Labour Economics Introduction: Some Preliminaries

Labour Economics Introduction: Some Preliminaries

<p> Labour Economics Introduction: Some Preliminaries</p><p>- Objectives of Labour Economics: </p><p>- To explain and evaluate labour market outcomes. </p><p>- Labour market outcomes?</p><p>- Compensation, wages, benefits, pay structure (price variables)</p><p>- Employment, unemployment, skill composition, types of jobs, hours worked (quantity variables)</p><p>- Other? union status; hiring and promotion practices; work rules; form, nature & length of contracts etc.</p><p>- Outcomes reflect the interplay of:</p><p>(1) decisions of buyers and sellers of labour services; </p><p>(2) institutions; and </p><p>(3) government.</p><p>1 - Role of Markets:</p><p>- Market economies: decision-making is largely decentralized.</p><p>-Decision makers: - individual buyers and sellers.</p><p> i.e. employers and employees (workers).</p><p>- Millions of workers are sorted into millions of jobs; thousands of wage rates.</p><p>- Wages, job matches, contract provisions reflect interaction of employers and workers.</p><p>- simple contracts: wage-hours provisions</p><p>- complex: contracts for long-term matches (wage progression, career paths, pensions and benefits)</p><p>- Explaining this process and its consequences is a major task of labour economics.</p><p>2 - Role of Institutions and Centralization:</p><p>- Main institutions: unions, professional associations and, in some countries, employer organizations.</p><p>- North American labour markets are among the most decentralized in the developed world. </p><p>- large non-union sectors</p><p>- decentralized bargaining within the unionized sector common.</p><p>- Many developed countries: more centralization</p><p>- union coverage higher</p><p>- bargaining often more centralized: industry or even economy-wide bargaining may occur.</p><p>- models and approaches needed for these arrangements too. </p><p>3 - Role of Government in Labour Markets:</p><p>- Markets, individual and union contracts are important but:</p><p>- they are highly regulated by government</p><p>- affected by many government programs.</p><p>- governments can be major employers. </p><p>- Studying the effects of government a key task.</p><p>- Government intervention in labour markets (Canada):</p><p>- Employment/Labour standards legislation (mainly provincial)</p><p>- Minimum wages - Minimum overtime premia - Maximum hours - Minimum vacation pay - Working age - Notice of layoff requirements - Maternity leave - Equal pay and pay equity - Health and safety regulation.</p><p>- Collective bargaining legislation (mainly Provincial) - regulates collective bargaining, union formation, strike/lockout rules.</p><p>- Public education and training programs. - helps determine workforce skill levels.</p><p>4 - Income Maintenance programs: - Workers' compensation (Provincial) - (Un)Employment insurance (Federal) - Social assistance or welfare (Provincial) - Public pension plans (Federal).</p><p>- Taxation: - income taxes affect sellers decisions - payroll taxes affect buyers decisions.</p><p>- Government as an employer (roughly 20% of employment)</p><p>- Public administration, health, education, social services, local government services, transportation, utilities all have significant public sector employment. </p><p>- More centralized: dominant employer, high unionization.</p><p>- Other countries?</p><p>- government involvement varies substantially</p><p>- more direct role in wage determination in some countries.</p><p>- active labour market policies in Sweden</p><p>- United States more laissez faire than Canada. </p><p>5 - The (micro) economic approach:</p><p>- Decision makers are assumed to be rational and self-interested. </p><p>- Implication: decisions are made based on a comparison of its benefits and costs. </p><p>- Best decision changes when factors determining the benefits and costs of the decision change. </p><p>- This approach underlies the models covered in the course. </p><p>- Is this realistic?</p><p>- Are people really like rational calculating machines?</p><p>- What about role of custom/tradition, altruism, notions of fairness in affecting decisions? Are these inconsistent with rationality?</p><p>- “Models” – simplification implied but hopefully captures something important. </p><p>- simplification: manageable, ignore unessential detail. </p><p>- Ultimate test? do the models make predictions that fit the data.</p><p>- Other possible approaches?</p><p>- Descriptive approaches: describe actual arrangements, their evolution. (Institutional economics; sociological approaches) </p><p>- Group behavior e.g. classes and conflict (Marxian approaches, Radical economics)</p><p>- Behavioral economics and psychological approaches.</p><p>6 - Some current issues in labour economics:</p><p>- Is current US unemployment and low employment structural or cyclical?</p><p>- Long-term unemployment: what are its long-term consequences?</p><p>- Aging populations and the workforce: implications? policies?</p><p>- New technologies and labour markets: polarization? what will people do? does AI mean no good jobs?</p><p>-Trade with China and India: what does it do to Canadian labour markets? </p><p>- Declining unionization: are private sector unions doomed? </p><p>- Inequality trends : </p><p>- why have the very rich gotten so much richer?</p><p>- what is happening to labour’s share of national income?</p><p>- Are high minimum wage rates a good idea?</p><p>- Can governments create jobs or do they just change the mix of jobs? </p><p>7 Data on Labour Market Outcomes: Major Sources</p><p>- Labour economics is “data intensive”.</p><p>- Good starting points:</p><p>Statistics Canada Web site: http://www.statcan.gc.ca</p><p>CANSIM Database (link off Statistics Canada’s main page): time series.</p><p>Lakehead library site: Data and Statistics (Government Info/Data), access to a variety of data sources. </p><p>See data source links on course website. </p><p>(1) Labour Force Survey:</p><p>- Monthly. See Labour Force Information Cat. 71-001. </p><p>- See course website for link to the latest release. </p><p>- Survey of roughly 62,000 households.</p><p>- Main source of data on: - Employment - Unemployment</p><p>- See questionnaire (in Guide to the Labour Force on website). Data includes:</p><p>- Hours of work - Industry - Occupation - Job tenure - Time unemployed - Reason last job ended, etc.</p><p>8 - Wage, union status and additional job data since 1997.</p><p>- Also provides information on worker characteristics. - Age, sex, education - Province, region.</p><p>- These can be cross-referenced with labour market outcomes.</p><p>- Historical LFS data.</p><p>- LFS has existed since 1946 (but major revisions).</p><p>- Labour Force Historical Review extensive tables for data back to 1976. (Access via Library webpage: Government Info/Data link then use “Equinox” or ODESI)</p><p>- Older data: Historical Labour Force Statistics (paper – Library) Historical Statistics of Canada (see below).</p><p>(2) Survey of Employment, Payrolls and Hours (SEPH)</p><p>- Monthly. See: Employment, Hours and Earnings Cat. 72-002</p><p>- Employer data: mix of administrative (tax data) and employer survey data.</p><p>- Data reported by detailed industry and province. - Number of employees - Hours of work - Weekly and hourly wages and salaries.</p><p>9 (3) Census:</p><p>- Every 5 years (since 1961 every 10 before that back to 1871).</p><p>- Wage and salary income, occupation and industry employment.</p><p>- Good personal and family characteristic data.</p><p>- Widely used in studies of wage differences and inequality. </p><p>- 2011 results are just being released ("National Household Survey")</p><p>(4) Survey of Labour and Income Dynamics:</p><p>- Predecessor: Survey of Consumer Finances</p><p>- A panel survey: follows same people over time. </p><p>- Annual data on incomes, poverty, inequality: Income in Canada </p><p>- Has a Statistics Canada page (search “Income in Canada”) </p><p>- Some tables with income, poverty data back to 1976. </p><p>(5) Historical Sources for Canada</p><p>Historical Statistics of Canada now online: (http://www.statcan.ca/english/freepub/11-516-XIE/sectiona/toc.htm)</p><p>CANSIM (see above) – has some historical data. </p><p>10 (6) U.S. Data:</p><p>- Data from the U.S. counterparts of the Labour Force Survey (Current Population Survey) and SEPH are reported in:</p><p>Employment and Earnings (paper) U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS).</p><p>- BLS website: http://stats.bls.gov/ (data available free)</p><p>- Federal Reserve Economic Data (FRED) website: http://research.stlouisfed.org/fred2/</p><p>- many US and some international data series (electronic)</p><p>(7) International data</p><p>European Union (EUROSTAT): http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu</p><p>International Labor Organization (http://laborsta.ilo.org/)</p><p>OECD (http://stats.oecd.org/)</p><p>Bureau of Labor Statistics: Foreign Labor Stats Page http://stats.bls.gov/fls/home.htm</p><p>11 Real and Nominal Wages </p><p>- In economic models the wage (compensation) variable is usually a measure of the real wage (real compensation).</p><p>Real wage = the wage adjusted for changes in the price level over time. </p><p> e.g., </p><p> labour supply: workers likely care about what their wages will buy, i.e. compared to the prices of consumer goods. </p><p> labour demand: employers care about how the wage paid compares to the price of the product produced.</p><p>Measuring the Real Wage:</p><p>- Nominal wage data: wage in actual dollars</p><p>Retail worker in 1966: $1.00 hour</p><p>Retail worker in 2013: $10.25 hour</p><p>- These figures are not comparable over time.</p><p>- Inflation adjustment required.</p><p>- Real Wage: - nominal wage adjusted for changes in the price level.</p><p>- constant dollar wage, i.e., wage in terms of a base year.</p><p>12 - Calculating the real wage</p><p>(1) Obtain a relevant price index:</p><p>Consumer Price Index (Base year 2002) June 1966 17.5 June 2013 123.0</p><p>- Base year? year in which the index equals 100</p><p>- Prices in 2013 were more than 7 times higher (123/17.5) than in 1966. </p><p>(2) Convert the nominal wage data into CPI Base Year (2002) dollars:</p><p>Real Wage = (Nominal Wage) x (100/Price Index)</p><p>1966 $1.00 x (100/17.5) = $5.71 2013 $10.25 x (100/123.0)= $8.33</p><p>What if you want the real wage in 2013 dollars?</p><p>Real wage in = (Nominal wage) x (Price index in 2013) 2013 dollars (Price index)</p><p>- where the price index has 2002 as its base.</p><p>- so 1966 wage of $1 is worth $7.03 in 2013 dollars ($1x 123.0/17.5)</p><p>13 Measuring Economic Relationships: Ordinary Least Squares Regression </p><p>- References: see Ch. 1, Appendix of Benjamin, Gunderson, Lemieux & Riddell. </p><p>- Concerned with:</p><p>- Measuring the relationship between variables.</p><p>- Testing hypotheses about the measured relationship.</p><p>- Regression and related techniques are widely used in labour economics.</p><p>- Classification of Variables: </p><p>Dependent variable: the variable you are trying to explain.</p><p>Explanatory or independent variables: the variables you are trying to explain the dependent variable with.</p><p>14 Example: Wages and education.</p><p>Say that 12 people are surveyed and each is asked their wage and number of years of education. Say this is the result: </p><p>Person: Wage(W) Years of Education (ED) 1 $12.00 13 2 $24.00 17 3 $11.00 8 4 $15.00 12 5 $13.00 13 6 $20.00 16 7 $9.00 10 8 $10.00 6 9 $13.00 10 10 $15.00 14 11 $8.00 2 12 $9.00 3</p><p>- Scatter plot: plots the 12 observations of W vs. ED</p><p>- Suggests a positive relationship. - How to measure it? </p><p>15 - Linear Regression: assumes a linear relationship between the two variables.</p><p>W = a + b ∙ ED + e Eq. (1)</p><p> a = intercept or constant b = slope measuring the effect of a rise in ED on W</p><p>“a” and “b” are the coefficients or parameters of the regression.</p><p>“e” : error term (relationship is inexact due to measurement error, uncontrolled for variables, etc.)</p><p>- Choose a and b so that (Eq. 1) most closely fits the scatter pattern.</p><p>- Best fit? Method of ordinary least squares (OLS)</p><p>- OLS chooses a and b to minimize the sum of the squared, vertical distances between the fitted line and the data points.</p><p>(actual calculations done with statistical software)</p><p>For the example the best fitting line has: a=4.69, b=0.83</p><p>W = 4.69 + 0.83 x ED</p><p>- Interpreting output:</p><p>- Slope coefficient: an extra year of education raises the wage by 0.83 (83 cents).</p><p>- Intercept: if ED=0 predicted wage is $4.69 </p><p>16 - Statistics commonly included in a regression output:</p><p>(a) Std. error of a, b: a measure of the uncertainty of the estimates. </p><p>The larger it is relative to the size of the coefficient (a or b) the less reliable is that estimate.</p><p>Example: std. error of a = 1.92 std. error of b = .17</p><p>(b) t-statistic: </p><p> t-statistic= (coefficient estimate) (Std. error)</p><p>- tests whether the coefficient estimate differs from 0.</p><p> i.e. tests for the existence of a relationship between the variables.</p><p>Example: t-stat of a = 2.44 t-stat of b = 4.88</p><p>- Rule of thumb (larger samples): </p><p>Absolute value of t > 2.0 relationship is statistically significant.</p><p>Absolute value of t<2.0 relationship not statistically significant.</p><p>- Output is sometimes presented with the t-statistics or std. errors in brackets below or beside the coefficient estimates:</p><p> e.g., W = 4.69 + 0.83 x ED (2.44) (4.88)</p><p>17 - R2 is a measure of goodness of fit.</p><p>- Range 0-1 : near 0 poor fit, near 1 close fit.</p><p>- it measures share of the variation in W that is explained by the estimated equation.</p><p>R2 = .704 , 70.4% of the variation in W (around its mean) is explained.</p><p>- Multiple Regression (more than one explanatory variable):</p><p>- In practice, the value of an economic variable depends on many variables.</p><p>- Multiple regression fits the relationship between a dependent variable (e.g. wage) and several explanatory variables.</p><p> e.g. Wage might depend upon: - Years of education (ED) - Ability (IQ) - Seniority (SEN) - Union status (UNION)</p><p>Multiple regression fits (still linear):</p><p>W = a + b x ED + c x IQ + d x SEN + f x UNION + e</p><p> by choosing: a,b,c,d,f to minimize the sum of squared deviations of the equation from the values of W. </p><p>18 - Importance of multiple regression? </p><p>- Simple version: did the estimate of "b" reflect education or omitted variables that are correlated with education?</p><p> e.g. education vs. ability</p><p>- Muliple regression allows you to isolate the effect of each explanatory variable on the dependent variable. </p><p>Dummy Variables:</p><p>- Dummy variable: has a value of 0 or 1</p><p>- Equals 1 if the observation satisfies a certain condition, 0 if it does not.</p><p>Examples: - Married or not - Woman or Man - Has a university degree or not.</p><p>- Coefficient on a dummy: shows the effect on the dependent variable of satisfying the condition vs. not satisfying it.</p><p>- Sometimes a series of dummy variables describe the same characteristic.</p><p> e.g., age, educational attainment, industry of employment. </p><p>- Say maximum educational attainment can be one of three possibilities and define a dummy variable for each possibility: </p><p>Less than high school LHS=1 (HS=MHS=0) High school HS=1 (LHS=MHS=0) More than high school MHS=1 (LHS=HS=0)</p><p>19 Notice that: LHS+HS+MHS=1 for any given person. </p><p>Say that wages (W) are determined as follows:</p><p>W = a LHS + b HS + c MHS </p><p> substitute: LHS=1-HS-MHS then</p><p>W = a (1-HS-MHS) + b HS + c MHS </p><p> so: W = a + (b-a) HS + (c-a) MHS </p><p>- In this last equation LHS=1 is the default category for educational attainment.</p><p>- Coefficients on HS and MHS are interpreted as the effect on W of being in either HS or MHS rather than the default category (LHS=1). </p><p>- Ordinary least squares is a common statistical method in labour economics. </p><p>- not the only method. </p><p>- output from many other methods can often be interpreted in much the same way as OLS. </p><p>- Handout: Earnings equation table from Krueger (1993) </p><p>- another standard way to present regression output.</p><p>- remember it is just a linear equation! (write out the equation for the example)</p><p>20 SUPPLY AND DEMAND IN LABOUR MARKETS</p><p>- Sources: BGLR, Ch. 1 and Ch. 7 pp. 191-202.</p><p>- Basic model of price and quantity determination.</p><p>Price of labour:</p><p>- wage rate (all compensation)</p><p>- Wages NOT income</p><p>- wage (W): price of labour per hour, per week</p><p>- income: wages and salary income plus all other forms of non-labour income (investment income, transfer income, etc.)</p><p>Income = W x (Time Worked) + Non-labour income</p><p>Measures of the quantity of labour</p><p>- Possible Units? Number of people Hours, weeks of work</p><p>- Time period: day, week, year.</p><p>- Level of “aggregation”? many possible levels of application</p><p>- Specific type of job.</p><p>- Related jobs: e.g - same occupations - same skill level </p><p>21 - Aggregate: - Across many (possibly all) job. - Demographic groups.</p><p>- Level of focus depends upon problem under study.</p><p>Labour supply (LS)</p><p>- The amount of labour time people in the relevant market are willing to work.</p><p>- Economic approach: a person’s labour supply decision reflects a comparison of the costs and benefits of supplying labour. </p><p>- benefit of supplying labour? Pay! - cost? Value of time in other uses. </p><p>- Some key determinants of labour supply:</p><p>- Wage rate</p><p>- probably a positive effect on LS</p><p>- higher pay: work more attractive vs. other uses of time.</p><p>- If pay is high in a particular type of job: people switch from alternative jobs.</p><p>- Wages paid at other jobs: value of time in another job.</p><p>- Tastes/preferences: determines value of non-work time, value of money.</p><p>- Size of the adult population: how many decision-makers?</p><p>- Labour supply curve - (Probably) upward sloping in wage (W)- LS diagram.</p><p>- Changes in values of determinants of LS , other than the wage, shift the LS-curve.</p><p>22 Labour Demand (LD)</p><p>- Amount of labour that employers in the relevant market would like to hire. .</p><p>- Economic approach? Labour demand decision reflects a comparison of the costs and benefits of hiring labour.</p><p>- cost? What the employer must pay the worker. - benefit? Value of the worker’s time to the employer e.g. value of output produced. </p><p>- Some determinants of labour demand:</p><p>- Wage level: - Negatively related to LD.</p><p>- Technology: determines how much labour is needed to produce a given amount of output.</p><p>- Output market conditions, e.g., output price.</p><p>- Cost or price of other inputs.</p><p>- Labour demand curve</p><p>- Downward sloping in wage (W)- LD diagram.</p><p>- Changes in values of other determinants of LD shift the LD-curve. </p><p>23 Labour Market Equilibrium </p><p>- Equilibrium: - values of W (wage) and L (labour) where LS=LD </p><p>- equilibrium? no pressure for W or L to change</p><p>- Call equilibrium wage W* </p><p>- Consider W<W* </p><p>- Excess demand for labour LS<LD </p><p>- labour shortage: employers rationed ; workers have no problems finding jobs </p><p>- Workers: "pay more or I will go elsewhere".</p><p>- Employers: some are willing to pay more rather than do without. </p><p>- Result? Wage rises.</p><p>- Consider W>W* </p><p>- Excess supply of labour LS>LD </p><p>- More job applicants than jobs.</p><p>- Employers: "take less or I'll hire someone else" </p><p>- Workers: some are willing to take less rather than be out of a job</p><p>- Result? Wage falls.</p><p>24 - Is it a “good” outcome? Potentially “efficient”.</p><p>- All jobs created are created because the employer and worker expect to gain i.e. benefits > costs to both decision-makers. </p><p>- Each job match creates a surplus:</p><p>At a given level of L:</p><p>- Height of labour demand curve: maximum some employer in this market would pay for extra L.</p><p>- Height of labour supply curve: minimum some worker needs to be willing to supply extra L.</p><p>- Surplus on a given job?</p><p>- Employer: difference between maximum would pay and the wage. </p><p>- Worker: difference between wage and the minimum they need to be willing to work.</p><p>- All jobs created at supply-demand equilibrium create some surplus for both employers and workers. </p><p>- The supply-demand outcome generates the maximum amount of surplus from this market.</p><p>(add up the surpluses from each job to get total surplus)</p><p>- in this sense the outcome is a good or “efficient” one.</p><p>25 Usefulness of the supply-demand model:</p><p>- Provides a framework for explaining wages and employment:</p><p>- shifts in supply and demand curves change wages and employment. </p><p>- levels of wages and employment reflect values of variables that shift supply and demand curves. </p><p>- Imagine the Canadian labour market as a network of markets: - use it to think about wage structure, job share by skill & occupations.</p><p>Limitations of the Supply-Demand model applied to labour markets:</p><p>- Competition assumed: union sector? few employers? Public sector? - extensions needed! (will look at some of these)</p><p>- No explanation of unemployment: excess supply disappears. - what's missing? Unemployment appears bounded but why doesn't it disappear? What explains fluctuations in unemployment?</p><p>- Wages often seem more rigid than Supply-Demand suggests.</p><p>- treats wages like any other price: adjusts to equate supply and demand.</p><p>- Does the wage play other roles than just equating supply and demand? e.g. incentives, insurance, effects on morale? </p><p>- Are wages locked-in with long-term employment relationships? i.e. is Supply-Demand only appropriate for short-term jobs or entry- level jobs?</p><p>- Assumes away information problems - how do workers and employers find each other? (search models) - sorting and selection problems.</p><p>26 Application: Government Job Creation initiatives</p><p>- Job creation initiatives may involve hiring more public employees or via grants or tax incentives that lead to private businesses expanding.</p><p>- Supply-Demand perspective: both shift labour demand right.</p><p>- size of horizontal shift in labour demand are job openings directly created by the initiative. </p><p>- unless labour supply is perfectly flat actual change in employment is smaller than the horizontal shift in labour demand.</p><p>- actual rise in total employment will be smaller the steeper is labour supply. </p><p>- extreme? - if labour supply is vertical the policy creates no new employment.</p><p>(policy moves fixed labour supply from other jobs into the new jobs created by the initiative: displacement )</p><p>- policy does raise wages if labour supply vertical.</p><p>- what is more likely relatively flat or relatively vertical labour supply?</p><p>Think about:</p><p>- national labour market vs. localized labour market. </p><p>- booming economy vs. depressed economy.</p><p>27 Application: R. Freeman (2006) “Labor Market Imbalances: Shortages, or Surpluses or Fish Stories” (see website)</p><p>- How will the US labor market change over the next two decades? - he adopts a supply-demand framework.</p><p>- Two major factors are often mentioned:</p><p>(1) Demography: aging population and labour force, fewer young entrants, maybe eventually smaller workforce. </p><p>- Will there be shortages? (Supply shifts left especially in market for entry positions)</p><p>- Fewer workers, less output, smaller GDP likely.</p><p>- Is this a big problem?</p><p>- Supply-Demand model: wages will rise in affected markets. - this will eliminate shortages.</p><p>- GDP may be lower but GDP per worker may rise!</p><p>- Freeman doesn’t see this as much of a problem. </p><p>(2) Globalization of the labour market:</p><p>- A number of large countries have entered the world economy in recent years:</p><p>- China, India, former Soviet Union.</p><p>- Previously: little trade between these countries and the rest of the world. </p><p>- Freeman: as if the global labour supply has doubled. </p><p>28 - Effect in US (or Canada): - Shift in labour demand left (some of the goods and services now produced in the new economies instead).</p><p>- Pressure on wages to fall. </p><p>- low-skill workers only? (he thinks not: Russian skill levels, Indian programmers, etc.)</p><p>- But: prices of traded goods and services will fall too. i.e. real wages will fall less. </p><p>- Employment in US? Not likely to fall much (overall labour supply close to vertical?)</p><p>- Freeman thinks (2) not (1) is the bigger issue for the future. </p><p>- Note: simple, some insights, uses only supply-demand.</p><p>- Later section on labour demand: Katz and Murphy explanation of skilled- unskilled wage differentials is also an application of supply-demand. </p><p>29 ("race between education (supply) and technology (demand)")Appendix: An Algebraic Example of Supply and Demand</p><p>LS = labour supply POP = population W= wage rate LD= labour demand ISPG = measure of income support program generosity PIND = output price index PK = price of physical capital </p><p>- Variables whose values are determined in this market (endogenous): W, LS , LD</p><p>- Variables whose values are taken as given, i.e. determined outside this market (exogenous): POP, ISPG, PIND, PK</p><p>Say that these are the estimated Supply and Demand equations: </p><p>Labour supply: </p><p>LS = 400 + 25 W + 1.0 POP – 10 ISPG </p><p>- POP, ISPG shift the labour supply curve, i.e. more POP more supply, more generous income support (↑ISPG) less supply. </p><p>Labour demand: </p><p>LD = 500 – 75 W + 30 PIND + 20 PK</p><p>- PIND and PK shift the labour demand curve: higher output prices (↑PIND) more demand, higher price of capital (↑PK) more demand. </p><p>Equilibrium: LS = LD (= L call L the equilibrium quantity.)</p><p>400 + 25 W + 1.0 POP – 10 ISPG = 500 – 75 W + 30 PIND + 20 PK</p><p>Solve for the value of W (that equates supply and demand): </p><p>W = (100 + 30 PIND + 20 PK – 1.0 POP +10 ISPG ) / 100</p><p>30 To get the equilibrium quantity of labour substitute the solution for W into either the labour supply or labour demand equation (doesn’t matter which since LS = LD at this wage):</p><p>L = 400 + 25 W + 1.0 POP – 10 ISPG = 400 + 25 x {(100 + 30 PIND + 20 PK – 1.0 POP +10 ISPG ) / 100 } + .0 POP – 10 ISPG = 425 + 7.5 PIND + 5 PK + 0.75 POP - 7.5 ISPG </p><p>Note: - The equilibrium levels of W and L depend on the shift variables (POP, ISPG, PIND, PK).</p><p>- rise in POP or fall in ISPG shift the supply curve right – in diagram this will raise L and lower W (the same is true in the equations for equilibrium W and L) ;</p><p>- rise in PK or rise in PIND shift the labour demand curve right: in a diagram this would raise the equilibrium W and L (same is true in the equations for equilibrium PIND and PK).</p><p>31</p>

View Full Text

Details

  • File Type
    pdf
  • Upload Time
    -
  • Content Languages
    English
  • Upload User
    Anonymous/Not logged-in
  • File Pages
    31 Page
  • File Size
    -

Download

Channel Download Status
Express Download Enable

Copyright

We respect the copyrights and intellectual property rights of all users. All uploaded documents are either original works of the uploader or authorized works of the rightful owners.

  • Not to be reproduced or distributed without explicit permission.
  • Not used for commercial purposes outside of approved use cases.
  • Not used to infringe on the rights of the original creators.
  • If you believe any content infringes your copyright, please contact us immediately.

Support

For help with questions, suggestions, or problems, please contact us