Draft chapter for the Oxford Handbook of Portuguese Politics, ed. J. Fernandes, P. Magalhaes and A. Costa Pinto. Portuguese Labour Market Governance in Comparative Perspective Alexandre Afonso, Leiden University Abstract. This chapter analyses the core characteristics of labour market governance in Portugal in a comparative perspective, analyzing the interplay of public and private regulation in the setting of wages and employment conditions. The chapter describes the main characteristics of the Portuguese employment model within the European context and how it departs from other Southern European countries, notably when it comes to female and low-skilled employment. The chapter argues that the power relationships that emerged out of the transition to democracy favoured a more liberal employment regime than in Spain, resulting in a lower threshold of unemployment but also higher income inequalities and lower wage protections. The models have tended to converge in recent years, and income inequality in Portugal has diminished. The chapter highlights the high level of female employment since the 1960s, a characteristic that departs significantly from other Southern European countries. It is explained by specific contextual factors, notably the legacy of the colonial war and high rates of emigration. Keywords: Portugal, labour market policies, collective bargaining, employment protection, employment, gender Words: 6557 Introduction Portugal is often bundled within the broader “Southern” or “Mediterranean” model of welfare and employment when it comes to the governance of its labour market (Ferrera 1996; Zartaloudis and Kornelakis 2017). In many ways, Portuguese labour market governance indeed shares many characteristics with Spain, Italy or Greece: high levels of segmentation between “insiders” and “outsiders”, relatively high levels of inequality, the large size of the informal sector, and a reliance on the state to regulate wages and employment rather than on social partners alone, as in Scandinavia. However, it has also departed in significant ways from comparable countries on a number of indicators. While typical shortcomings of Southern European employments models have been the low levels of employment of women and the low- skilled, owing to a catholic tradition and what was often perceived as too restrictive employment protection, Portugal has done remarkably well in the employment of these groups. In 2019 Portugal had the highest rate of women employed in relation to the population in Southern Europe: 75% of Portuguese women between 25 and 64 were employed (on par with the Netherlands or Denmark), compared to 64% in Spain and 56% in Italy (OECD 2020b). Similarly, 70% of Portuguese individuals with below upper secondary education were employed (one of the highest rates in the OECD) compared to 58% in Spain and 52% in Italy. In comparative terms, the Portuguese model of welfare and employment has been described as a “liberal” variant contrasting with the more “protective” Spanish model (Watson 2015, 1). While Spain had higher levels of social and wage protection but also a much higher threshold of unemployment, Portugal, at least in the decades that followed democratization, displayed lower unemployment but also lower wage protection, as well as higher levels of inequality and poverty. The models have converged in the recent decade, with inequality increasing to a greater extent in Spain than in Portugal (Perez and Matsaganis 2019). However, notable differences in unemployment rates have persisted up to now (Bover, García-Perea, and Portugal 2000). For the last 30 years, the average unemployment rate in Portugal has been 8.5%, compared with 16.5% in Spain. At the same time, in 2018 Portuguese median hourly earnings only amounted to 53% of Spanish ones. In this chapter, I outline the main characteristics of the Portuguese model of labour market governance across three dimensions: labour market policies, collective bargaining and labour market outcomes in a comparative perspective. I focus on the development and change of institutions which regulate employment relations: wages, working conditions, working hours, unemployment protection and wage-setting institutions. I first review the characteristics and development of public policies organizing the labour market (employment protection, active labour market policies, skills and education), then outline the main dimensions of the system of industrial relations, and conclude with how these institutions have shaped a number of outcomes such as unemployment, employment rates and inequality. The chapter traces developments from the advent of democracy in 1974 to the movement of liberalization that has taken place in the wake of the Eurozone crisis and up to the support measures implemented during the corona pandemic. The chapter is comparative in nature, highlighting how the Portuguese case resembles but also diverges from other comparable European countries, especially in the Mediterranean or “Southern” cluster composed of Spain, Italy, and Greece (Regini, Pavolini, and Burroni 2021). Context and Emergence of the Portuguese Labor Market Regime A central factor in the emergence of welfare states and labour market regulations in Europe from the late 19th century onwards has been the capacity of organized labour to mobilise and 2 pressure employers and the state to regulate employment relationships (Korpi 1983). In the most developed welfare states or “coordinated economies” (Hall and Soskice 2001), labour is extensively “de-comodified”, that is, an extensive set of limits are introduced in the ability of employers to use labour as a pure commodity, notably through restrictions on the employment of certain types of individuals (e.g children), limits on the ability to fire them, and income alternatives outside the market (unemployment insurance or other benefits) (Esping-Andersen 1990, 21). Just as other late industrialisers such as Spain, Italy or Greece, Portugal was a poor, agricultural society with no meaningful industrial working class at the turn of the 20th century. As such, it did not display the conditions that enabled the emergence of expansive welfare states and cooperative industrial relations that emerged in core European countries in that period. Hence, while elsewhere trade unions were starting to become forces to be reckoned with around 1900, Spain and Portugal “stood completely outside of this pattern of labour political progress” (Crouch 1993, 94). If the first Portuguese trade unions emerged and were legalized in 1891, the labour movement remained weak. When it did gain some clout in the early twentieth century, it was mostly influenced by radical tendencies (e.g anarcho-syndicalism, then Communism in the 1920s) which ruled out any form of class collaboration (Barreto and Naumann 1998, 9). Adversarial industrial relations, fostered by insurgent labour, ideological divisions within the union movement and a repressive state unwilling to share power have been a common feature of industrial relations in Southern Europe. In the Portuguese context, the influence of Communism forged in that period would persist within the trade union movement even after the fall of the dictatorship. Under Antonio de Oliveira Salzar’s corporatist Estado Novo (1933-1974), both employer and trade union organisations became appendixes of the state and were tightly controlled by the regime. Wages, prices and industrial decisions could be subordinated to the regime’s economic policy objectives. On the one hand, the repressive nature of the regime functioned as a tool of wage restraint depriving labour from its power resources: strikes were outlawed and repressed, autonomous unions were abolished, and the legislature was controlled by the regime. One indivator of the weak power of labour was the delay with which Portugal adopted ILO labour conventions regarding safety at work, minimum wages or child labour. For instance, while ILO convention 59 of 1937 defined 15 as the minimum working age, Portugal only ratified it 33 years later. Before 1970, Portuguese legislation allowed 12-year-olds to work (ILO 2019, 66). If we refer back to the idea of de-commodification mentioned above, this shows how commodified labour still was. 3 On the other hand, the regime also constrained capital’s industrial decisions via an elaborate system of licensing: the relocation of plants or investments in machinery required government approval (Baklanoff 1992, 4). Nevertheless, some industrial conflict never vanished, and occasional wildcat strikes were repressed (Barreto and Naumann 1998, 13). In spite of their lack of autonomy, trade unions managed to achieve some improvement for their members. This took place against the background of favourable market developments. In the 1960s economic growth accelerated, and the labour shortage created by the colonial war started in 1961, coupled with large-scale emigration, created the conditions for substantial wage increases and, as will be emphasized later, the entry of large numbers of women in the workforce. On the eve of the 1974 revolution, 36% of the workforce was a union member (Barreto and Naumann 1998, 11). The market-friendly characteristics of the employment model that emerged out of the 1974 revolution were shaped by the nature of the transition to democracy, and especially by the divisions within left-wing forces and the trade union movement. Paradoxically, it was the strong position of the radical left in Portugal which, according to Watson (2015, 44), fostered
Details
-
File Typepdf
-
Upload Time-
-
Content LanguagesEnglish
-
Upload UserAnonymous/Not logged-in
-
File Pages22 Page
-
File Size-