DPRIETI Discussion Paper Series 20-E-018 The Political-Economy Trilemma AIZENMAN, Joshua University of Southern California and NBER ITO, Hiroyuki RIETI The Research Institute of Economy, Trade and Industry https://www.rieti.go.jp/en/ RIETI Discussion Paper Series 20-E-018 March 2020 The Political-Economy Trilemma1 Joshua Aizenman University of Southern California and NBER Hiro Ito Portland State University Research Institute of Economy, Trade and Industry Abstract This paper investigates the political-economy trilemma: policy makers face a trade-off of choosing two out of three policy goals or governance styles, namely, (hyper-)globalization, national sovereignty, and democracy. We develop a set of indexes that measure the extent of attainment of the three factors for 139 countries in the period of 1975-2016. Using these indexes, we examine the validity of the hypothesis of the political-economy trilemma by testing whether the three trilemma variables are linearly related. We find that, for industrialized countries, there is a linear relationship between globalization and national sovereignty (i.e., a dilemma), and that for developing countries, all three indexes are linearly correlated (i.e., a trilemma). We also investigate whether and how three political-economic factors affect the degree of political and financial stability. The results indicate that more democratic industrialized countries tend to experience more political instability, while developing countries tend to be able to stabilize their politics if they are more democratic. The lower level of national sovereignty an industrialized country attains, the more stable its political situation tends to be, while a higher level of sovereignty helps a developing country to stabilize its politics. Globalization brings about political stability for both groups of countries. Furthermore, more globalized countries, whether industrial or developing, tend to experience more financial stability. Keywords: Impossible trinity; globalization; financial crisis. JEL Classification Nos. F36, F41, F51. The RIETI Discussion Paper Series aims at widely disseminating research results in the form of professional papers, with the goal of stimulating lively discussion. The views expressed in the papers are solely those of the author(s), and neither represent those of the organization(s) to which the author(s) belong(s) nor the Research Institute of Economy, Trade and Industry. 1 This paper was conceived when Ito was visiting RIETI as a visiting fellow. The authors are grateful for helpful comments and suggestions by Discussion Paper seminar participants at RIETI. 1. Introduction In the international macroeconomics literature, the complexity of open macro policy management is viewed through the lens of the “open economy trilemma.” This hypothesis, advanced by Mundell and Fleming in the 1960s, states that a country may simultaneously choose any two, but not all, of the three goals of monetary policy independence, exchange rate stability, and financial market openness to the full extent.1 Figure 1 (a) is a textbook graphical presentation of the policy trade-offs associated with this trilemma. Each of the three sides – representing monetary independence, exchange rate stability, and financial integration – depicts a potentially desirable goal, yet it is not possible to be simultaneously on all three sides of the triangle. The top vertex – labeled “floating exchange rate regime” – is associated with monetary policy autonomy and open financial markets, but not exchange rate stability, the preferred choice of some industrialized countries such as Australia, Canada, Japan, and New Zealand. This hypothesis has been widely taught, explaining the constraints policymakers face in an open economy setting. These constraints imply policy tradeoffs imposed by arbitrage forces linking the interest rates of nations’ bonds in the presence of capital mobility.2 Dani Rodrik (2000) postulated the presence of international political-economy trilemma associated with globalization. That is, policy makers face a trade-off of choosing two out of three policy goals or governance -- globalization, national sovereignty, and democracy. A continuous version of the globalization trilemma states that if a country increases its globalization, it has to give up either some democracy or some national sovereignty.3 The more a country opens up and 1 See Mundell (1960), Fleming (1961), and Boughton (2000) for an overview of the history of the open economy Trilemma. 2 See Shambaugh (2004), Obstfeld, et al. (2005), Aizenman, et al. (2013), Obstfeld (2015) for various tests of the open economy Trilemma. 3 Or, more strictly speaking, the weighted sum of democracy and national sovereignty must fall. 1 integrates itself to the world, the more directly it faces the impact of market mechanism. Trade and financial liberalization may help private markets to allocate economic resources more efficiently, which may facilitate economic growth and development (a conjecture dubbed as “the Washington consensus” associated with globalization). Such globalization trend constrains domestic economic policy making, shrinking the domestic policy space.4 This is in line with Friedman (1999), “your economy grows and your politics shrinks.” In such a nation state, the process of integration with the globalized world may increase the role of more independent technocrats’ taking over the role of policy making, diminishing the role of “mass politics.” In Friedman’s words, instead of wearing different political “jackets” or “suits,” such a country wears the “Golden Straitjacket,” a choice depicted by the top vertex of the triangle in Figure 1 (b). In a Golden Straitjacket state, policy making often does not reflect the political will of the majority of the voters. For example, regulators in a capital-abundant country may try to push forward trade liberalization while their democratic voters oppose to it because they know trade liberalization could make them worse-off. Thus, when globalization and national sovereignty are pursued, democracy will be constrained. A nation state can pursue both hyper-globalization and democracy, though it would have to give up on its state sovereignty, possibly in the context of federalism, delegating external issues dealing with globalization to the federal center. For example, the U.S. states follow democratic decisions in their internal regulations, while delegating external decisions to the federal levels, diluting their own sovereignty. Hence, countries that pursue deeper international economic integration guided by democratic votes may 4 That means, for example, ruling and opposition parties would barely differ from each other and argue only over minor differences instead of debating grand issues. 2 converge towards “global federalism,” exemplified by the European Union (EU) and the U.S., depicted by the right vertex of the triangle in Figure 1 (b). Alternatively, a democratic state may decide to curtail globalism and implement protectionist measures if its majority voters prefer so. This policy configuration constrains the domestic impact of global interests. This situation is exemplified by the Bretton Woods system, where member states were allowed to implement capital controls, and various trade barriers existed despite a series of trade liberalization efforts under the regime of the General Agreements on Tariffs and Trade (GATT). Countries give up the opportunity to integrate themselves to the world markets while they pursue full extents of national sovereignty and democracy, exemplified by the right vertex of the triangle in Figure 1 (b). These tradeoffs were articulated by Rodrik as a political-economy trilemma, where at most only two of the following triplets of policy dimensions can be achieved: globalization, national sovereignty, and democracy. Until recently, the framing of this trilemma was mostly done as a binary choice between the three policy goals. Yes, in practice, one expects the presence more continuous tradeoffs.5 When it comes to international political-economy trilemma, to our knowledge, no studies have quantitatively tested the validity of the tradeoff among the three political-economic variables. This is one of the primary focus of this paper. We begin by constructing a set of the indexes, each one of which measures the extent of attainment of the three political-economic factors that represent international policy goals or orientation: globalization, national sovereignty, and democracy. 5 Aizenman, et al. (2010, 2013), Ito and Kawai (2012, 2014), and Aizenman and Sengupta (2013) create continuous indexes for the three policy goals of the open economy trilemma, testing and overall confirming the validity of a continuous version of Mundell-Fleming’s hypothesis. Studies that test a binary choice hypothesis include Shambaugh (2004), Obstfeld, et al. (2005), Obstfeld (2015), Han and Wei (2018). 3 These indexes, available for 139 countries in the last four decades, show that industrialized and developing countries have gone through different paths of development in the pursuit of three policy choices and orientation. We show countries’ international political-economic policy combinations has developed with much variance over the sample time of 1975-2016 and across countries. Our three indexes suggest that in the last four decades, industrialized countries have faced a dilemma between globalization and national sovereignty while these countries maintained overall high and stable levels of democratization.
Details
-
File Typepdf
-
Upload Time-
-
Content LanguagesEnglish
-
Upload UserAnonymous/Not logged-in
-
File Pages45 Page
-
File Size-