Hyperinflation in a Monetary Union: Lessons from 1619-1623

Hyperinflation in a Monetary Union: Lessons from 1619-1623

Hyperinflation in a Monetary Union: Lessons from 1619‐1623 Martin Kliem and Alexander Kriwoluzky Deutsche Bundesbank University of Halle Chicago, 1st April 2016 Disclaimer: The views expressed by the authors in this presentation do not necessarily reflect those of the Deutsche Bundesbank or those of the European System of Central Banks. Motivation • The European Monetary Union (EMU) faces institutional gaps (Sims, 1999; Uhlig, 2003) • How do these gaps affect price stability in such an union ‐ especially in presence of big shocks? • EMU is unique, hard to find comparable structure anywhere else • Therefore, we investigate a historical episode with surprising similarities The Holy Roman Empire The structure of the Holy Roman Empire Emperor Army of Empire Imperial Courts Imperial Diet “Reichstag” legislative body of empire 10 imperial circles up to 300 imperial estates Executive body: defence, imperial Individual entities governed by taxation, supervision of coining, bishops, kings, dukes, abbots peace‐keeping functions and public security The Holy Roman Empire and the EU Niall Ferguson (2005): “Like the Holy Roman Empire , it (the EU) has a relatively weak legislature … like the Holy Roman Empire it (the EU) is always in the process of reforming itself, without ever quite getting there.” Jan Zielonka (2006): “In Essence, the Holy Roman Empire like the contemporary EU was always a highly ‘plurilateral‘ and decentralized unit unable or unwilling to forge a fully fledged political union” Timeline From 1559 to Hyperinflation • Augsburg imperial mint ordinance (“Reichsmünzordnung”) • selected group of princes maintaining a limited number of mints • intrinsic content of coins was fixed • system of supervision and punishment 1559 1610 1618 1623 From 1559 to Hyperinflation • silver content for small coins was set too high • incentive to reduce intrinsic value • rules to prevent this behavior were not enforceable ‐> right from beginning incentives to deviate from “Reichsmünzordnung” 15591610 1618 1623 From 1559 to Hyperinflation • debasement becomes more severe • imperial estates (principalities) still attempt to fight debasement e.g. tried to punish mints not minting according to “Reichsmünzordnung” 1559 1610 1618 1623 From 1559 to Hyperinflation • start of the Thirty Years‘ War • Hyperinflation starts in 1618/19 ‐> called “Kipper‐ and Wipperzeit” (to tilt) (to seesaw) • similar characteristics as before but at different pace (e.g. more mints) 1559 1610 1618 1623 From 1559 to Hyperinflation • People became unwilling to accept bad coins • Government received more and more bad coins • Between 1623‐1624, the authorities started to revert to the old coinage system • Bad coins were withdrawn from circulation • Losses were borne by the principalities ‐> Commitment device to stop hyperinflation 1559 1610 1618 1623 Historical data Debasement of Kreutzer vs Reichsthaler 700 600 Bayern 500 400 Frankfurt 300 200 100 0 1559 1569 1598 1610 1618 1621 1623 Source: Schneider (1991): Frankfurt und die Kipper‐ und Wipperinflation der Jahre 1619‐1623. Altmann (1976): Die Kipper‐ und Wipperinflation in Bayern (1620‐1623). Price indices (CPI) in local currencies (Kreuzer or Pfennig) 16 14 Leipzig 12 Augsburg 10 Munich 8 Vienna 6 4 2 0 1565 1575 1585 1595 1605 1615 1625 Source: Elsas (1940): “Umriss einer Geschichte der Preise und Löhne in Deutschland“. Vol. 2. Allen (2001), “The Great Divergence in European Prices and Wages from the Middle Ages to the First World War", Explorations in Economic History Seignorage („Schlagschatz“) in Gulden 700000 3500 Munich 600000 3000 Kulmbach 500000 2500 Kursachsen 400000 Quedlinburg 2000 300000 1500 200000 1000 100000 500 0 0 1604 1605 1606 1607 1608 1609 1610 1610 1611 1612 1613 1614 1615 1616 1617 1618 1619 1620 1621 1622 Outlook and Questions Historical Data • we have started to collect data for prices, on debasement, and seignorage • so far just from few areas of the HRE • most of data sources are anecdotal descriptions of the most severe episode for a single region (state) • various issues: missing observations, etc • Goal: comprehensive picture (e.g. fiscal financing) of the union at this time; most existing paper focus on one state Guidance for modeling • interpretation of data through structural model • Kipper‐ and Wipperinflation often told as version of Gresham‘s Law (Kindleberger, 1991; Schnabel and Shin, 2006) • for us, this sounds questionable (see also Rolnick and Weber, 1986; Sargent and Smith, 1997) • quite stable epsiode until war; until more and more governments join the game of debasement • rather fiscal inflation (unpleasent arithmetic) Further intersting features: • fiscal free riding, assymetric information Distribution across Holy Roman Empire Number of flysheets per region regarding hyperinflation between 1620‐1623 Source: Rosseaux (2001): “Die Kipper‐ und Wipperinflation als publizistisches Ereignis (1620‐1626)“ .

View Full Text

Details

  • File Type
    pdf
  • Upload Time
    -
  • Content Languages
    English
  • Upload User
    Anonymous/Not logged-in
  • File Pages
    19 Page
  • File Size
    -

Download

Channel Download Status
Express Download Enable

Copyright

We respect the copyrights and intellectual property rights of all users. All uploaded documents are either original works of the uploader or authorized works of the rightful owners.

  • Not to be reproduced or distributed without explicit permission.
  • Not used for commercial purposes outside of approved use cases.
  • Not used to infringe on the rights of the original creators.
  • If you believe any content infringes your copyright, please contact us immediately.

Support

For help with questions, suggestions, or problems, please contact us