
A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Totzek, Alexander Working Paper The Bank, the Bank-Run, and the Central Bank: The Impact of Early Deposit Withdrawals in a New Keynesian Framework Economics Working Paper, No. 2008-20 Provided in Cooperation with: Christian-Albrechts-University of Kiel, Department of Economics Suggested Citation: Totzek, Alexander (2008) : The Bank, the Bank-Run, and the Central Bank: The Impact of Early Deposit Withdrawals in a New Keynesian Framework, Economics Working Paper, No. 2008-20, Kiel University, Department of Economics, Kiel This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/27675 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu The Bank, the Bank-Run, and the Central Bank: The Impact of Early Deposit Withdrawals in a New Keynesian Framework by Alexander Totzek Economics Working Paper No 200 8-20 The Bank, the Bank-Run, and the Central Bank: The Impact of Early Deposit Withdrawals in a New Keynesian Framework∗ Alexander Totzek∗∗ Department of Economics, Christian-Albrechts-University of Kiel, Olshausenstr. 40, D-24098 Kiel, Germany December 15, 2008 Abstract Currently, private trust in commercial banks declines as a consequence of today´s financial crisis. As past crises, e.g. the Asian crisis, show, the loss of confidence in the financial sector typically causes private agents to withdraw their capital from financial institutions. Thus, the purpose of this paper is to implement the feature of early deposit withdrawal in a New Keynesian framework with commercial banks in order to analyze the implications of a loss of confidence. In addition, we present the optimal monetary policy to ensure a stabilized system. JEL classification: E44, E50, G01 Keywords: banks, financial crises, deposit withdrawal, optimal monetary policy ∗ I would like to thank Hans-Werner Wohltmann, Roland Winkler, Stephen Sacht and Christian Merkl for very helpful comments. ∗∗ Phone: +49-431-880-1447, Fax: +49-431-880-2228, E-mail: [email protected] 1 Introduction Currently, private trust in commercial banks declines as a consequence of to- day´s financial crisis. As past crises, e.g. the Asian crisis, show, the loss of confidence in the financial sector typically causes private agents to withdraw their capital from financial institutions. The corresponding extreme case sce- nario would be the bank-run. Fortunately, this scenario has not yet occurred in today’s financial turmoil. But what happens, if it does? Therefore, the purpose of this paper is to develop a New Keynesian model with explicit consideration of early deposit withdrawals in order to analyze the implications of households’ loss of confidence in the financial system. Moreover, we will present the optimal monetary policy to ensure a stabilized system. The main results are: (i) the extended withdrawal leads to temporary stagflation. (ii) also an impulse shock leads to persistent real effects. (iii) the resulting welfare losses decrease in bank’s adjustment costs. (iv) the opti- mal central bank’s response is to rise the interest rate in order to increase the private costs of withdrawals. (v) the optimal monetary policy response implies that the impact recession is amplified while inflation is stabilized. This paper is related to recent literature as an implementation of early deposit withdrawal in a New Keynesian framework. Hence, like Henzel et al. (2007) or H¨ulsewig, Mayer and Wollmersh¨auser (2006), we explicitly model a third type of economic agent besides households and firms, namely the bank as a kind of profit maximizing firm. But in contrast to the latter studies that just implement commercial banks for the purpose of generating a cost channel, we allow the household to early withdraw deposits during the current period. However, there are several studies which investigate the impact of early deposit withdrawal on the financial system [e.g. Gilkeson et al. (1999), Ring- bom et al. (2004) or Stanhouse and Stock (2004)]. Other studies use such a framework for modelling financial problems [e.g. Carletti et al. (2007) who investigate the impact of bank mergers on liquidity needs or Diamond and Dy- bvig (1983) who investigate optimal bank contracts that can prevent bank-runs] but to our best knowledge, it has never been implemented in a New Keynesian framework, yet. Moreover, the analysis shows that the shock of confidence causes both the marginal costs of firms and banks to increase. Hence, the current paper can also be seen as a new approach for implementing a microfounded cost push shock in a New Keynesian framework. The remainder is structured as follows. Section 2 presents the basic idea of the interaction between the agents and the problems resulting from withdrawals. In section 3 the microfounded New Keynesian model for a closed economy with explicit consideration of the banking sector and the possibility for households of withdrawing deposits in a cash-in-advance framework is developed. The purpose of section 4 is to analyze the impulse responses to a shock in the withdrawal rate and the optimal monetary policy. In the last chapter, the main results are summarized. 1 2 Idea Apart from consumption demand and labor supply decisions, the household can invest money in form of interest-bearing deposits with a duration of one period at a loan bank. Within the period, the household can decide to break the contract with the bank and to early withdraw deposits. In the case that the household holds its deposits D till the end of the period, D it obtains a next period return of Rt Dt. But the household only fulfills the con- tract with the probability 1 − δt. With the counter probability δt the household withdraws its capital from the bank within the period. In this case deposits are converted into liquid money. In punishment of breaking the contract the household does not get any interest payments. Its payoff is then simply given by D. Hence, it is implicitly assumed that deposits contain an embedded with- drawal option. In contrast to the withdrawal per se, the option is assumed to be costless [see e.g. Gilkeson et al. (2000) or Stanhouse and Ingram (2007)]. Due to the temporal sequence of cash flows, firms have to pre-finance house- holds’ wages at the loan bank by credits. Banks’ business is therefore assumed to be given by pre-financing firms’ working capital with the usage of private deposits. Thereby, the amount of credits is limited by the amount of private deposits and banks’ reserve holdings. Reserves ℜt(i) are held to ensure the bank against liquidity shortages as a consequence of withdrawals. If the demand for liquidity δtDt(i) exceeds the reserve holdings, the loan I bank has to refinance the resulting liquidity gap at a final creditor with rt > L I L rt > rt, where rt , rt and rt denote the refinancing interest rate, the loan rate and the nominal interest rate (representing the central bank’s instrument variable), respectively. The final creditor or lender of last resort substitutes the interbank market for short-run capital since in turbulent times/financial crises, interbank markets often fail [see e.g. Freixas et al. (2000) or Kahn and Santos (2005)]. Moreover, it is assumed that liquidity needs will not force the single banks into bankruptcy and that hence the lender of last resort must possess unlimited liquidity. Figure 1 depicts the resulting cash flows between the differentiated types of agents. The interactions between banks and final creditor are put in parenthe- sis since they only occur if the amount of deposit withdrawals exceeds banks’ reserve holdings. For sake of simplicity, dividend payments from banks and firms are neglected in figure 1. Without any shock in confidence, the bank’s balance of payments is shown in table 1. In period t = 0 the households makes its deposits Dt(i) at bank i. t = 0 0 <t< 1 t = 1 D Dt(i) −δtDt(i) −(1 − δt)Rt Dt(i) L −Lt(i) ℜt(i)= δtDt(i) Rt Lt(i) −ℜ(i)= δtDt(i) 0 0 > 0 Table 1: The Bank’s balance of payments without confidence shock 2 Creditor 6 (credits) ? (interest payments) withdrawal @I Banks @ interest@ paymentsdeposits @ @ @ @ credits @ @ @ @ @ © @@R @ ? interest paymentsgoods expenditure Firms - Households labor income Figure 1: cash flows The contributed capital the bank deals in credits Lt(i) for firms and in reserves ℜt(i). The bank chooses the amount of reserves as ℜt(i) = δtDt(i) to ensure itself against the expected withdrawal during the period. In 0 <t< 1 some constant fraction of households δt = δ now withdraws its capital. Since the bank has considered that in its reserve holding decision, the balance of payments is even within the period. At the beginning of t = 1 (or at the end of t = 0) the fraction 1 − δt of households that has not withdrawn its deposits gets its D interest payments Rt Dt(i).
Details
-
File Typepdf
-
Upload Time-
-
Content LanguagesEnglish
-
Upload UserAnonymous/Not logged-in
-
File Pages20 Page
-
File Size-