Instrument-Based Vs. Target-Based Rules

Instrument-Based Vs. Target-Based Rules

Instrument-Based vs. Target-Based Rules Marina Halac Pierre Yared Yale University Columbia University January 2020 Motivation Should central bank incentives be based on instruments or targets? • Instruments: interest rate, exchange rate, money growth • Targets: inflation, price level, output growth Global central banks have moved towards inflation targets • 26 central banks since 1990, 14 EMs • But many EMs continue fixed exchange rate regimes This paper: Do target-based rules dominate instrument-based ones? What We Do Monetary model to study instrument-based vs. target based rules • Rule is optimal mechanism in setting with non-contractible information Elucidate benefits of each class, when one is preferred over the other • Compare performance as a function of the environment Characterize optimal unconstrained or hybrid rule • Examine how combining instruments and targets can improve welfare Preview of Model Canonical New Keynesian model with demand shocks Central bank (CB) lacks commitment, has private forecast of demand • Inflation/output depends on monetary policy and realized demand Incentives: Socially costly punishments (money burning); no transfers • Instrument-based rule: Punishment depends on interest rate • Target-based rule: Punishment depends on inflation Main Results In each class, optimal rule is a maximally enforced threshold • Instrument-based: Punish interest rates below a threshold • Target-based: Punish inflation above a threshold Target-based dominate instrument-based iff CB info is precise enough • More appealing on the margin if CB commitment problem is less severe Optimal hybrid rule improves with a simple implementation • Instrument threshold that is relaxed when target threshold is satisfied • E.g., interest rate rule which switches to inflation target once violated Related Literature Optimal monetary policy institutions • Rogoff 1985, Bernanke-Mishkin 1997, McCallum-Nelson 2005, Svensson 2005, Giannoni-Woodford 2017 • This paper: Mechanism design to characterize and compare rules Commitment vs. flexibility in policymaking • Athey-Atkeson-Kehoe 2005, Amador-Werning-Angeletos 2006, Halac-Yared 2014,19 • This paper: Condition incentives on outcome in addition to action Delegation in principal-agent setting • Holmstrom 1977,84, Alonso-Matouschek 2008, Amador-Bagwell 2013 • This paper: Condition incentives on outcome in addition to action Model New Keynesian model: πt = βEtπt+1 + κxt (Phillips Curve) xt = Etxt+1 − ζ(it − Etπt+1) − θt/κ (Euler Equation) θt i.i.d. with Eθt = 0 (Demand Shock) Social welfare at t = 0: 1 2 2 X (κxt) π E βt ακx − γ − t −1 t 2 2 t=0 Substituting with Phillips curve: ( 1 " 2 2 #) X (πt − βEtπt+1) π E απ + βt −γ − t −1 0 2 2 t=0 Timing L H 1. CB privately observes signal st = fs ; s g • Where sH = −sL = ∆ and each signal has equal probability 2. CB publicly chooses interest rate it 2 3. Aggregate demand θt is publicly observed, where θtjst ∼ N st; σ 2 2 • Unconditional distribution has E(θt) = 0 and V ar(θt) = σ + ∆ 4. Expectations are formed, output gap and inflation are realized 5. CB punished according to rule: Pt 2 [0; P ] based on it and/or πt Markov Perfect Equilibrium Focus on Markov CB strategy, conditioning on st only and not history • Constant future expectations (Eπ, Ex) on- and off-path Given expectations, CB's choice of it implies choice of µt: µt ≡ (β + κζ)Eπ + κEx − κζit Therefore, πt = µt − θt Eπ = Eµ µ − θ − βEµ x = t t t κ Welfare Social welfare from timeless perspective: E [U(µ, θ; Eµ) − P (µ, µ − θ)] [µ − θ − βEµ] 2 (µ − θ)2 where U(µ, θ; Eµ) = −γ − 2 2 Given Eµ, CB of type sj chooses µj to maximize j j j j Esj α µ − θ − βEµ + U(µ ; θ; Eµ) − P (µ ; µ − θ) Thus, CB is better informed but biased relative to society: First best policy: µ = s; implying Eπ = Ex = 0 α + γβEµ Flexible policy: µ = s + implying Eπ > 0, Ex > 0 1 + γ Classes of Rules Compare different classes of rules • Instrument-based: P (µ, µ − θ) depends only on µ • Target-based: P (µ, µ − θ) depends only on µ − θ Compare as we vary info precision keeping E(θ) and V ar(θ) fixed • Uninformative signal: σ ! pV ar(θ) and ∆ ! 0 • Perfect signal: σ ! 0 and ∆ ! pV ar(θ) Assumptions: 1. Types are close: α=(1 + γ) ≥ 2∆ I Implies both types prefer higher action than either type's first best α2 1 2. Large maximum punishment: P ≥ 1+γ 2φ(1j0;1) I Implies sufficient breadth of incentives to use in relationship Optimal Instrument-Based Rule X 1 max E U(µj; θ; Eµ) − P jjsj µL,µH ;P L;P H 2 j=L;H subject to, for j = L; H, E αµj + U(µj; θ; Eµ) − P jjsj ≥ E αµ−j + U(µ−j; θ; Eµ) − P −jjsj j j j j j E αµ + U(µ ; θ; Eµ) − P js ≥ max E αµe + U(µ,e θ; Eµ) − P js µe P j 2 [0; P ] Optimal Instrument-Based Rule Proposition: Optimal rule implemented with maximally-enforced instrument threshold µ∗ = 0. • If µ ≤ µ∗, P (µ) = 0. Otherwise P (µ) = P Proof: Solve relaxed problem with only L's private info constraint • Optimal mechanism admits µL = µH = µ∗ = 0, P L = P H = 0 Mechanism deters CB from choosing excessively expansionary policy • Enforcement constraint non-binding, punishment occurs off path Optimal Target-Based Rule X 1 max E U(µj; θ; Eµ) − P (µj − θ)jsj µL,µH ;P (π) 2 j=L;H subject to, for j = L; H, j j µ 2 arg max E αµe + U(µ,e θ; Eµ) − P (µe − θ)js µe P (π) 2 0; P for all π Optimal Target-Based Rule Proposition: Optimal rule implemented with maximally-enforced target threshold π∗. • If π ≤ π∗, P (π) = 0. Otherwise P (π) = P Proof: Solve relaxed problem using a first-order approach j j • Given normal shocks, CB's FOC yields µ = s + δ for some δ T 0 • Social welfare depends on δ and is independent of type Mechanism deters CB from choosing excessively expansionary policy • α+γβEµ δ 2 0; 1+γ : below flexible, above first best (to limit punishment) • E(π) = δ < π∗: CB undershoots cap (to limit punishment) Role of Precision of Private Information Consider increasing precision σ−1 while keeping V ar(θ) unchanged Social welfare is unchanged under optimal instrument-based rule: V ar(θ) −(1 + γ) 2 but it increases under optimal target-based rule: σ2 δ2 −(1 + γ) − 1 + γ(1 − β)2 − Pr π > π∗jσ2 P 2 2 Welfare at the extremes: • Perfect signal (σ ! 0, ∆ ! pV ar(θ)): target-based dominates • Uninformative (σ ! pV ar(θ), ∆ ! 0): instrument-based dominates Optimal Class of Rules Proposition: Take instrument-based and target-based rules and consider changing σ while keeping V ar(θ) unchanged • There exists σ∗ > 0 s.t target-based strictly optimal if σ < σ∗, instrument-based strictly optimal if σ > σ∗. • σ∗ is decreasing in CB's bias α and increasing in punishment P Low α and high P reduce punishment frequency in target-based rule • While not affecting welfare under instrument-based rule When does inflation-targeting dominate interest rate rule? • CB has highly superior non-contractible information • CB is not very biased, suffers large sanctions Optimal Hybrid Rule X 1 max E U(µj; θ; Eµ) − P j(θ)jsj µL,µH ;P L(θ);P H (θ) 2 j=L;H subject to, for j = L; H, E αµj + U(µj; θ; Eµ) − P j(θ)jsj ≥ E αµ−j + U(µ−j; θ; Eµ) − P −j(θ)jsj j j j j j E αµ + U(µ ; θ; Eµ) − P (θ)js ≥ max E αµe + U(µ,e θ; Eµ) − P js µe P j(θ) 2 [0; P ] for all θ Optimal Hybrid Rule Proposition: Optimal rule implemented with maximally-enforced hybrid threshold fµ∗; µ∗∗; π∗(µ)g. • If µ ≤ µ∗, P (µ, θ) = 0 • If µ 2 (µ∗; µ∗∗], P (µ, θ) = 0 if π ≤ π∗(µ). Otherwise P (µ, θ) = P • If µ > µ∗∗, P (µ, θ) = P Proof: Solve relaxed problem with only L's private info constraint • Solution yields µL = µ∗ < µH = µ∗∗ Optimal rule admits simple implementation, strictly improves welfare • Interest rate rule switches to inflation target if violated • " flexibility vs. instrument-based, # punishment vs. target-based Discussion: Other Instruments and Targets Results apply to output gap/price level target instead of inflation • Follows from divine coincidence Results apply to open economy: ∗ it = it + Et(∆et+1) (UIP) • CB choice of ∆et+1 is equivalent to choice of it • Optimal instrument-based rule is cap on exchange rate devaluation Results apply to model with money growth ∆mt = πt + xt − ηit − xt−1 + ηit−1 • Optimal instrument-based rule is cap on money growth rate Extension: Continuum of Types 2 2 Suppose CB's signal is st ∼ N 0; ∆ , with θtjst ∼ N st; σ 2 2 • Unconditional distribution has E(θt) = 0 and V ar(θt) = σ + ∆ • Let β = 1: Zero expected output gap, no expected inflation externality I Allows focus on welfare implications of local perturbations Proposition: Optimal instrument-based and target-based rules take the same implementation as under binary types. There exists σ∗ > 0 s.t. target-based preferred if σ < σ∗, instrument-based if σ > σ∗ Target-based identical to two-type case. Instrument-based different: • Types s < s∗ and s > s∗∗ choose flexible action; s 2 [s∗; s∗∗] bunched • Moreover, types s > s∗∗ break threshold and are punished • Welfare increases with precision, but main result still valid Extension: Persistent Shocks Suppose θt−1 shifts mean of θt • Signal st also shifted by Et−1(θt) • Implication: Action µt can be renormalized by Et−1(θt) Proposition: Optimal instrument-based and target-based rules take the same implementation as under i.i.d shocks.

View Full Text

Details

  • File Type
    pdf
  • Upload Time
    -
  • Content Languages
    English
  • Upload User
    Anonymous/Not logged-in
  • File Pages
    24 Page
  • File Size
    -

Download

Channel Download Status
Express Download Enable

Copyright

We respect the copyrights and intellectual property rights of all users. All uploaded documents are either original works of the uploader or authorized works of the rightful owners.

  • Not to be reproduced or distributed without explicit permission.
  • Not used for commercial purposes outside of approved use cases.
  • Not used to infringe on the rights of the original creators.
  • If you believe any content infringes your copyright, please contact us immediately.

Support

For help with questions, suggestions, or problems, please contact us