fulfilled in the long run, (1) rules out any long- run deviation from x = 0. However, as long as economic agents do not fully anticipate fiscal, monetary and other policies, governments are able to temporarily increase output at the cost of higher inflation. Beginning with Fischer (1977) the literature has focused on explanations of this macroeconomic regularity founded in microeconomic mechanisms, including overlapping nominal wage contracts, stochastic price resetting, costly price adjustment and stochastic updating of information . Calvo’s (1983) “sticky price” model assumes that firms are uncertain whether they will be able to adjust its price in the each period. An important result is that the new Keynesian curve is forward looking, as contrasted to the backward-looking interpretation of expectations given to (1). We explore this refinement empirically in Section 6. Another essential element is an assumption about political objectives. A simple possibility supposes that the government’s goals are given as a quadratic function of the output gap and inflation, 2 U = − x 2 + ()π − πˆ , () where πˆ is the inflation target, not necessarily the announced target. Textbooks often define social welfare as an aggregation of individual preferences. Governmental targets may reflect a weighted average of citizen preferences. Woodford (2003) establishes microfoundations for several close relatives of this function form 4 as an approximation to the utility of a representative consumer-worker. Objectives might also include the discounted value of expected future outcomes. See Svensson (1997) for an elaboration of monetary policy based on multi-period objective functions, and Carlin and Soskice (2005) for a discussion of the single- period simplification. 2 Our approach accounts only for the period in which current policy initially influences outcomes, ignoring other periods as second order. Quadratic forms are tractable because they result in linear solutions. 3 Within the quadratic family, a variety of alternatives are plausible. Ours has circular indifference curves, but these can be made elliptical by adding a parameter to reflect the relative weight of inflation versus output goals. Some studies consider parabolic indifference curves. 4 Differing targets for inflation could account for ideological differences. Often the output target exceeds zero. 5 Kiefer (2008) estimates several different quadratic forms. He confirms the conventional wisdom that it is not possible to statistically separate goal weights from inflation and output targets. 6 Thus, the inflation-target parameter is a composite measure of weights and targets. Government has limited options in this model. Although it may be able to exploit information advantages implied in (1) to lean against the macroeconomic wind, nevertheless its goals x = 0 and π = πˆ are usually unattainable in the short run. Following Carlin and Soskice, we assume that policymaking is only effective after a one-period delay. Although they take periods as years, we apply the analysis to three possibilities, three-month, six-month and yearlong periods. They explain this delay as a lag in the IS relation between interest rate and output gap. 7 Recognizing that governments have more tools than just the 2 The government might plan for its current term of office only, or it might plan to be in office for several terms, discounting the future according to the probability of holding office. Alternatively, it might weigh pre-election years more heavily. These ideas are pursued in Kiefer (2000) who finds little evidence that governments have long-term stabilization goals. 3 Ruge-Murcia (2003) questions the conventional linearity assumption. He develops an alternative where the government’s inflation preferences are asymmetrical around its target. 4 See, for example, Alesina et al. (1997). 5 Barro and Gordon (1983) assume a zero inflation target and an unemployment target below the natural rate. 6 Also see Ireland (1999). 7 Although plausible, such policy lags conflict with conventional consumer choice derivations of the IS curve which do not show any lag; for example see Gali (2008). 5 interest rate, we assume this lag also applies to other instruments. Accordingly, we add an expectations operator and date the objective as g g 2 2 Et U = −Et xt+1 + ()π t+1 − πˆ , (2) () which defines the government’s expectation of next period’s welfare. Subject to the Phillips curve E a 2 t π t+1 +ψ πˆ constraint, the government’s preferred inflation is 2 , assuming that the government cannot 1+ψ E aε = 0 forecast the inflation shock, t t+1 . To the extent that agents are rational and well informed they would expect this inflation rate, however if expectations are inertial the government has an informational advantage. Lagging by one period and adding a random inflation shock, gives inflation as E a 2 t−1π t +ψ πˆ π t = 2 +εt (3) 1+ψ Using (1) and adding another shock, the resulting output gap is E a π − πˆ x = −ψ t−1 t + ξ . t 1+ψ 2 t We take the inflation shock εt and the output shock ξt to be exogenous and unpredictable.

View Full Text

Details

  • File Type
    pdf
  • Upload Time
    -
  • Content Languages
    English
  • Upload User
    Anonymous/Not logged-in
  • File Pages
    26 Page
  • File Size
    -

Download

Channel Download Status
Express Download Enable

Copyright

We respect the copyrights and intellectual property rights of all users. All uploaded documents are either original works of the uploader or authorized works of the rightful owners.

  • Not to be reproduced or distributed without explicit permission.
  • Not used for commercial purposes outside of approved use cases.
  • Not used to infringe on the rights of the original creators.
  • If you believe any content infringes your copyright, please contact us immediately.

Support

For help with questions, suggestions, or problems, please contact us