<p> Models of Economics Growth: Capital Accumulation</p><p>- Growth models go beyond last section's "growth accounting” framework.</p><p>- Models of the growth process: </p><p>- simplification: focus on essentials </p><p>- identify key parameters and outcomes</p><p>- model interrelationships between key variables.</p><p>- The two models below stress the importance of "capital accumulation". </p><p>- Physical capital is the focus: machines, tools, buildings, infrastructure.</p><p>- Some characteristics of capital (K): </p><p>- Capital is a produced input. </p><p>- Capital is a productive asset: - an asset pays a stream of returns over it’s lifetime. </p><p>- capital generates a stream of valuable services i.e. value of the extra output produced with the capital.</p><p>- Creating/ buying K involves investment: pay now reap future returns. </p><p>- Capital is a durable asset but wears out over time (depreciation)</p><p>- Durable: lasts for many periods – there is an important time element in decisions to invest in K. </p><p>- Depreciation means that a country’s stock of K will shrink unless there is replacement investment. </p><p>1 - Economic history and the importance of capital:</p><p>- Developed countries: underwent industrializations.</p><p>- Capital accumulation is necessary to build modern industry (factories, machines, infrastructure)</p><p>- Early development economics (1950s-1970s): strong emphasis on boosting capital accumulation. </p><p> e.g. W.W. Rostow (1960) Stages of Economic Growth: boost the savings (and investment rate) to achieve -- “takeoff”.</p><p>W. A. Lewis (1955) Theory of Economic Growth: “central problem of economic development is to understand the process by which a community … investing 4-5 per cent of its national income … converts…to saving 12-13 per cent …” </p><p>- Allen Global Economic History – plots of K per L vs. GDP per L (see next page)</p><p>- first plot: each data point is a country; - second and third plots: also includes evolution of the relationship over time for Italy and Germany. </p><p>- Graphs suggest a positive relationship: higher GDP per worker associated with higher K/L.</p><p>- Growth accounting and development accounting studies (last set of notes): most suggest that differences in K/L are important.</p><p>2 3 Harrod-Domar Model</p><p>- See: Easterly The Elusive Quest for Growth Ch. 2 (a practictioner’s criticial view)</p><p>- Developed in the 1940s.</p><p>- Focus: capital accumulation as the key to growth.</p><p>- Model highlights two key parameters (k and s): </p><p>(1) k = incremental capital-output ratio (assumed a constant) (ICOR)</p><p>= extra capital needed to produce an extra unit of output</p><p>= K/Y (this is inverse of K productivity: Y/K)</p><p>- ICOR is often treated as constant determined by technology and industrial structure of the economy.</p><p>(2) s = savings rate (share of output or income that is saved)</p><p>4 - Aggregate (economy-wide) production function in Harrod-Domar:</p><p>"Fixed-coefficients" (Leontief) technology:</p><p>Yt = min(aLt , bKt)</p><p>- this says that Yt is the minimum of aLt or bKt </p><p>- it implies that producing one unit of Y requires "1/a" units of L and "1/b" units of K (so: Y = min(1,1)=1 ) </p><p>- notice that having L=2/a and K=1/b still gives only one unit of output: Y=min(2,1)=1</p><p> i.e. the extra L is unproductive unless it has K to work with.</p><p>- Let’s represent the production function in a graph.</p><p>- Isoquants: combinations of K and L that produce the same quantity of output.</p><p>- Leontief production: isoquants are right-angles (through the ray from the origin a/b).</p><p>5 - Poor economies? - Surplus labour seems plausible (like pt. 0 at LBig above)</p><p>- lots of L, relatively little K (so K/L < a/b).</p><p>- much of the L is ‘unproductive’ or ‘surplus’ due to lack of K. - there is a bottleneck on growth from lack of capital.</p><p>- raise K to raise output (raising L has no effect).</p><p>- the growth equation is (assuming b is constant):</p><p>Y = b K</p><p>- ‘b’ measures the productivity of extra K.</p><p>- The incremental capital-output ratio (ICOR) k= 1/b:</p><p>1/b = K/Y </p><p>- this is the amount of extra K needed to ease the capital shortage bottleneck enough to raise output by 1. </p><p>6 - Where does K come from? </p><p>Capital is created by investment spending (I):</p><p>Investment (I) = K (this version ignores depreciation’ with constant depreciation: K =I-K where is depreciation rate: see Solow model)</p><p>- Investment spending is financed via savings (S)</p><p> i.e. some of the economy’s income is not being spent on current consumption.</p><p>Savings (S) = Investment (I)</p><p>- Assume a simple economy-wide savings equation:</p><p>S = s Y s= savings rate (constant)</p><p>- savings is assumed to be domestic (from own country).</p><p>- savings is a constant share of output (national income).</p><p>7 - So output growth in the labour surplus economy is:</p><p>Y = bK = K/k by definition of k=1/b</p><p>Y = I/k = S/k = sY/k (assumes: S=sY )</p><p>Y/Y = s/k growth rate of GDP equals s/k</p><p>- Capital accumulation is key to growth in a labour surplus economy.</p><p>- industrialize ! </p><p>- a lack of K is keeping workers unproductive and Y low. </p><p>- “Financing gap” approach to development is rooted in this kind of thinking: - a target growth rate implies a target level of savings (given k).</p><p>- development policies should aim to provide the needed finance.</p><p>- Policies that raise "s" will raise output growth.</p><p>8 - Aggregate savings and National accounting (from intro economics):</p><p>Y = GDP G = government spending T = taxes (less transfers) C = consumption X = exports NCI = net capital inflow I = investment spending M = imports</p><p>An identity: GDP equals aggregate spending across sectors.</p><p>Y = C + I + G + X – M</p><p>Solve for I and then add and subtract T :</p><p>I = (Y-T-C) + (T-G) - (X-M)</p><p>Y-T-C = private domestic savings</p><p>T-G = government savings (budget surplus if >0)</p><p>X-M = net exports : <0 financed by borrowing abroad (foreign savings) >0 financed by lending abroad. (outflows of domestic saving)</p><p>= -(net foreign savings) (or Net Capital Inflow)</p><p>9 - So three sources of savings: </p><p>Source Policies</p><p>Domestic private financial development, taxes and savings</p><p>Government savings budget surpluses</p><p>Savings from abroad foreign aid, ownership rules, exchange rate policy, stability, rule of law.</p><p>- Recall Allen’s discussion of the ‘Standard Model’ followed by countries who industrialized after Britain: development of a financial system was one of the four parts of this strategy. </p><p>- Financial system: offers a variety of secure ways to save; provides ways in which businesses can borrow; matches savings to borrowers. </p><p>10 - Model suggests growth rates would also be affected by altering "k" </p><p>- lower k: more growth</p><p>- Interpretation of a lower k: more productive investments.</p><p>- Labour? - implicitly it is in excess supply here (surplus).</p><p>- unemployment or underemployment of labour depends on the capital growth.</p><p>- Is much of labour in poor country agriculture or in the informal sector underemployed?</p><p>11 - Easterly: Harrod-Domar “most widely used growth model”</p><p>- Early development economics, planners and the World Bank used (and some still use) versions of this model for their policy prescriptions.</p><p>- often multi-sector versions (a Leontief production function and estimates of ICOR (k) for each major industry): Input-Output Models. </p><p>- Given “k” the growth rate equation tells what the target value of “s” must be to achieve a growth rate target in a given sector.</p><p>- Construct a plan to allocate savings (investment) between industries to achieve a growth target. Allows via input-output structure for interdependence between industries (outputs in one industry may be an input in another industry).</p><p>- Bhagwhati (in India in Transition) experience of India and the Soviet Union in the post-WWII period.</p><p>- savings rates were reasonably high. </p><p>- BUT investment was unproductive (high k) - lack of competition - poor incentives.</p><p> i.e., economic institutions proved to be a barrier to growth</p><p>- High savings and investment only produce high growth if capital is productive.</p><p>- Was this true elsewhere in 1950s and 1960s? North Africa, parts of Latin America.</p><p>12 - Problems with the Harrod-Domar Model and the "Financing Gap Approach" to Development: (see Easterly):</p><p>- Empirical support: - the link between investment and growth is not as simple as the model suggests (other factors matter);</p><p>- predictive power: Easterly’s Figure 2.1 for Zambia; model’s prediction of which countries would grow fast (wrong ones).</p><p>- Technological assumptions: - Leontief production function does not allow for different input intensities in production: low K/L need not mean that capital shortages constrain growth.</p><p>- common for LDCs to use very different input mixes than MDCs in the same industry.</p><p>- Model ignores incentives: </p><p>- low investment may partly reflect incentives </p><p> e.g. returns to investment are low for some reason.</p><p>- then additional finance (savings) may produce little growth.</p><p>- Growth diagnostics approach: can methods be developed to identify constraints on growth in individual countries?</p><p>- Poor countries: too little finance or no incentive to invest? </p><p>13 (D. Rodrik: no single recipe, answer is case specific – growth diagnostics)Solow Growth Model</p><p>- See: any second-year macroeconomics text; see website for online sources. </p><p>- Developed by R. Solow in the late-1950s (Solow model, Solow-Swan model).</p><p>- The dominant model of growth in mainstream, "neoclassical economics".</p><p>- It makes neoclassical technical assumptions: - substitution between types of inputs is assumed possible; - diminishing returns.</p><p>- An alternative to the Harrod-Domar model which was built upon a non- neoclassical production function.</p><p>Model Components:</p><p>(1) Aggregate Production function</p><p>Yt = F(Kt, Lt)</p><p>Yt = GDP, output at time t.</p><p>Lt = amount of labour at time t.</p><p>Kt = quantity of capital at time t.</p><p>14 - Production function assumptions:</p><p>- K and L are substitutes in production.</p><p>- K intensive and L intensive ways of producing a given Y.</p><p>- Constant returns to scale:</p><p>- double K and L and output (Y) doubles.</p><p>- Due to constant returns to scale:</p><p>Yt = F(Kt, Lt)</p><p> divide by Lt: Yt /Lt = F(Kt, Lt)/ Lt</p><p>Yt /Lt = F(Kt/Lt, 1) GDP per worker depends on capital per worker.</p><p>15 - Diminishing returns:</p><p>- Marginal product: extra output from an extra unit of input.</p><p>- If K rises, with L constant, the marginal product of K will fall.</p><p>- If L rises, with K constant, the marginal product of L will fall.</p><p>- A given rise in K/L gives a smaller rise in Y/L the higher is K/L.</p><p>- technically: same first derivative as for diminishing returns to K.</p><p>- intuitively: K/L rising, so K is growing faster than L, extra K has less L to work with so its productivity falls.</p><p>- Picture: Production function becomes flatter at higher K/L.</p><p>- Support for diminishing returns: see figures from Allen (above and see the previous set of notes)</p><p>16 (2) Capital accumulation:</p><p>- Capital accumulation part of the model is like Harrod-Domar model.</p><p>- K grows due to investment;</p><p>- but let’s allow for depreciation of existing capital as well.</p><p> i.e. assume that a share () of the K stock wears out each period.</p><p>- in the model is treated as a constant. </p><p>Kt = (Investment at time t) - (Depreciation of existing stock)</p><p>= It - Kt</p><p>Investment (It) = Savings (St)</p><p>Savings function (as in Harrod-Domar):</p><p>St = sYt </p><p> s= savings rate (a constant)</p><p>So: Kt = sYt - Kt</p><p>- is the capital accumulation relationship.</p><p>17 (3) Labour force growth:</p><p>Lt = gLt</p><p> labour grows at a constant rate g (some current treatments set g=0).</p><p>- Put the three parts of the model together!</p><p>- Since:</p><p>Yt /Lt = F(Kt/Lt, 1)</p><p>How Y/L changes over time depends on whether K/L is rising, falling or constant: </p><p> i.e., on how the growth rates of K and L compare: </p><p>K/L rising if: Kt/Kt - Lt/Lt > 0 </p><p>K/L falling if: Kt/Kt - Lt/Lt < 0</p><p>K/L constant if: Kt/Kt - Lt/Lt = 0</p><p>We have: Lt/Lt = g</p><p>Kt/Kt = (sYt - Kt)/ Kt</p><p>= sYt/Kt - </p><p>So answer to the question of how K/L changes depends on whether: </p><p>Kt/Kt - Lt/Lt = sYt/Kt - - g > 0 , < 0 , = 0</p><p>18 - The key equation:</p><p> sYt/Kt - - g > 0 , < 0 , = 0</p><p>Is usually multiplied through by K/L to help present the model in graphs.</p><p>- After multiplying through by K/L the key equation of the model is: </p><p>K/L and Y/L rising if: s(Yt/Lt) – (g+)(Kt/Lt) > 0 </p><p>K/L and Y/L falling if: s(Yt/Lt) – (g+)(Kt/Lt) < 0</p><p>K/L and Y/L constant if: s(Yt/Lt) – (g+)(Kt/Lt) = 0</p><p>19 - Graph: s(Yt/Lt) – (g+)(Kt/Lt) > 0, =0 or <0</p><p> s(Yt/Lt) = savings per unit of L</p><p>= capital growth per unit L generated by savings.</p><p>= falling slope reflects diminishing returns </p><p> i.e., s Yt/Lt = s F(Kt/Lt, 1)</p><p>(g+)(Kt/Lt) = amount of capital growth per unit L required to keep K/L constant.</p><p> i.e. to maintain K/L: g K is needed to equip each new worker with the same level of K as old workers.</p><p> the Kt capital that wears out must be replaced.</p><p>20 - The model has an equilibrium: (Y/L)ss, (K/L)ss</p><p>Start instead with: </p><p>Low K/L: - capital growth per L exceeds K growth required to keep K/L constant.</p><p>- K/L rises, Y/L rises.</p><p>- As K/L rises, capital required to keep K/L constant grows steadily at rate of (g+.</p><p>- Savings per L grow at a diminishing rate due to diminishing returns in producing output. </p><p>- K/L eventually stops growing.</p><p>- when required capital growth equals actual capital growth.</p><p>(Constant returns numerical example?</p><p>Say that: g= .05 (5%) K-growth: 12%</p><p>Output must be growing between 5%-12% (e.g. 9%)</p><p>Next period - Investment in K grows at 9% (S = sY = I) - Say depreciation is 1% then K has grown 8%. - So: - L now grows at 5% - Y grows 5-8% (say 7%)</p><p>Next period: - K has grown by 7%-1%=6% - L grew 5% - Y grows 5-6% (6%)</p><p> i.e., K growth eventually falls to equal L growth: here 5% )</p><p>21 Start with: </p><p>High K/L: - capital growth per L is less than K growth required to keep K/L constant.</p><p>- K/L falls, Y/L falls.</p><p>- As K/L falls, the capital required to keep K/L constant falls at a steady rate of (g+.</p><p>- Savings per L falls more slowly due to diminishing returns in producing output. </p><p>(i.e., drop in Y/L is relatively small for a fall in K/L when K/L is high)</p><p>- K/L eventually stops falling.</p><p>- when required capital growth equals actual capital growth.</p><p>- At the "steady state" equilibrium (K/L)ss:</p><p> s(Yt/Lt) – (g+)(Kt/Lt) = 0</p><p>- equilibrium in that Y/L and K/L are constant over time.</p><p>- But: Y, K and L are all growing over time at a rate of g.</p><p> i.e., equal to the labour growth rate. (‘balanced growth’)</p><p>- Consumption per worker? Consumption (C) = Income – Savings</p><p>- In per worker terms: (Y/L) – (sY/L) = (1-s)Y/L</p><p>- Notice that higher K/L raises Y/L but at a cost (lower C). - Is there a best value of ‘s’ that balances these effects and maximizes C/L?</p><p>22 Comparative statics: How does the steady state equilibrium change if key parameters change?</p><p>(1) Change in the savings rate (s):</p><p>- Rise in s:</p><p>- at the old equilibrium K/L, savings per L are higher than what is required to keep K/L constant.</p><p>- K/L rises. </p><p>- Capital required to keep K/L constant at its higher level grows faster than savings: </p><p> eventually get to a new equilibrium: K/L and Y/L higher than before.</p><p>23 (2) Rise in g (labour force growth):</p><p>- At the old equilibrium, capital growth required to keep K/L constant is now higher than before.</p><p>- K/L falls.</p><p>- capital required to keep K/L constant shrinks at a faster rate then savings, eventually a new equilibrium is attained with a lower K/L and lower Y/L.</p><p>24 (3) Technology improves (or institutions or organization improves):</p><p>- Form of F(K, L) changes so that more output is produced by current K, L (total factor productivity has risen).</p><p> 1- e.g. in Cobb-Douglas “A” rises. ( Yt = A Kt Lt )</p><p>- Savings per L rise. </p><p>- Capital growth is higher than is required to keep K/L constant. K/L rises.</p><p>- Capital growth required to keep K/L at its increasingly higher level grows faster than savings. Eventually, K/L stops rising.</p><p>- K/L and Y/L higher after the technological improvement.</p><p>(a depreciation rate comparative static could also be done but is not so interesting – is treated as if it is not an economic variable)</p><p>25 Predictions: Why might Y/L Differ between Rich and Poor Countries?</p><p>- Imagine Poor and Rich economies operate along the lines of the Solow model.</p><p>- Poor have lower levels of GDP per capita (Y/L) than Rich countries. </p><p>- Why might this occur? </p><p>- Two types of situation are suggested by the model:</p><p>(A) If these are equilibrium differences, the Solow growth model suggests these differences could arise because:</p><p>(1) Poor countries have lower savings rates than Rich countries;</p><p>(2) Poor countries have higher labour force growth than Rich countries; </p><p>(3) Poor countries have inferior technology, organization or institutions compared to Rich countries (so lower F).</p><p>(any of these or some mix of them could explain lower Y/L)</p><p>- To encourage growth, Poor countries should:</p><p>- Adopt policies that will raise their savings rates.</p><p>- Adopt policies that will lower labour force growth (e.g., slow population growth).</p><p>- Improve their technology, organization, improve institutions so they get more output per worker for a given K/L.</p><p>26 (B) Some Poor vs. Rich country Differences may be Transitional:</p><p>- Say Poor country has the same equilibrium K/L and Y/L as a Rich country.</p><p>- Then the Poor Country is poorer since it is still moving toward its equilibrium. </p><p>- Differences will be eliminated once the equilibrium is reached. (convergence)</p><p>27 Predictions Regarding Differences in Growth Prospects: </p><p>- Comparative statics asked how the equilibrium was affected by differences in g, s and technology.</p><p>- For economies with the same “s”, “g” and the same production function:</p><p>- countries with low Y/L should grow faster (shrink less) than countries with high Y/L (low Y/L country is further from their common steady state)</p><p>- For economies starting with the same initial Y/L, same production function:</p><p>- high "s" and/or low "g" countries will see most growth (least shrinkage) in Y/L.</p><p>- low “s” and/or high “g” countries will see least growth (most shrinkage) in Y/L.</p><p> i.e., as each economy moves to its steady state (steady state is higher for high s, low g country) </p><p>- Same initial Y/L, same s, same g: </p><p>- country with a higher production function (F) will have more growth (less shrinkage).</p><p>28 Evidence in Support of the Solow Growth Model:</p><p>- Scatterplots from Jones and Vollrath or Mankiw and Scarth:</p><p>- positive association between current GDP per person and investment as a share of GDP (averaged over the previous few decades).</p><p>- negative association between current GDP per person and average annual population growth over the previous few decades.</p><p>- note: if the labour force participation rate is constant population growth will equal labour force growth.</p><p>- scatterplots are consistent with Solow model. </p><p>29 30 Mankiw, Romer and Weil: Quarterly Journal of Economics 1992</p><p>- Can the neoclassical (Solow) growth model explain observed cross-country variation in GDP per worker?</p><p>- Started with a Cobb-Douglas production function. - extra wrinkle: assumes production function is shifting upward at a constant rate (see below) e.g. reflecting technological progress.</p><p>- Linear regression approach:</p><p> ln(Yt/Lt) = a + b ln(I/Y) + c ln(g+)</p><p>- Fits this relation to data for a large sample of countries 1965-85, i.e. choose values of the coefficients (a, b and c) that best fit the data. </p><p>- Value of Y/L is for 1985</p><p>- Investment rate (I/Y) plays the role of “s”: average 1960-85</p><p>- g is the working population growth rate: average 1960-85.</p><p>- : suggests it is around .03-.04 for most countries.</p><p>- Actual version also assumes constant growth in technological progress (dropped in the regression equations below).</p><p>- Regression results:</p><p>98 country sample: (excludes 8 major oil producers)</p><p> ln(Yt/Lt) = 5.48 + 1.42 ln(I/Y) -1.97 ln(g+)</p><p>75 country sample: (excludes countries with poor data quality)</p><p> ln(Yt/Lt) = 5.36 + 1.31 ln(I/Y) -2.01 ln(g+)</p><p>OECD (industrialized) countries only (22 countries):</p><p> ln(Yt/Lt) = 7.97 + 0.50 ln(I/Y) -0.76 ln(g+)</p><p>31 - Results and theory:</p><p>- Signs of the coefficients are consistent with the Solow model.</p><p>- higher investment (savings) rate higher Y/L.</p><p>- higher population growth smaller Y/L.</p><p>- Estimates are statistically significant for the two larger samples.</p><p>- The estimated equation explains 60% of variation in Y/L in 1985 between countries for the two larger samples.</p><p>- But estimated coefficients are larger than theory suggests. </p><p>- Extended version adds human capital accumulation to the model: - coefficients still predicted signs.</p><p>- coefficient sizes more reasonable.</p><p>- 80% of variation in Y/L explained. </p><p>32 Some Problems and Extensions of the Neoclassical (Solow) Model</p><p>(1) Steady-state equilibrium has a constant value of Y/L:</p><p>- There appears to be an upward trend in Y/L. - maybe there is a steady state in Y/L rather than Y. i.e. Y/L grows at a constant rate in equilibrium. </p><p>- Technology tends to improve over time. </p><p>- Could have allow a constant shift upward in the production function over time e.g. Y=F(K,L) = A KL1- let A in the Cobb-Douglas grow at a constant rate. </p><p>- Common alternative (labour-augmenting technical progress):</p><p>- Main effect of technology is to increase efficiency of L. </p><p>- Say that N is the measure of labour input:</p><p>Yt = F(Kt, Nt)</p><p>Nt = et Lt where et = measure of efficiency of a unit of L. Lt = units of labour (workers) – as before. </p><p>- let technological improvements raise the productivity of labour </p><p>(boost “et”)</p><p>- say that “e” grows at a rate of </p><p>- then N grows by (g+ ) each year (L grows at rate g).</p><p>- Now assuming constant returns (as before):</p><p>Yt/Nt = F(Kt/Nt, 1) </p><p>33 - A steady state requires a constant K/N :</p><p> s(Yt/Nt) - (g+ +) (Kt/Nt) = 0</p><p>- like before except N replaces L and (g+ +) replaces g+.</p><p>- this maintains a constant: K/N and Y/N</p><p>- K/L and Y/L will actually be growing in the steady state: - K, N and Y grow at rate (g+) - L grows at rate g - so Y/L grows at rate </p><p>- Implication: differences in will determine relative growth in Y/L between countries. </p><p>34 (2) Determination of population growth or savings rates:</p><p>(a) Population growth</p><p>- It can be argued that savings rates and population (labour force) growth rates depend on the current level of Y/L.</p><p> i.e., not constants as in basic model. </p><p>- Malthusian population growth: </p><p> sub g = ∙(Yt/Lt – y )</p><p> where: ysub = subsistence level Y/L. >0 a parameter showing the effect of Y/L on population (labour force) growth. </p><p>- Diagrams? - imagine g growing as K/L and Y/L grow. </p><p>- K growth required to maintain K/L grows since L growth rises. </p><p>- Malthusian population growth means less Y/L growth for a given rise in s, F.</p><p>- But don’t have the Classical model result of no growth. (can get closer to this by adding a fixed input too)</p><p>- Is Malthusian population growth more appropriate for an LDC?</p><p>- Does the Malthusian relationship break down at higher Y/L? (demographic transition)</p><p>- if so: g may rise with Y/L at low Y/L g may start to decline after some threshold level of Y/L.</p><p>- imagine what this could do to the steady-state.</p><p>35 (b) Savings rate (s): constant in the basic model. </p><p>Savings rates and Y/L:</p><p>- s likely low in poor countries (little income left after meeting basic needs)</p><p>- s seems likely to rise initially with Y/L. </p><p>(see for example Weil's Figure 3.8)</p><p>- More generally: maybe "s" rises gradually over some range of Y/L.</p><p>- this can give low-, medium- and high-level equilibria (draw this!) - note: medium-level equilibrium is unstable.</p><p>- Interest?</p><p>- low-level steady state equilibrium is a “poverty trap” type outcome: </p><p> low income low savings, low investment low productivity low K/L ( of L)</p><p>- vicious circle: poor because you are poor!</p><p>- is this the situation of LDCs today?</p><p>- high-level steady state could be identified with MDCs.</p><p>36 37</p><p>- A “Big Push” strategy? </p><p>- a one-time shock to the economy that raised K/L sufficiently could switch a LDC into a MDC.</p><p> i.e. it would grow from the low-level to the high-level steady state (show this).</p><p>- Jeffrey Sachs (2005) End of Poverty suggests that foreign aid might be able to do something like this.</p><p>(others e.g. William Easterly dispute this)</p><p>- Other determinants of investment and savings:</p><p>- Are they determined by “fundamentals” – culture, governance, history, religion, geography, etc. </p><p>- if so what if anything can be done?</p><p>- Above: more savings leads to more investment.</p><p>- but low investment may partly reflect incentives </p><p> e.g. returns to investment are low for some reason.</p><p>- then additional finance (savings) may produce little growth.</p><p>- Growth diagnostics approach: can methods be developed to identify constraints on growth in individual countries?</p><p>- too little finance (low savings) or no incentive to invest? e.g Dani Rodrik.</p><p>38 - Interest Rates and the Solow model. </p><p>- focus is on capital accumulation, investment and savings but where is the interest rate?</p><p>- interest rates affect cost of borrowing to finance investment and the return to saving: likely to be important to capital accumulation.</p><p>- slope of the aggregate production function (F): indicates the amount by which extra K (extra K/L) raises value of output, Y (Y/L).</p><p> i.e. related to the return on investment in extra K. </p><p>- diminishing returns and this? Return on K investment should fall as K/L rises.</p><p>- interest rates are linked to this return (slope of production function) - return on K must be as good as on financial investments: savings are directed to the higher return investment (tends to equalize returns) - return on K > interest rate: borrow more to finance more K, extra borrowing raises the interest rate. </p><p>- Interesting implication: other things equal returns on K investment should be higher in LDCs where K/L is low.</p><p>- with globalized financial markets will savings flow to LDCs?</p><p>(will look at this in more detail later)</p><p>- Fuller versions of the model: savings a result of household maximization problem (end result is not too different from basic Solow).</p><p>39 (3) Human capital.</p><p>- Too simple: focus on one type of labour and an aggregate measure of capital.</p><p>- Versions of the model with education variables typically perform better.</p><p>(more of observed growth is explained: Mankiw, Romer and Weil)</p><p>(4) Technology:</p><p>- Technological change is not explained in the model. </p><p>- Implicitly it is independent of Y/L, the amount of investment, labour force growth etc.</p><p>- Investment and technological change may be closely linked in practice.</p><p>- Research and Development expenditures as investment.</p><p>- in the previous model and therefore growth in Y/L would depend upon “s”.</p><p>- Virtuous circles?</p><p>- More saving, more investment, more R&D, higher return to K investment (diminishing returns pushed back), more investment, more advances in knowledge, etc.</p><p>- higher Y/L, bigger markets, higher potential returns to innovation, more R&D, more innovation, higher productivity, higher Y/L, etc. </p><p>- Population growth: does it feed technological change? </p><p>- New (Endogenous) Growth theory: interest in links like these.</p><p>40 (5) What about economic institutions?</p><p>- Aren’t institutions important?</p><p>- Eastern Europe / Soviet Union vs. the West? </p><p>- Could be introduced into the model through form of F (like technology they may affect productivity of inputs).</p><p>- Do institutions help determine the savings and investment rates? Are they higher in countries with good institutions e.g. rule of law, high levels of trust, etc. </p><p>- Do institutions change in predictable ways with income per person? </p><p>- Some work on this (historical, empirical): little consensus. </p><p>41</p>
Details
-
File Typepdf
-
Upload Time-
-
Content LanguagesEnglish
-
Upload UserAnonymous/Not logged-in
-
File Pages41 Page
-
File Size-