Gendered Labour Markets and Capitalist Accumulation

Gendered Labour Markets and Capitalist Accumulation

For Japanese Political Economy Gendered labour markets and capitalist accumulation Jayati Ghosh Abstract Gender relations affect economic processes, especially macroeconomic patterns and accumulation trajectories, so capitalism relies on gender construction of societies to further its expansion. For example, changes in women’s involvement in paid and unpaid work impacts the extent to which the unpaid care economy subsidises the formal economy. Failure to recognise this leads to misleading estimates of aggregate labour productivity and its change over time. Similarly, ignoring the gender distribution of cross- border migration can lead to wrong expectations about the patterns of remittance flows during business cycles in the receiving country. Keywords Gender, development, women’s work, migration Article Economics as a discipline has been remarkably resistant to incorporating gender perspectives. This has been most evidently so in mainstream economic analysis, in which consumers and producers are treated as homogenous or identical entities with preferences and behavioural tendencies that fit into the identikit standard of the utility maximising individual. But it has also permeated many heterodox approaches, which operate on the basis of classification into groups like classes but still ignore the effects of gender differentiation within these classes or groups and their economic impacts. This has affected the understanding of macroeconomic processes, which are generally seen to operate at a “supra-gender” level. This is unfortunate because gender has been a crucial element in determining how many economic processes play out in particular capitalist contexts, and in creating the basis for particular trajectories of accumulation. In this article I will consider two ways in which different social constructions of gender relations affect macro-economic processes in particular: the nature of labour supply and changing work force participation; and the implications of gendered migration patterns. Women as workers One of the enduring myths about capitalism that continues to be perpetuated in mainstream economic textbooks and other economic pedagogy is that labour supply is somehow exogenous to the economic system. The supply of labour is typically assumed (especially in standard growth theories) to be determined by the rate of population growth, which in turn is also seen as “outside” the economic system rather than in interaction with it.1 The reality is of course very different: the supply of paid labour has 1 Contributions such as those of James Heintz in this issue provide a welcome counterpoint to this, emphasising the endogenous nature of fertility and its links with economic processes and social policies. been very much a result of economic processes, not something extraneous to it. Throughout its history, capitalism has proved adept at causing patterns of labour supply to change in accordance with demand. Migration – whether of slaves, indentured labour or free workers – has been instrumental in this regard. The use of child labour similarly has been sanctioned and encouraged or disapproved and suppressed in varying economic conditions. But nowhere has this particular capacity of capitalism to generate its own labour been more evident than in the case of female labour. Women have been part of the working class since the beginning of capitalism, even when they have not been widely acknowledged as workers in their own right. Even when they are not paid workers, their often unacknowledged and unpaid contribution to social reproduction as well as to many economic activities has always been absolutely essential for the functioning of the system. All women are usually workers, whether or not they are defined or recognised as such. In all societies, and particularly in developing countries, there remain essential but usually unpaid activities (such as cooking, cleaning and other housework, provisioning of basic household needs, child care, care of the sick and the elderly, as well as community-based activities), which are largely seen as the responsibility of the women. This pattern of unpaid work tends to exist even when women are engaged in outside work for an income, whether as wage workers or self- employed workers. These processes are also integral to capitalism: the production of both use values and exchange values by women is essential for the accumulation process. In contemporary capitalism, this integration of women’s work in both paid and unpaid form has also become an essential means of stabilising economic systems through downturns, when the costs of recessions and/or austerity policies are passed onto to unpaid labour within families. If anything, this reliance has become even more marked in recent years. This in turn means that it is impossible to understand women’s work without situating it in the specific trajectory of capitalism in that society, and that issues relating to women’s work and employment are qualitatively different from those of men workers. Just increasing paid employment does not always mean an improvement in the conditions of women workers. Women from poor families who are also engaged in outside work usually cannot afford to hire others to perform these tasks, so most often these are passed on to young girls and elderly women within the household or become a “double burden” of work for such women (Elson 1995). These outcomes are critically affected by social relationships as well as economic policies and processes, which determine whether or not increased labour market activity by women is associated with genuine improvements in their economic circumstances. The recognised work participation rates of women as described by official statistics may not really be reliable indicators of the productive contributions of women, which are not just unpaid but also socially unrecognised. This is true of not just social reproduction, but other economic activity where women’s work is rendered invisible by social perceptions. As a result, it could be argued that the women’s work participation rate can be taken as one of the proxy indicators of women’s overall status in society and of gender empowerment: in addition to the income that derives from paid employment, the engagement of women in such work adds to their social status. The productive contribution of women is typically less recognised in societies where women are engaged mostly in unpaid work and thereby undervalued in general. The significance of the unpaid-paid continuum in women’s work is also evident in segmented labour markets and working conditions. Simply put, where there is a large amount of unpaid work that is performed in a society, and where the bulk of that is performed by women, the participation of women even in paid activities tends to be much more disadvantaged. Since the unpaid labour performed by women is not remunerated – and often not even socially recognised – it is easier for society to undervalue such work in general, and particularly the types of care work and related activities that are typically performed within families. And this in turn leads to lower wages and worse working conditions, especially when many of the paid workers involved in such activities are also women. The very existence of the continuum therefore affects not only the bargaining power of women workers, but also social attitudes to them and to their work, and indeed their own reservation wages and self-perception. The gender division of work is not usually fixed over time in any particular society but tends to be flexible, changing according to the need to preserve not just male power over women but also to ensure the greater economic exploitation of women to suit the needs of capital as required by particular accumulation trajectories. Segmented labour markets have major effects of depressing women’s wages and allowing for even greater extraction of surplus value from their work. There are many strategies for increasing working hours and reducing wages of women, which contribute to increases in both absolute and relative surplus value. Piece rate work is a significant instrument for this, particularly because it also combines other advantages such as reducing the need for supervision. But also the very possibility of extracting significant amounts of unpaid work from women enables the subsidisation of “formal” economic activities. This use of patriarchal social relations then becomes fundamental to the accumulation process itself, which actually requires the continuing impoverishment of certain sections for its very success. It has generally been accepted that capitalist industrialisation and economic development tend to be associated with rising paid work participation of women. The literature of the mid 20th century tended to suggest a U-shaped curve of work participation of women as per capita incomes increase, with high work participation of women in subsistence activities at lower levels of development, followed by a decline in early phases of industrialisation as factory jobs went primarily to men and the “male breadwinner model” got further entrenched, followed by renewed increases in women’s employment rates at higher levels of per capita income because of increased shares of service activities, accompanied by demographic changes like falling fertility rates and rising education levels. The increasing paid work participation of women not only involved an increase in “labour supply” for the market economy, but also contributed to demand for that

View Full Text

Details

  • File Type
    pdf
  • Upload Time
    -
  • Content Languages
    English
  • Upload User
    Anonymous/Not logged-in
  • File Pages
    15 Page
  • File Size
    -

Download

Channel Download Status
Express Download Enable

Copyright

We respect the copyrights and intellectual property rights of all users. All uploaded documents are either original works of the uploader or authorized works of the rightful owners.

  • Not to be reproduced or distributed without explicit permission.
  • Not used for commercial purposes outside of approved use cases.
  • Not used to infringe on the rights of the original creators.
  • If you believe any content infringes your copyright, please contact us immediately.

Support

For help with questions, suggestions, or problems, please contact us