Perverse Accountability: a Formal Model of Machine Politics with Evidence from Argentina SUSAN C

Perverse Accountability: a Formal Model of Machine Politics with Evidence from Argentina SUSAN C

American Political Science Review Vol. 99, No. 3 August 2005 Perverse Accountability: A Formal Model of Machine Politics with Evidence from Argentina SUSAN C. STOKES Yale University olitical machines (or clientelist parties) mobilize electoral support by trading particularistic benefits to voters in exchange for their votes. But if the secret ballot hides voters’ actions from the machine, P voters are able to renege, accepting benefits and then voting as they choose. To explain how machine politics works, I observe that machines use their deep insertion into voters’ social networks to try to circumvent the secret ballot and infer individuals’ votes. When parties influence how people vote by threatening to punish them for voting for another party, I call this perverse accountability.I analyze the strategic interaction between machines and voters as an iterated prisoners’ dilemma game with one-sided uncertainty. The game generates hypotheses about the impact of the machine’s capacity to monitor voters, and of voters’ incomes and ideological stances, on the effectiveness of machine politics. I test these hypotheses with data from Argentina. hirty-five years ago, James Scott (1969) observed machines also have the secret ballot. Political machines that political life of contemporary new nations did not disappear in the United States after the intro- bore a strong resemblance to the machine poli- duction of the Australian ballot in most U.S. states at T 1 tics of the United States in earlier eras. The patronage, the end of the nineteenth century. And clientelism particularism, and graft endemic to the Philippines or flourishes in countries from Mexico (Fox 1994) to Italy Malaysia in the postwar decades recalled, for Scott, (Chubb 1982) to Bulgaria (Kitschelt et al. 1999), all of the Tweed machine in nineteenth-century New York which have the ballot. or the Dawson machine in twentieth-century Chicago. Assuming that machines can overcome the problem Much has happened in the third of a century since Scott of their clients’ reneging, what kinds of voters will they outlined “the contours and dynamics of the ‘machine target? Scattered through the qualitative literature is model’ in comparative perspective” (1143). Many of evidence that poor voters are the targets of machines the new nations that occupied his analysis have under- (see, e.g., Chubb 1982; Wilson and Banfield 1963). For- gone transitions to electoral democracy; yet politics in mal treatments agree, citing diminishing marginal util- these systems often remains particularistic, clientelis- ity of income as the reason why particularlistic ben- tic, and corrupt. We therefore have a larger sample of efits generate more votes among the poor than the countries, and a richer experience on which to draw, rich (Calvo and Murillo 2004; Dixit and Londregan to understand the contours and dynamics of the ma- 1996). chine. The historiography of the U.S. political machine Yet in the societies where clientelistic parties or ma- has also grown, as have historical studies of patronage chines are active, not all poor voters receive benefits. and vote buying in the history of today’s advanced Limited resources force political machines to choose European democracies (see, e.g., Piattoni 2001). Fi- among poor voters. Machine operatives everywhere nally, a formal literature on redistributive politics has face a version of the dilemma that an Argentine Pero- developed, one in which the political machine plays a nist explains. About 40 voters live in her neighborhood, central role. and her responsibility is to get them to the polls and Yet the formal literature on the political ma- get them to vote for her party. But the party gives her chine leaves some crucial questions unanswered. Chief only 10 bags of food to distribute, “ten little bags,” she among them: How does the machine keep voters from laments, “nothing more.”2 How does she, and machine reneging on the implicit deal whereby the machine dis- operatives like her in systems around the world, de- tributes goods and the recipient votes for the machine? cide who among her neighbors shall and who shall not If voters can renege, then machines should not waste receive handouts? scarce resources on them and clientelist politics breaks The formal literature answers this question by saying down. The question is the more pressing, given that that machines target core constituents. But if these con- many of the societies in which we find active political stituents are ideologically committed to the machine, is it not wasting resources if it distributes rewards to them? Would it not do better by distributing rewards to Susan C. Stokes is the John S. Saden Professor of Political Science, the uncommitted or even to those who, on ideological Department of Political Science, P.O. Box 208301, Yale University, New Haven, Ct 06520-8301. ([email protected]). I thank Valeria Brusco, John Carey, Matt Cleary, Avinash Dixit, 1 The Australian ballot is one in that is produced by governments Jeff Grynaviski, John Londregan, Scott Mainwaring, Roger Myerson, or neutral election authorities (rather than by political parties), dis- Luis Fernando Medina, Mario Navarro, Marcelo Nazareno, Steve tributed through guarded channels on or close to election day, and Pincus, Duncan Snidal, and three anonymous APSR reviewers for that lists all parties or candidates for an office in a single format. excellent comments. I am especially indebted to Michael Wallerstein. 2 Interview conducted by Valeria Brusco, Susan Stokes, and Gloria Research was supported by National Science Foundation research Trocello, in Villa Mercedes, Argentina, July 2003; my translation. Grant SES-0241958 and by the John Simon Guggenheim Memorial This and all subsequent translations from the Spanish are by the Foundation. author. 315 Perverse Accountability August 2005 grounds, oppose the party? The selection method of every group, the parties deploy tactical rewards to com- our Argentine operative is to help “the people who pete for the same groups of swing voters—–groups with complain the most, the ones who say, ‘What are you a relatively large number of moderate voters who are going to give me?’ I pick them up [to take them to ideologically indifferent between the two parties. But the polls] and after I take them they say, ‘Aren’t there when one party has an especially close link to a group of any bags of food?”’ Her words hint at a logic in which voters, then the party will target this core constituency. machines give private handouts not to die-hard sup- Dixit and Londregan write that core constituents are porters but to people whose future support is in doubt. ones The analysis in this article helps make sense of her explanation. whom [the party] understands well ...A party’s core con- stituencies need not prefer its issue positions. It is the Far from being just a Latin American problem, or a party’s advantage over its competitors at swaying voters problem that advanced democracies have completely in a group with offers of particularistic benefits that makes overcome, vote buying, clientelism, and machine poli- the group core (1986, 1134) . The key to the electoral tics are blights on many democracies around the world, strategies of the urban political machines was their ability even today. Prosecutors in 2004 accused a candidate to provide “personal services” to their core constituents at for a district judgeship in Eastern Kentucky of giving a lower cost than could their competitors. They did this by $50 checks to voters, implicitly in return for their sup- knowing their constituents (1147). port.3 Journalists reported, also in 2004, that an elderly For Cox and McCubbins (1986), the crucial feature hospital patient in Ukraine confessed to his son that of the machine–core constituent link is that the party he had voted for the official presidential candidate, is more certain about how core groups will respond Viktor Yanukovych, rather than for the opposition can- to rewards than it is about other groups. The party didate, Viktor Yuschenko. He had planned to support is more certain because “core supporters ...are well- Yuschenko but switched his vote after a nurse at the known quantities. The candidate is in frequent and hospital promised him a wheelchair if he switched.4 intensive contact with them and has relatively precise These practices make a mockery of democratic ac- and accurate ideas about how they will react” (1986, countability. Democratic accountability usually means 378–9). that voters know, or can make good inferences about, The problem with both pairs of authors’ models what parties have done in office and reward or punish is that they don’t deal adequately with commitment them conditional on these actions. But when parties problems. Both assume by caveat that the party won’t know, or can make good inferences about, what indi- renege on its offer of particularistic rewards once it’s vidual voters have done in the voting booth and reward won the election.5 And they don’t deal adequately or punish them conditional on these actions, this is per- with the fact that a voter, once in the voting booth, verse accountability. We usually think of accountability can also renege by voting his or her conscience or in democratic systems as a good thing: it means that preference, ignoring the reward he or she received. voters can keep elected officials from misbehaving and When we translate these authors’ models into one- pressure governments to be more responsive to voters. shot strategic interactions between party operatives But perverse accountability is bad for democracy: it and voters, redistributive politics does not happen. (For reduces the pressure on governments to perform well reasons of space, I do not analyze such games here.) and to provide public goods, keeps voters from using The operative doesn’t give a reward, and the possibil- elections to express their policy preferences, and under- ity of a reward doesn’t change the voter’s vote.

View Full Text

Details

  • File Type
    pdf
  • Upload Time
    -
  • Content Languages
    English
  • Upload User
    Anonymous/Not logged-in
  • File Pages
    11 Page
  • File Size
    -

Download

Channel Download Status
Express Download Enable

Copyright

We respect the copyrights and intellectual property rights of all users. All uploaded documents are either original works of the uploader or authorized works of the rightful owners.

  • Not to be reproduced or distributed without explicit permission.
  • Not used for commercial purposes outside of approved use cases.
  • Not used to infringe on the rights of the original creators.
  • If you believe any content infringes your copyright, please contact us immediately.

Support

For help with questions, suggestions, or problems, please contact us