
Responding to VAT: Concurrent Tax and (C) Tax Analysts 2011. All rights reserved. does not claim copyright in any public domain or third party content. Social Security Reforms By Alan D. Viard Alan D. Viard is a resident scholar at the American Enterprise Institute. He thanks Alex Brill for helpful comments. The views expressed are solely his own. Most proposals for a VAT in the United States call for part, or all, of the resulting revenue to be used to reduce other taxes. In this essay, I discuss the possibilities of using a VAT to finance reductions in the corporate income tax, payroll and self- employment taxes, and the individual income tax. I also describe changes to the Social Security system that would need to accompany the adoption of a VAT. If a VAT is adopted, it should be used to eliminate the corporate income tax and its assortment of economic inefficien- cies. It should also be used to eliminate the Medicare component of the payroll and self-employment taxes. Replacement of the Social Security component of those taxes should be avoided, however, because it would be difficult to reconcile with the current design of the Social Security system. A variety of indi- vidual income tax reductions could be added to the corporate tax and Medicare tax reductions to achieve the desired mix of efficiency and distributional goals. Repeal the Corporate Income Tax Several recent VAT proposals have called for repeal or reduc- tion of the corporate income tax. The Treasury Department (2007) analyzed three reform options, one of which would replace the corporate income tax with a VAT. The Roadmap for America’s Future proposal introduced by Rep. Paul Ryan, R-Wis., would also replace the corporate income tax with a VAT. Prof. Michael Graetz’s (2008) VAT proposal calls for a reduction in the corpo- rate income tax rate to 15 or 20 percent. On efficiency grounds, the corporate income tax is a prime candidate for full or partial replacement. Like any other tax on capital income, and unlike the VAT, the corporate income tax TAX ANALYSTS 123 VIARD THE VAT READER penalizes saving for future consumption, relative to current consumption. But the tax induces a wide variety of additional (C) Tax Analysts 2011. All rights reserved. does not claim copyright in any public domain or third party content. distortions not imposed by other taxes on capital income. Some of the distortions arise from the fact that the corporate income tax essentially applies only to equity-financed investment by corporations, not to corporate debt-financed investment or noncorporate investment. To be sure, corporate equity enjoys advantages at the individual level because reinvested earnings are not taxed until gains are realized and because dividends and capital gains are taxed at preferential rates, although the divi- dend preference is scheduled to expire at the end of 2010. On the whole, though, corporate equity-financed investment is taxed more heavily than other investment. As a result, the corporate income tax distorts the choice of organizational form and the choice between debt and equity. The corporate income tax also penalizes the location of invest- ment inside the United States. For foreign-chartered firms, the tax applies only to income derived inside the United States, giving those firms an incentive to operate abroad rather than here. In an effort to keep investment in the United States, the current system taxes U.S.-chartered firms on their foreign, as well as their do- mestic, income. At least in the long run, however, this charter- based taxation (misleadingly called ‘‘global’’ or ‘‘worldwide’’ taxation) probably does little to keep investment in the United States and instead simply encourages investment abroad to be done through foreign- rather than U.S.-chartered firms. This doubtlessly explains why charter-based taxation is being aban- doned by many countries and why the United States’ application of it has always been diluted by the deferral of tax on overseas earnings. All of these considerations suggest that the United States should join the international movement toward lower corporate tax rates. Given the lack of a coherent argument for why corporate equity investment should be singled out for taxation, outright elimination of the corporate income tax would be ideal. The resulting flow of investment to the United States would ultimately make labor more productive and thereby boost real 124 TAX ANALYSTS THE VAT READER VIARD wages. Treasury (2007) estimated that replacement of the corpo- rate income tax with a VAT would increase long-run output by 2 (C) Tax Analysts 2011. All rights reserved. does not claim copyright in any public domain or third party content. to 2.5 percent. The repeal of the corporate income tax should be accompanied by a significant strengthening of the undistributed earnings tax to protect the individual income tax base from erosion. Also, preferential individual income tax treatment of dividends, rela- tive to other types of capital income, would no longer be needed once there was no corporate tax to offset. There might be resistance on distributional grounds to the use of the VAT to finance a repeal of the corporate income tax. Those concerns would be misplaced to the extent that the benefits of corporate tax repeal flow to workers in the form of higher wages. In any case, the concerns could be addressed by including indi- vidual income tax reductions in the package, as discussed below. Modify Payroll and Self-Employment Taxes There would be economic advantages to using a VAT to partially replace payroll and self-employment taxes, which are essentially equivalent to a wage tax. To be sure, wage taxes are relatively simple and relatively efficient because, like consump- tion taxes, they do not distort the saving decision. Nevertheless, wage taxes are economically inferior to consumption taxes. The consumption tax base effectively includes wages, plus above- normal returns on new investment and initial wealth. It is clearly desirable to tax above-normal returns, and it is probably desir- able to place some tax burden on initial wealth while using transition relief to modulate the extent of the burden. Therefore, replacing a wage tax with a consumption tax offers at least modest economic gains. Complications arise, however, because payroll and self- employment taxes are tied to Social Security and Medicare Part A. Those complications make it unwise to replace the Social Security component of these taxes but do not pose an obstacle to replacement of the Medicare component. At the aggregate level, payroll and self-employment taxes are earmarked to finance Social Security and Medicare Part A benefits. Those programs are not authorized to pay benefits greater than the levels that can be supported by current and past TAX ANALYSTS 125 VIARD THE VAT READER taxes, as tracked by a trust-fund accounting mechanism. On the whole, this earmarking appears to have promoted fiscal respon- (C) Tax Analysts 2011. All rights reserved. does not claim copyright in any public domain or third party content. sibility and spending restraint, particularly for Social Security. Legislation to restrain Social Security benefit growth was enacted in 1983 when earmarked taxes were insufficient to support scheduled benefits, and discussion of Social Security reform today is driven by the prospect that earmarked taxes will again fall short in roughly three decades. Could these advantages be retained by earmarking some of the VAT receipts to finance Social Security and Medicare Part A? For Medicare, that approach would indeed be satisfactory. If a VAT is adopted, the Medicare tax should be abolished, as Burman (2008) has proposed, and a portion of the VAT receipts should be earmarked to finance Part A benefits. Unfortunately, that ap- proach would not work well for Social Security. Formidable complications would arise because Social Security benefits are linked to tax payments at the individual level, a linkage that does not exist to any significant extent in Medicare. Specifically, each worker’s Social Security benefits are based on her lifetime earnings (wages and self-employment income) that were subject to Social Security tax. A worker with higher average earnings receives higher monthly benefits, although the increase is less than proportional. The benefit computation includes only earnings subject to Social Security tax; it excludes earnings that exceeded the taxable maximum and those from employment not covered by Social Security, primarily some state and local gov- ernment employment. It would be difficult to maintain the current benefit formula if Social Security benefits were financed by a VAT rather than by payroll and self-employment taxes. At a minimum, it would be inappropriate to continue excluding earnings from employment previously exempt from Social Security tax, as those workers would now pay the same VAT as other workers to finance the system. More broadly, the principle of paying higher monthly benefits to those with higher lifetime earnings might be politi- cally untenable in the absence of a visible link between earnings and tax payments. (Of course, there would still be a linkage, because workers with higher earnings would pay higher VAT over their lifetimes.) 126 TAX ANALYSTS THE VAT READER VIARD One possible response would be to radically revamp the benefit formula, perhaps paying flat monthly benefits to all (C) Tax Analysts 2011. All rights reserved. does not claim copyright in any public domain or third party content. retirees. But that switch would create its own problems, as it would dramatically change public perceptions of the system’s contributory nature. Moreover, there would be no easy way to apply it to current workers, who have been paying earnings- related taxes and have been promised earnings-related benefits. Social Security is often considered the third rail of American politics.
Details
-
File Typepdf
-
Upload Time-
-
Content LanguagesEnglish
-
Upload UserAnonymous/Not logged-in
-
File Pages7 Page
-
File Size-