Becker Meets Kyle: Insider Trading and Legal Risk

Becker Meets Kyle: Insider Trading and Legal Risk

Becker Meets Kyle: Insider Trading and Legal Risk Abstract Do illegal insiders internalize legal risk? We answer this question with hand-collected data from 530 SEC investigations. Using two plausibly exogenous shocks to expected penalties, we show that insiders trade less aggressively, relatively earlier, and concentrate on tips of greater value when facing higher risk. The results match the predictions of a model in which an insider internalizes his trades’ impact on both prices and the likelihood of prosecution, and anticipates penalties in proportion to trade profits. Our findings lend support to the effectiveness of U.S. regulations’ deterrence and the long-standing hypothesis that insider trading enforcement could hamper price informativeness. This Version: November 1, 2020 A large literature in economics and finance has argued that private information gets transmitted into asset prices through trading activity of informed investors. The canonical representation of this process is the Kyle (1985) model: Knowing the value of an asset, and internalizing price impact, an informed trader cautiously spreads his trades over time. However, the literature largely abstracts from how the information is produced and how this process affects trading and prices. In the Grossman–Stiglitz (1980) tradition, a trader becomes informed by conducting costly fundamental research. In practice, private information can also be obtained differently, in breach of a fiduciary duty, thus exposing regular investors to legal risk. Do illegally informed traders rationally internalize legal risks, as in Becker (1968)? Does this process get reflected in their trades and asset prices? These questions deserve formal study given their importance for market efficiency and welfare (Ausubel (1990); Fishman and Hagerty (1992); Leland (1992)), capital formation (Manove (1989); Easley and O’Hara (2004)), as well as for better understanding of the insider trading regulation and detection infrastructure (DeMarzo et al. (1998)). In this paper, we aim to contribute to this research in three ways. First, we manually collect data from 530 illegal trading investigations, prosecuted by the U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC), on individual trades and the resulting legal outcomes. We characterize over 6,500 trades in 975 firms from 1995 to 2018, representing a fairly large universe of assets and market conditions. We examine in depth the information sets, timing, quantity traded, and penalties of illegal insiders. To our knowledge, a study with such scope has never been undertaken. Most important, the quality and the granular aspect of our data allows us to overcome a formidable identification challenge: neither private information nor legal risks are readily observable. Second, informed by our empirical facts, we develop a stylized equilibrium framework of informed trading featuring an insider who internalizes his own trades’ impact on prices, the probability of being prosecuted by a regulator, and the conditional value of a legal fine. The model allows us to benchmark the impact of the likelihood or severity of legal penalties on trading strategies. Third, we exploit two plausibly exogenous sources of variation in legal risk exposure to test the models’ predictions. Controlling for individual-level behavioral predictors, we provide strong evidence that legal risk influences insiders’ trading behavior. In Section 1, we provide a detailed characterization of illegal insider trading, from the transmis- sion of the private tip to the resolution of legal penalties. We highlight a few robust trends that 1 later inform our modeling choices. First, insider tips contain economically powerful information connected to specific corporate announcements. For example, the average stock price change from receiving the tip to the public release is 44.26% for mergers and acquisitions (M&A) and 17.78% for earnings. Second, insiders trade more than once but do not trade continuously. While the distribu- tion of trading frequency is highly skewed, over a median horizon of two weeks, the median insider trader places two trades. Third, consistent with the prevailing legal framework, we observe a strong association between dollar trading profits and pecuniary penalties. The average and median profit values per trader are $757,127 and $44,318, respectively. For pecuniary penalties, the corresponding values are $2.85 million and $200,000. In general, conceptualizing the economic links between insiders’ actions and the regulatory framework from the data alone is challenging without a proper benchmark. In Section 2,webuild on seminal insights by Becker and Kyle, and develop a model in which the equilibrium actions of a privately informed trader, a competitive market maker, and a regulator are jointly determined. The model features two periods to capture the insider’s intertemporal concerns in the simplest fashion. A fixed trading cost captures factors, such as the opportunity and monitoring costs of agents. The market maker observes the aggregate order flow and sets a clearing price to break even. The most significant contrast with conventional analyses is that, apart from an adverse realization of uninformed traders’ order flow, the insider is concerned with the regulator’s prosecution methods and penalties. Our setting considers exogenous detection via whistleblowers with first-hand knowledge, and endogenous proactive screening of abnormal order flow. If the prosecution is successful, penalties are proportional to the realized profits. In the early period, the insider trades guided by the private tip; in the late period, he incorporates the price movement and the updated belief of whether early period transactions raised a red flag to the regulator. We analyze the impact of legal risk on the insider’s behavior by considering changes in either the severity of the penalties or the probability of successful prosecution. The equilibrium’s comparative statics yield three predictions: Following an increase in the expected legal punishment, the insider (1) trades smaller quantities, (2) reduces the frequency of market visits, and (3) trades relatively earlier. The intuition behind the results is that the legal threat, first, acts as a deterrent and incentivizes more cautious trading volume; second, it increases the range of scenarios in which 2 the insider decides not to revisit the market as the expected incremental benefit is more likely to fall below the opportunity cost. Third, it induces a smoother trade pattern across periods to reduce the probability of prosecution—absent legal risk, as in the Kyle model, the insider trades more intensely in the late period. We exploit our insider trading database to empirically match these strategic dimensions using trade size, the incidence of trade splitting over time, and a time-weighted average of informed trade volume. To test these predictions, in Section 3, we propose two quasi-natural experiments that exploit plausibly exogenous variation in legal risk specific to insider trading. The first one is the 2014 U.S. Court of Appeals for the Second Circuit ruling on United States v. Newman and Chiasson (13-1837-cr(L)), which significantly narrowed the application of insider trading laws, and was subse- quently used as a precedent to redeem several allegedly guilty individuals. We argue that this ruling constitutes a negative shock to legal risk across all jurisdictions. The second experiment considers the impact of Preet Bharara, the U.S. Attorney of the Southern District of New York (SDNY), who earned the reputation of a “crusader” prosecutor. Given that his employment spell was ex ante uncertain, we regard his 2009–2013 tenure as a positive shock to legal risk for traders prosecuted by SDNY. In our view, considering both shocks is appealing due to complementarities regarding the direction of the impact, and the ability to induce an economically meaningful time-series and cross-sectional variation in legal risk. Our tests are based on a regression design in which each dependent variable represents a specific strategic dimension. We also include controls concerning trade activity, proxies for the model parameters, and a host of fixed effects accounting for event type, court, and the individual trader. The results from both tests indicate that, first, insiders’ strategies respond to the shocks in a meaningful manner, economically and statistically; second, their qualitative responses correspond well to our theoretical predictions (see, Section 4). Following the Newman shock, the average trader becomes less cautious, increasing quantities and trading intensity closer to the public release time. Conversely, traders within the SDNY jurisdiction significantly reduce their trade aggressiveness during the Bharara’s reign. The impact on trade splitting over time manifests itself through an intensive margin, that is, through the length of the trading horizon, rather than through the binary decision of whether to trade on a single date or not. 3 We next explore the link between trading strategies and legal risk by exploiting cross-sectional attributes of the investigations. We note three following insights. First, the model’s predictions seem to capture better the interaction among market participants around M&A events rather than earnings. We argue that since M&A announcements tend to coincide with times of a relatively normal trading activity—rather than predictably high volume, as before earnings—insiders could be more sensitive not to leave traces for the regulator to follow upon.

View Full Text

Details

  • File Type
    pdf
  • Upload Time
    -
  • Content Languages
    English
  • Upload User
    Anonymous/Not logged-in
  • File Pages
    61 Page
  • File Size
    -

Download

Channel Download Status
Express Download Enable

Copyright

We respect the copyrights and intellectual property rights of all users. All uploaded documents are either original works of the uploader or authorized works of the rightful owners.

  • Not to be reproduced or distributed without explicit permission.
  • Not used for commercial purposes outside of approved use cases.
  • Not used to infringe on the rights of the original creators.
  • If you believe any content infringes your copyright, please contact us immediately.

Support

For help with questions, suggestions, or problems, please contact us