Child Marriage, Income Shocks and the Bride Price Tradition

Child Marriage, Income Shocks and the Bride Price Tradition

Selling daughters: Child Marriage, Income Shocks and the Bride Price Tradition Lucia Corno, Alessandra Voena∗ February 16, 2021 Abstract This paper investigates the relationship between child marriage and income shocks in a setting where the bride price - transfer from the groom to the bride's parents at marriage - is customary. First, we develop a dynamic model in which households are exposed to income volatility and have no access to credit markets. If a daughter marries, her household obtains a bride price. In this framework, girls may have a higher probability of marrying early when their parents have higher marginal utility of consumption because of adverse income shocks. Second, we test the responsiveness of child marriage to income fluctuations by exploiting idiosyncratic variation in rainfall over a woman's life cycle, using a survey dataset from rural Tanzania. We find that adverse shocks during teenage years increase the probability of early marriages. Third, we use these empirical results to estimate the parameters of our model and isolate the role of the bride price custom for consumption smoothing. In counterfactual exercises, we show that child marriage bans can have lasting effects on age of marriage even after they are no longer binding and they do so at a limited utility cost to households. Cash transfers, both conditional on avoiding child marriage and unconditional, can reduce early marriages, especially when they target low-income households. ∗We thank Jerome Adda, Marcella Alsan, Oriana Bandiera, Natalie Bau, Monica Costa Dias, Caterina Gennaioli, Veronica Guerrieri, Sylvie Lambert, Eliana La Ferrara, Costas Meghir, Claudia Olivetti, Michelle Tertilt, Marcos Vera Hernandez, Imran Rasul and participants at the following workshops: COSME, Barcelona GSE Summer Forum, SED meetings, EDePo, AEA meetings, and at seminars at Stockholm School of Economics, Bocconi and Queen Mary University for helpful comments. We are grateful to Helene Bie Lilleor and Sofya Krutikova for useful discussion on the Kagera Health Development Survey and to Kalle Hirvonen for the clarification regarding weather data. Simone Lenzu, Alejandra Rodriguez Vega and Alex Weinberg provided outstanding research assistance. This research was partly funded by a Research Grant from the Social Sciences Division at the University of Chicago. Corno: Cattolica University, LEAP, CEPR, EUDN and IFS, [email protected]; Voena: Stanford University, CEPR, NBER, LEAP and BREAD, [email protected]. 1 1 Introduction Child marriage is still a common practice in many countries, especially among girls. World- wide, 700 million women alive today married before turning 18. This phenomenon is especially pronounced in Sub-Saharan Africa and South Asia, where the prevalence is 56% and 42%, respec- tively (UNICEF, 2019).1 The relationship between female early marriage and poor physical and socioeconomic outcomes is well established in the literature. Child marriage is associated with lower educational attainment, lower use of preventive health care services, lower bargaining power within the household, physical abuse and domestic violence (Jensen and Thornton, 2003; Field and Ambrus, 2008; Chari et al., 2017).2 Despite this evidence, little research has examined the important question of why such a practice is still so widespread in many countries and what might be effective policies to reduce it. This paper has two main goals. First, we estimate the responsiveness of child marriage to income fluctuations in a setting where the bride price, a transfer from the groom to the family of the bride at the time of marriage, is customary, in order to understand the mechanisms by which child marriage and income shocks are related. Second, we use these estimates to perform counterfactual simulations to evaluate effective economic policies potentially able reduce the practice. To address the first goal, we start by theoretically exploring the relationship between the probability of child marriage { defined as a formal or informal union in which at least one member gets married before the age of 18 (UNICEF, 2014) { and adverse income shocks in a setting with bride price. We develop a dynamic model in which households face income variability and have no access to credit markets. A daughter may be costly to support, or can contribute to her household's budget through her labor supply or home production. Upon the marriage of a daughter, parents obtain a bride price payment, which depends on her age. In this framework, a negative income shock is associated with an increase in the probability of marriage in the same period, as long as 1Niger (76% ), Central African Republic (68%) and Chad (67%) are among the countries with the highest prevalence (UNICEF, 2019). 2Based on these findings, international organizations have called for "urgent action", arguing that the eradication of child marriage is a necessary step towards improving female human capital accumulation, empowerment and autonomy around the world (UNFPA, 2012; UNICEF, 2014). The elimination of harmful practices is also part of the Sustainable Development Goals 2015-2030, a collection of 17 global goals set by the United Nations General Assembly reflecting the priorities to reduce poverty around the world. 2 the bride price exceeds the daughter's contribution to home production. We test this theoretical prediction using a survey dataset from a region in Tanzania, the Kagera Health Development Survey 1991-2010 (KHDS), which elicited detailed information on bride price payments, and weather data from the NASA Langley Research Center. In particular, we exploit exogenous variation in rainfall to estimate the causal effects of rainfall shocks on the age of marriage. Negative rainfall shocks, measured as the absolute deviation of rainfall from the historical mean at the village level, are associated with sizable declines in household consumption. To examine the relationship between rainfall shocks and the timing of marriage, we match each woman to the community in which she grew up, and reconstruct the patterns of rainfall shocks that she experienced over time. Because marriage migration is prevalent among brides in these communities, we consider these rainfall deviations as idiosyncratic shocks to the village resources relative to the overall marriage market, which encompasses the Kagera region. Hence, we control for year-of-birth fixed effects to account for variation at the level of the marriage market, and for village fixed effects to account for the cross-sectional variation in the timing of marriage across the communities of origin of each woman. We find that girls whose families were hit by a negative rainfall shock in their teenage years have a higher probability of being married by the age of 18. As expected, shocks that occur after that age do not have any statistically significant effect on the likelihood of early marriage. On the contrary, rainfall shocks are not associated with early marriages for boys, but, in line with the fact that men marry later than women on average in the data, we find weak evidence that rainfall shocks in their own communities delay marriage to later ages. By exploiting data on bride price amount, we also show that the relationship between female child marriage and negative income shocks is stronger in villages where bride price payments are typically higher. In line with the idiosyncratic nature of the rainfall shocks, we do not find that these shocks affect the level of bride price paid at the time of marriage. To disentangle the role of bride price as a consumption-smoothing mechanism, we estimate the parameters of our dynamic model by indirect inference, targeting the responsiveness of child mar- riage to resource shocks, the marriage-age profile, and the empirical distribution of consumption. 3 We find that families generally prefer to delay the marriage of their daughters, but that the inabil- ity to borrow or save leads to an age of marriage that is often lower than what optimal from the household's preferences. In this model, a bride price is also crucial for marriage to occur, because daughters are productive in their parents' home. In counterfactual exercises, we find that child marriage bans can have lasting effects on the age of marriage even after they are no longer binding, because marriage rate do not immediately increase once the girls is eligible to marry. Nevertheless, because child marriage is a tool to cope with income volatility, a marriage ban comes with a utility cost, albeit a small one. Other policies, such as unconditional or conditional cash transfers, can be effective at reducing child marriage, especially when they target low-income households. Our paper fits into four main strands of the literature. First, the paper is related to the recent literature looking at the effect of income shock on marriage decisions. Hoogeveen, Van der Klaauw and Van Lomwel (2011) investigate the effect of economic conditions on marriage's choices among a small sample of Zimbabwean smallholder farmers in rural areas. They find that the marriage rate for daughters is higher when households experience changes in their livestock, but not when aggregate rainfall is low. Relative to this paper, we focus on the effect of exogenous income shocks and we have the advantage of exploiting a larger sample that allows us to identify the elasticity of child marriage to income shocks, which informs then our structural estimates. Corno, Hildebrandt and Voena (2020) study the impact of aggregate rainfall shocks on child marriage in Sub-Saharan Africa and India and show an opposite effect of the shocks on the early marriage hazard in the two regions: in Africa, they increase the hazard into early marriage, while in India, they decrease it. This differential response is explained by differences in the direction of traditional marriage payments in each region, with bride price being prevalent in Africa and dowry in India. Compared to this study we rely on one of the very few surveys that elicits information on bride price amount.

View Full Text

Details

  • File Type
    pdf
  • Upload Time
    -
  • Content Languages
    English
  • Upload User
    Anonymous/Not logged-in
  • File Pages
    56 Page
  • File Size
    -

Download

Channel Download Status
Express Download Enable

Copyright

We respect the copyrights and intellectual property rights of all users. All uploaded documents are either original works of the uploader or authorized works of the rightful owners.

  • Not to be reproduced or distributed without explicit permission.
  • Not used for commercial purposes outside of approved use cases.
  • Not used to infringe on the rights of the original creators.
  • If you believe any content infringes your copyright, please contact us immediately.

Support

For help with questions, suggestions, or problems, please contact us