Module 11: Innovation & Patents

Module 11: Innovation & Patents

Module 11: Innovation & Patents Market Organization & Public Policy (Ec 731) George Georgiadis · Technological progress is crucial for improving welfare, but (very) costly. ◦ – How to incentivize firms to innovate? Suppose that a large number of firms engage in Cournot competition. ◦ – We have seen that the equilibrium price will be close to the marginal cost, and firms’ profits close to 0. – Consider a firm’s incentive to engage in costly R&D. – If other firms can imitate a new innovation, then the innovating firm will have little incentive to invest in the first place. – Therefore, a new firm must be guaranteed enough (expect) profits to recoup the R&D cost. Enter: Patents (that provide the innovating firm with a temporary monopoly). ◦ Schumpeter (1943): If one wants to induce firms to undertake R&D, then one must ◦ accept the creation of monopolies as a necessary evil. The Value of Innovation A simple model of process innovation: ◦ – Assume that innovation lowers the (constant) marginal production cost fromc ¯ to c < c¯. – How much would a firm be willing to pay to reduce its marginal cost, given that no other firm will (be allowed to) buy it? 1 Social Planner (First best): She sets price equal to marginal cost; i.e., p =¯c before the innovation, and p = c after. ◦ s u¯ Additional net social surplus p.u of time: v = u D(c)dc ◦ ´ The social planner’s value from innovating is: ◦ c¯ s 1 rt s 1 V = e− v dt = D(c)dc ˆ0 r ˆc Monopoly: Suppose that a firm is in a monopoly situation. ◦ Let ⇧m denote monopoly profit p.u of time. Then: ◦ d⇧ d m = [(p c) D(p)] dc dc − @⇧ dpm @⇧ = m + m = D (pm(c)) @p dc @c − =0 – Application of the Envelope| Theorem{z } . The monopolist’s value from innovating is: ◦ m 1 rt m m V = e− [⇧ (c) ⇧ (¯c)] dt ˆ0 − 1 c¯ d⇧m = dc r ˆ − dc c ✓ ◆ 1 c¯ = D (pm(c)) dc r ˆc m m m s Because p (c) >cand D0 < 0, we have D (p (c)) <D(c) for all c, and hence V <V . ◦ A monopolist has weaker incentives to innovate relative to a social planner. ◦ – Intuitively: Because he sets a higher price, the cost reduction pertains to a smaller number of units. Competition: Suppose that 2 firms engage in Bertrand competition. ◦ 2 – Then p =¯c, and firms earn 0 profits. The firm that obtains new technology with cost c is awarded a patent. ◦ Let pm(c) be the monopoly price when the cost is c. ◦ Case 1: If pm(c) c¯, then we say that the innovation is drastic. ◦ – The innovator then charges p = pm(c), and obtains the entire market. – His value from innovating is V m. Case 2: If pm(c) > c¯, then we say that the innovation is nondrastic. ◦ – Both firms charge p =¯c, and the innovator’s profit p.u of time is ⇧c =(¯c c) D (¯c). − – The value from innovating is 1 V c = (¯c c) D (¯c) r − – Becausec<p ¯ m(c) <pm(c), we have D(¯c) >D(pm(c)) for all c c,so ≥ 1 c¯ 1 c¯ V m = D (pm(c)) dc < D (¯c) dc = V c r ˆc r ˆc s 1 c¯ 1 c¯ c – But D (¯c) <D(c) for all c<c¯,soV = r c D(c)dc > r c D(¯c)dc = V . ´ ´ – Therefore, V c (V s,Vm). 2 Take-aways: ◦ – Even with patents of infinite duration, the innovator does not internalize the entire social surplus from the innovation. – A monopolist has less to gain from innovating than does a competitive firm. Why? Monopoly Threatened By Entry Simple setting with two firms. Initially: ◦ – Firm 1 is a monopolist, produces at marginal costc ¯, and earns profit ⇧m (¯c). – Firm 2 does not currently produce, but is a potential entrant. 3 If only one of the firms has the opportunity to acquire the technology to reduce marginal ◦ cost to c, then we have the same situation as before: – V c >Vm, so innovation is more valuable for the entrant than for the monopolist. Now suppose that a 3rd party generates the innovation, and auctions it to the two firms. ◦ We will see that in this case, the innovation is more valuable for the monopolist than ◦ for the entrant. If firm 1 obtains the innovation, then it remains a monopolist, and earns profit ⇧m (c). ◦ If firm 2 obtains the innovation, then both firms become duopolists. ◦ – Denote the profits of firm 1 and 2 by ⇧d (¯c, c) and ⇧d (c, c¯), respectively. The value of innovation for firm 1 is: ◦ ⇧m (c) ⇧d (¯c, c) V m = − r The value of innovation for firm 2 is: ◦ ⇧d (c, c¯) V c = r Assume that: ⇧m (c) ⇧d (c, c¯)+⇧d (¯c, c). ◦ ≥ – A monopolist earns greater profit than two non-colluding duopolists. Then: V m >Vc. (Opposite from before!) ◦ Because competition reduces profits, the monopolist’s incentive to remain a monopolist ◦ is greater than the entrant’s incentive to become a duopolist. A monopolist may have incentives to obtain property rights on an innovation, even ◦ though he will make no use of it (often referred to as patent shelving). – The only purpose is to prevent an entrant from competing. 4 – Subject of many antitrust cases; generally considered anti-competitive behavior. – In many countries, the patent law includes a compulsory licensing provision (i.e., patent holder is forced to license if he does not utilize the innovation within a specified length of time). Patent Races Insofar, we have considered ◦ 1. the value of innovation in a situation where one firm has monopoly over R&D activities; and 2. the value of innovation when monopoly power is auctioned to a monopolist and a potential entrant. In practice, R&D competition can be likened to a “race” for a patent. ◦ – Multiple firms invest in R&D simultaneously, and whichever firm innovates first, obtains a patent. We will study the so-called “Poisson” patent race. ◦ – Initially, there is a monopolist with costc ¯, and a potential entrant. – The two firms compete in R&D activities, and the firm first to innovate (i.e., obtain a technology with cost c) obtains a patent. At every moment t, each firm i invests in R&D at rate x , and its innovation rate is ◦ i,t h(xi,t)dt, where h0 > 0 >h00. – If firm i invests xi during (t, t + dt), then it incurs cost xidt and its probability of innovating is h(xi,t)dt. – This is called a“Poisson”race, because the probability of innovating during (t, t + dt) is independent of investments at t0 <t. – It follows that each firm’s investment rate will be independent of t. If firm 1 obtains the patent, then the firms earn profits ⇧m (c) and 0, respectively. ◦ 5 If firm 2 obtains the patent, then the firms earn profits ⇧d (¯c, c) and ⇧d (c, c¯), respec- ◦ tively. Assume that: ⇧m (c) ⇧d (c, c¯)+⇧d (¯c, c). ◦ ≥ During an arbitrary interval (t, t + dt), firms 1 and 2 earn profit [⇧m(¯c) x ] dt and ◦ − 1 x dt, respectively. − 2 – With probability h(x1)dt, firm 1 is first to innovate, and the firms will earn dis- m ⇧ (c) x1 − counted profits r and 0, respectively. – With probability h(x2)dt, firm 2 is first to innovate, and the firms will earn dis- ⇧d(¯c,c) ⇧d(c,c¯) counted profits r and r , respectively. – With probability 1 h(x )dt h(x )dt, neither firm innovates during (t, t + dt). − 1 − 2 The value of innovation to firm 1 is ◦ m d m rdt ⇧ (c) ⇧ (¯c, c) V =[⇧(¯c) x ] dt + e− h(x )dt + h(x )dt +(1 h(x )dt h(x )dt) V 1 − 1 1 r 2 r − 1 − 2 1 m ⇧m(c) ⇧d(¯c,c) ⇧ (¯c) x1 + h(x1) + h(x2) = − r r r + h(x1)+h(x2) and for firm 2 d rdt ⇧ (c, c¯) V = x dt + e− h(x ) +(1 h(x )dt h(x )dt) V 2 − 2 2 r − 1 − 2 2 ⇧d(c,c¯) x2 + h(x2) = − r r + h(x1)+h(x2) rdt – Note 1: e− 1 rdt for “small” dt (Taylor expansion) ' − – Note 2: dt2 0 ' A Nash equilibrium is a pair x1⇤,x2⇤ such that xi⇤ maximizes Vi given x⇤ i. ◦ { } − Which firm will have stronger incentives to invest in R&D? ◦ Depends on which of two e↵ects dominates. ◦ 1. Efficiency e↵ect:⇧m (c) ⇧d (c, c¯)+⇧d (¯c, c) suggests that the monopolist has ≥ stronger incentives, and therefore, spends more on R&D. 6 2. Replacement e↵ect: By increasing x1, the monopolist (on expectation) brings the discovery date forward, thus hastening his own replacement. In contrast, the entrant does not forgo a flow profit during the R&D phase, and therefore has stronger incentives. What if we consider the case of a drastic innovation? ◦ – i.e., whichever firm obtains the patent, becomes a monopolist, so ⇧d (c, c¯)=⇧m (c) and ⇧d (¯c, c)=0. Problems: ◦ – Excessive duplication of research – With multiple stages, as the gap between the firm widens, incentives weaken. Welfare Analysis of Patent Protection Overall, economic research in this area is still nascent. ◦ Main issues: ◦ – Optimal patent length? – Optimal degree of patent protection? – Subsidies? (e.g., in the US, tax credits for R&D investments) An example from United States vs. Microsoft Corp: ◦ – Microsoft was accused of becoming a monopoly and engaging in abusive practices, in violation of the Sherman Act.

View Full Text

Details

  • File Type
    pdf
  • Upload Time
    -
  • Content Languages
    English
  • Upload User
    Anonymous/Not logged-in
  • File Pages
    9 Page
  • File Size
    -

Download

Channel Download Status
Express Download Enable

Copyright

We respect the copyrights and intellectual property rights of all users. All uploaded documents are either original works of the uploader or authorized works of the rightful owners.

  • Not to be reproduced or distributed without explicit permission.
  • Not used for commercial purposes outside of approved use cases.
  • Not used to infringe on the rights of the original creators.
  • If you believe any content infringes your copyright, please contact us immediately.

Support

For help with questions, suggestions, or problems, please contact us