
INSTITUTT FOR FORETAKSØKONOMI DEPARTMENT OF FINANCE AND MANAGEMENT SCIENCE FOR 13 2011 ISSN: 1500-4066 August 2011 Discussion paper Using Bank Mergers and Acquisitions to Understand Lending Relationships BY Ove Rein Hetland AND Aksel Mjøs Using Bank Mergers and Acquisitions to Understand Lending Relationships1 Ove Rein Hetland 2 Aksel Mjøs 3 This version: August 25, 2011 1We thank The Norwegian Ministry of Finance and the Norwegian Tax Authorities for generous provisioning of data and Finansmarkedsfondet for financing, and Terrence Hallahan, Jørgen Haug, Tore Leite, Ryu Nakagawa, Bent Value, and participants at the EFMA conference 2010, Arhus,˚ the FIBE 2011 conference in Bergen, Trondheim Business School lunch seminar, and the 2011 WEAI conference in San Diego, and internal seminar participants at the Norwegian School of Economics (NHH) for comments and suggestions. 2Department of Finance and Management Science, The Norwegian School of Economics (NHH), Helleveien 30, N-5045 Bergen (email:[email protected]) 3Department of Finance and Management Science, The Norwegian School of Economics (NHH), Helleveien 30, N-5045 Bergen (email:[email protected]) Abstract We study how firm-bank lending relationships affect firms’ access to and terms of credit. We use bank mergers and acquisitions (M&As) as exogenous events that affect lending relationships. Bank M&As lead to organisational changes at the involved banks, which may reduce the amount of soft information encompassed in the firm-bank relationship. Using a unique Norwegian dataset, which combines information on companies' bank accounts, annual accounts, bankruptcies, and bank M&As for the years 1997-2009, we find that domestic bank mergers increase interest rate margins by 0.24 percentage points for opaque small and medium sized firms, relative to less opaque firms. Since, due to information asymmetries, opaque firms are typically more dependent on bank lending relationships, our results indicate that these relationships are advantageous for such borrowers, and the destruction of a relationship during the merger process has adverse effects for the firm. Conversely, the results are not consistent with a lock-in effect due to an information monopoly by the relationship lender that on average increases a firm’s borrowing costs over its life cycle. The results are robust to the inclusion of variables that control for effects of market competition. 1 Introduction Salvaging the value of banks' relationships with their corporate customers has been put forward as one of the main reasons for bailing out banks during banking crises. Seminal work by Bernanke (1983) claimed that the destruction of such relationships contributed to the depth of the Great Depression in the US during the 1930s. This has spurred a large literature on relationship banking. One strand of this literature focuses on the information asymmetries between existing lenders and outside banks, which stem from banks possessing private information about their current debtors. A significant part of this private information is often "soft" in the sense that it is held by individual loan officers employed by the bank, and is not easily transferable to others, not even internally in the bank. This information asymmetry creates switching costs which limit businesses' ability to approach new lenders and thus realise benefits from competition between banks (Sharpe (1990), Rajan (1992), von Thadden (2004)). Another branch of the relationship banking literature is represented by Boot and Thakor (2000), where economic value is created through the lending relationship, and may be shared between banks and borrowers. If the effects from the first theory branch are more important, firms are adversely affected by banking relationships, while if the latter theory is dominating, relationships are beneficial to firms. Our paper aims to understand better which effect is more important in explaining firm-bank lending relationships. We use a dataset with the population of Norwegian firms and their banks for the period 1997-2009. Bank mergers and acquisitions (M&As) may lead to the loss of soft information in the involved banks. Stein (2002) develops a model where changes in loan officers’ responsibilities or lending guidelines following bank consolidations impair banks' abilities to grant credit based on soft information. Scott (2006) and Uchida, Udell, and Yamori (2011) provide evidence that loan officers play an important role in creating soft information about small firm borrowers, and that loan officer turnover reduces the likelihood that firms' credit applications are accepted. Bank M&As therefore provide exogenous events that affect the bank lending relationships. Changes in the merging banks' management, organisation, and strategy may lead to a deterioration in the banks' abilities to produce necessary relationship-related services, e.g., monitoring, at least in the short term. The bank may respond by increasing its interest rates or reducing its credit volumes to relationship-dependent customers. Bank M&As have several potential implications for borrowers. On the one hand, increased market concen- tration reduces competition among banks, with potentially negative effects for customers. On the other hand, efficiency gains, realised in larger, restructured banks, may to some extent be passed on to the bor- 1 rower. These effects are not necessarily related to relationship banking. To isolate and identify the effects that bank M&As have on lending relationships, we analyse how these M&As affect relationship-dependent borrowers relative to less relationship-dependent borrowers. In the literature1, size is commonly seen as an indicator of information asymmetry, whilst tangible assets may be used as loan collateral and thus reduce the overall importance of information asymmetry to a bank lender. Smaller firms and firms with fewer assets pledgeable as collateral are therefore expected to be less transparent and more dependent on banking relationships. By investigating the effect of the M&A events on relationship-dependent borrowers' access to credit, we can separate the following two hypotheses: 1. If the firm suffers from a detrimental lock-in effect due to an information monopoly prior to the bank M&A event, the firm’s access to credit will improve ex post. (I.e., banking relationships have a negative net effect.) 2. Alternatively, if the firm benefits from a banking relationship, the firm’s access to credit will deteri- orate ex post. (I.e., banking relationships have a positive net effects.) In particular, we expect the largest effects on the interest rates charged by the banks, rather than on credit volumes. Interest rates are easily changed on a few weeks' notice, while changes in loan amounts are determined by existing loan contracts as long as the loan is not defaulted. For example, if the firm benefits from a lending relationship, the loss of soft information during the merger process may lead the bank to use automatic pricing schedules, which take the "winner's curse" problem into account, rather than relying on soft information that would have indicated a lower interest rate. To our knowledge, ours is the first paper to use this approach to investigate which of these effects is the more salient to the firm. Our results suggest that the positive effects related to the second hypothesis outweigh any negative effects related to the first hypothesis. We find that for borrowing companies whose main bank is involved in a bank merger event, informationally opaque firms pay 0.24 percentage points higher interest rate margins on their total bank loans in the year of the merger. This is relative to a sample median interest rate margin of 3.0 percent. This effect is still present after we control for effects of the M&As related to market concentration and competition. We also find that relationship-dependent borrowers of acquired banks (i.e., targets in M&A transactions) are less likely to obtain new bank loans following the bank M&A event. In our test, we control for firm-, bank-, and loan market characteristics, 1See, e.g., Freixas and Rochet (2008 (2nd ed.)), for an introductory overview. 2 and firm-, M&A event-, and year fixed effects. Our results indicate that lending relationships are valuable for the firms. The rest of this paper is organised as follows: Section 2 reviews the theoretical background. Section 3 describes the data set. The empirical analysis is shown in Section 4. Finally, Section 5 concludes. 2 Theoretical and Empirical Framework 2.1 Relationship Lending There is no universally accepted, precise definition of relationship banking in the literature. Freixas and Rochet (2008 (2nd ed.)) define relationship banking as "the investment in providing financial services that will allow dealing repeatedly with the same customer in a more efficient way." This definition is not specific on how to identify a lending relationship empirically. Bank lending may be split into two broad categories: relationship lending and transactional lending. Relationship lending occurs when banks acquire proprietary information about its borrowers throughout the duration of the relationship. The alternative lending technology is transactional bank lending, where the bank is simply a passive intermediary in channelling funds from savers to borrowers, without any proprietary information. It is hard to empirically directly distinguish between these two types of lending technologies without detailed data on the type of interactions and production of information which occur between the banks and the borrowing firms. Early contributions to the relationship literature are Sharpe (1990) and Rajan (1992). They show how monitoring by a bank lender can lead to an textitex post information monopoly for the incumbent bank lender. The current bank lender has more information about its borrowers than bank competitors textitex post. These competitors will therefore take into account adverse selection problems when being approached by a loan applicant who is borrowing or has recently borrowed from the incumbent bank. Since competing banks are unable to fully distinguish between firms of good versus bad credit quality, they must offer a single interest rate2, at which high credit quality borrowers must subsidise poor credit quality borrowers.
Details
-
File Typepdf
-
Upload Time-
-
Content LanguagesEnglish
-
Upload UserAnonymous/Not logged-in
-
File Pages42 Page
-
File Size-