Purchasing Power Guarantees for Deferred Payments

Purchasing Power Guarantees for Deferred Payments

Purchasing Power Guarantees for Deferred Payments David Finch* MEASURE INTRODUCED in Finland in May 1955 appears to A be one of the first steps taken by a banking system to introduce, in its pure form, a device that has long been advocated by theoretical economists. Most savings banks in Finland introduced at that time a new form of time deposit for their customers. In future, money could be deposited for one year, and at the end of the year the bank would under- take to credit the account with the amount that the cost of living index indicated was necessary to restore the account's original purchasing power.1 The account would bear 4% per cent interest, 1% P^r cen^ below the prevailing rate on deposits without the purchasing power guarantee. Since this step was taken at a time when there was, in other countries, a rising practical interest in the device, it seems useful to re-examine closely the advantages claimed for such an arrangement and to study the practical problems and fears that have made such experiments rare. The theoretical support among economists for a purchasing power guarantee for deferred payments is most impressive. Marshall in 18862 strongly advocated the use of a standard unit of purchasing power in contracts for deferred payments, and reaffirmed this view in 19II.8 Jevons4 even earlier thought so much of the proposal that he suggested that it be made compulsory, after a short transition period, for uevery money debt of, say, more than three months' standing [to] be varied according to the tabular standard"6 of purchasing power. Keynes6 * Mr. Finch, economist in the Finance Division, is a graduate of the University of Melbourne, Australia, and the London School of Economics. He was formerly a lecturer in the University of Tasmania. 1 The exact provisions are reproduced in Appendix I. 2 In his Reply to the Royal Commission on the Depression of Trade and In- dustry, 1886, reprinted in Official Papers by Alfred Marshall (London, 1926), pp. 9-12. The proposal is also set forth in an article in the Contemporary Re- view, March 1887, reproduced in Memorials of Alfred Marshall (London, 1925), pp. 188-211. 3 In a letter to Irving Fisher, reproduced in Memorials of Alfred Marshall (London, 1925), p. 476. 4 W. Stanley Jevons, Money and the Mechanism of Exchange (New York, 1898), Chap. XXV, "A Tabular Standard of Value," pp. 318-26. (First published in 1875; page references are to the New York edition published in 1898.) 5 Ibid., p. 324. 6 In evidence before the Committee on National Debt and Taxation (Colwyn Committee), Minutes of Evidence (London, 1927), Vol. I, pp. 278 and 287. 1 ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 2 INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND STAFF PAPERS advocated the issue by the U.K. Treasury of "bonds of which the capital and interest would be paid not in a fixed amount of sterling but in such amount of sterling as has a fixed commodity value as indicated by an index number." More recently, the proposal that the U.S. Government should issue a bond whose value would be guaranteed in terms of pur- chasing power was enthusiastically supported by such eminent econo- mists as Milton Friedman,7 Fritz Machlup,8 and Sumner Slichter.9 Economists in some non-English-speaking countries have also sup- ported the concept. In France, Courtin,10 Gael Fain,11 and Sauvy12 have proposed purchasing power clauses of various forms to meet cur- rent French problems. In Latin America, Javier Marquez has urged the widespread use of guaranteed purchasing power bonds to secure addi- tional resources for development.13 In China, S.C. Tsiang14 supported the use of an indexed savings certificate to overcome some of the dis- advantages of the inflation. In financial circles, on the other hand, the weight of opinion has been overwhelmingly against this "artificial" device. Jevons' arguments were rejected by Bagehot.15 Keynes' proposal was dismissed by Sir Otto Niemeyer16 of the Bank of England with the assertion that no one would be interested. More recently, the case made in the United States by some economists before the Patman Subcommittee was attacked vigorously by business economists and in the replies of the Treasury17 and the Coun- cil of Economic Advisers.18 7 Joint Committee on the Economic Report, Monetary Policy and the Manage- ment of the Public Debt (82nd Congress, 2nd Session, Washington, 1952), Replies to Questions ... for the Use of the Subcommittee . (Wright Patman, Chair- man), p. 1105. 8 Ibid, p. 1106. 9 In "We Can Win the Economic 'Cold War/ Too," New York Times Magazine (New York), August 13, 1950, pp. 7, 22r-26, and in later letters and addresses. His proposal began the discussion leading to the examination by the Patman Subcommittee. A thorough theoretical analysis of the proposal with a favorable conclusion is given by Richard Goode in "A Constant-Purchasing-Power Savings Bond," National Tax Journal (Lancaster, Pa.), December 1951, pp. 332-40. 10 According to Le Monde (Paris), May 23, 1954, he proposed the use of the cost of an hour's unskilled labor as an index for loans. 11 La Lutte contre inflation et la stabilisation monetaire (Paris, 1947). A price index deflation is suggested. 12 U Observation Economique (Paris), October 1949, p. 7. The issue of bonds by public utilities denominated in terms of the selling price of their product is ad- vocated. 13 Javier M&rquez, "Bonos de Poder Adquisitivo Constante," El Trimestre Economico (Mexico, D.F.), January-March 1954, pp. 6-43. 14 Economic Review (Shanghai), April 6 and May 10, 1947. "Walter Bagehot, "A New Standard of Value," The Economist (London), November 20, 1875. Reprinted in The Economic Journal (London), Vol. II (1892), pp. 472-77. 16 Committee on National Debt and Taxation, op. cit., p. 633. 17 Joint Committee on the Economic Report, op. cit.t pp. 142-45. 18 Ibid., pp. 888-89. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution PURCHASING POWER GUARANTEES FOR DEFERRED PAYMENTS O The weight of financial opinion has been shown as impressively in the lack of practical application—at least until recently. There are still only a few scattered examples of the use of the device in its "pure form," i.e., using a price index to measure the adjustment needed to assure a contract with stable purchasing power.19 Even before the use of the clause by banks, Finland provided the broadest application. Govern- ment securities with a partial purchasing power guarantee based on price indices have been issued there since 1944. During succeeding years, a range of private securities with similar clauses, which have also been used in some private mortgages, has been issued. In Sweden in 1952 a large cooperative, the Kooperativa Forbundet, issued a bond with a partial guarantee. In the United States there was an early official appli- cation of the index principle in Massachusetts in the "equity bills" of 1742 and the "Massachusetts depreciation notes" of 1780, both based on the aggregate price of a few items.20 An interesting modern applica- tion using a full index number was made in 1925 when the Rand Kardex Company, at the instance of Professor Irving Fisher, issued a 30-year bond with interest and principal linked to the wholesale price index. The U.S. Government in 1946 accepted a contract in which payments were determined by the movements of a cost of living index.21 In Main- land China, time deposits with a guarantee related to an index based on the prices of a few major commodities were allowed during 1950-52. Official proposals for security issues with an index guarantee have been made in Chile and Israel. The device in a form less precise than that which involves the use of a price index has been much more widespread. In many Latin American countries, deposits in domestic banks may be denominated in U.S. dollars, a device intended to have the effect of stabilizing their purchas- ing power. In France the Pinay Loan of 1952, providing repayment guaranteed at a price related to the free market rate of the napoleon, was another variant. This loan was followed in France by issues of semi- governmental corporation bonds which had their purchasing power guaranteed by reference to the average price received for the cor- poration's product. Thus the Coal Corporation issued a bond repay- able at a price related to the wholesale price of coal; railway bonds were related to the price of a third-class railroad ticket for one kilometer; 19 In Appendix I, the details of several of the more important applications are given. 20 W. C. Fisher, "The Tabular Standard in Massachusetts History," Quarterly Journal of Economics (Cambridge, Mass.), Vol. 27 (1912-13), pp. 417-61. 21 The U.S.-Cuba Sugar Agreement of 1946 provided that the price paid by the Commodity Credit Corporation for Cuban sugar should be linked with the monthly indices of the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics. The text is quoted in Arthur Nussbaum, Money in the Law, National and International (Brooklyn, 2nd ed., 1950), p. 305, footnote 32. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 4 INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND STAFF PAPERS and those of the Electricity Board were tied to the price of a kilowatt hour. In Austria there was a similar issue by the electricity authority. In many countries and over periods stretching far back into history, there have been many arrangements tying payments to specific prices. Jevons22 recalled the way in which the colleges of Oxford and Cambridge were obliged by law to lease their lands for corn units, which had the effect over the long period of maintaining the purchasing power of their endowments.

View Full Text

Details

  • File Type
    pdf
  • Upload Time
    -
  • Content Languages
    English
  • Upload User
    Anonymous/Not logged-in
  • File Pages
    22 Page
  • File Size
    -

Download

Channel Download Status
Express Download Enable

Copyright

We respect the copyrights and intellectual property rights of all users. All uploaded documents are either original works of the uploader or authorized works of the rightful owners.

  • Not to be reproduced or distributed without explicit permission.
  • Not used for commercial purposes outside of approved use cases.
  • Not used to infringe on the rights of the original creators.
  • If you believe any content infringes your copyright, please contact us immediately.

Support

For help with questions, suggestions, or problems, please contact us