Precautionary Savings, Liquidity Constraints, and Self-Control

Precautionary Savings, Liquidity Constraints, and Self-Control

PRECAUTIONARY SAVINGS,LIQUIDITY CONSTRAINTS, AND SELF-CONTROL Jón Steinsson University of California, Berkeley Fall 2020 Steinsson Consumption 1 / 55 THREE IMPORTANT IDEAS Precautionary Saving Liquidity Constraints Self-Control Problems Steinsson Consumption 2 / 55 Very extreme model: Savings behavior unaffected by uncertainty!! Consumption smoothing and intertemporal substitution only forces affecting savings (same thing for linearized or log-linearized models) CERTAINTY EQUIVALENCE Suppose for simplicity β(1 + r) = 1 Consumption Euler equation: 0 0 U (Ct ) = Et U (Ct+1) With quadratic utility: Ct = Et Ct+1 This implies certainty equivalence: Ct depends only on Et Ct+1 not vart (Ct+1) (or any higher moments) Steinsson Consumption 3 / 55 CERTAINTY EQUIVALENCE Suppose for simplicity β(1 + r) = 1 Consumption Euler equation: 0 0 U (Ct ) = Et U (Ct+1) With quadratic utility: Ct = Et Ct+1 This implies certainty equivalence: Ct depends only on Et Ct+1 not vart (Ct+1) (or any higher moments) Very extreme model: Savings behavior unaffected by uncertainty!! Consumption smoothing and intertemporal substitution only forces affecting savings (same thing for linearized or log-linearized models) Steinsson Consumption 3 / 55 QUADRATIC UTILITY AND RISK With quadratic utility, utility cost of given variance of consumption independent of the level of consumption Amount of curvature of utility independent of level Jensen’s inequality term independent of the level But marginal utility falls with level of consumption Thus, with quadratic utility, consumer is willing to pay more to avoid a given amount of uncertainty (particular dollar coin toss) the richer he/she is Quadratic utility implies increasing absolute risk aversion Steinsson Consumption 4 / 55 COMMON UTILITY FUNCTIONS Constant Relative Risk Aversion (CRRA): ( 1−γ C −1 if γ 6= 1 U(C) = 1−γ log C if γ = 1 U00(C)C Relative Risk Aversion = − = γ U0(C) Constant Absolute Risk Aversion (CARA): exp(AC) U(C) = − A U00(C) Absolute Risk Aversion = − = A U0(C) Steinsson Consumption 5 / 55 RISK AVERSION IN REALITY Increasing absolute risk aversion completely unrealistic Implications for portfolio allocation: CRRA: Constant share in risky assets CARA: Constant dollar amount in risky assets IARA: Decreasing dollar amount in risky assets as wealth increases In reality, richer people allocate larger share of wealth to risky assets Suggests decreasing relative risk aversion (DRRA) (CRRA not such a bad approximation) See Gollier (2001, ch 2.) for more detailed discussion of various forms of risk aversion. Steinsson Consumption 6 / 55 000 0 With U (Ct ) > 0, U (Ct ) is convex If Ct = Et Ct+1, then 0 0 0 0 U (Ct ) < Et U (Ct+1) (since U (Et Ct+1) < Et U (Ct+1)) Marginal reduction in Ct (increase in saving) increases utility This extra saving relative to certainty equivalent case is called precautionary saving PRECAUTIONARY SAVINGS Curvature of utility almost surely falls as consumption rises: 000 U (Ct ) > 0 What does this imply about savings? Steinsson Consumption 7 / 55 PRECAUTIONARY SAVINGS Curvature of utility almost surely falls as consumption rises: 000 U (Ct ) > 0 What does this imply about savings? 000 0 With U (Ct ) > 0, U (Ct ) is convex If Ct = Et Ct+1, then 0 0 0 0 U (Ct ) < Et U (Ct+1) (since U (Et Ct+1) < Et U (Ct+1)) Marginal reduction in Ct (increase in saving) increases utility This extra saving relative to certainty equivalent case is called precautionary saving Steinsson Consumption 7 / 55 Source: Romer (2019). 50-50 chance of CH and CL. Steinsson Consumption 8 / 55 Source: Romer (2019) Steinsson Consumption 9 / 55 PRUDENCE Definition: (Kimball, 1990) An agent is prudent if adding an uninsurable zero-mean risk to his/her future wealth raises his/her optimal savings Proposition: (Leland, 1968) An agent is prudent if and only if the marginal utility of future consumption is convex. Steinsson Consumption 10 / 55 LIQUIDITYCONSUMPTIONCONSTRAINTS OVER THE LIFE CYCLE 67 Thousandsof 1987 dollars 27 Consumption(smoothed) 26 O Consumption(raw) 25- 21 17 , , l , , l l 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 Age FIGURESteinsson 2- Household consumptionConsumption and income over the life cycle. 11 / 55 Source: Gourinchas-Parker (2002). Takes out cohort and time effects. Family size held constant over life-cycle. and interest income and, as noted, those expenditures subtracted from consump- tion. The first two adjustments are saving in illiquid form and so are available to the household only after retirement. We remove asset income since the input to our theoretical model is a profile of income net of liquid asset returns. Consis- tent with the spirit of our model, all items removed from income involve a large amount of commitment and are hard to substitute intertemporally. Finally, we put all data into real 1987 dollars using the Gross Domestic Product implicit price deflator for personal consumption expenditures.31 5.3. Life Cycle Profiles Figure 2 presents consumption (raw and smoothed) and income profiles for our entire sample when the family-size is held constant over the life-cycle. Even after correcting for the effects of cohort, time, and family, both profiles are still hump shaped and track each other early in life. Consumption lies above income over the late twenties. Given that the CEX wealth data, and better household wealth surveys, show modest increases in liquid wealth over these ranges, this fea- ture seems likely due to misreporting of income or consumption. One possibility is underreporting the assistance that is provided by intergenerational transfers early in life. After these first few years, consumption rises with income from age 30 to age 45, when consumption drops significantly below income. This tracking is however a lot less than is observed in profiles constructed by simply averaging cross-sections because we control for changes in family size and cohorts effects. 31 t is important not to use different deflators for income and consumption. This could break the relationship between cash on hand and consumption in nominal terms, which is the relationlship predicted by the buffer-stock theory. This content downloaded from 160.39.33.139 on Sun, 12 Apr 2015 02:24:22 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions LIQUIDITY CONSTRAINTS Consumption smoothing over the life-cycle likely involves substantial borrowing early in life Simple PIH/LCH model assumes people can borrow (unsecured) at same rate as they can save Highly unrealistic: Most household borrowing is secured (e.g., mortgages, car loans) Interest rates on car loans and even mortgages substantially higher than on savings accounts Interest rates on unsecured consumer lending (i.e., credit cards) extremely high (∼ 20%) Limits on unsecured borrowing beyond which can’t go at any rate Steinsson Consumption 12 / 55 LIQUIDITY CONSTRAINTS Two effects of liquidity constraints: 1. Less borrowing when they bind 2. Less borrowing even when they don’t bind because they may bind in the future Bad shock tomorrow may cause low consumption due to binding liquidity constraint at that point Consumer saves today to “self-insure” against this future bad shock Steinsson Consumption 13 / 55 BUFFER STOCK SAVING Liquidity constraints and prudence cause households facing uninsurable income risk to engage in buffer stock saving (i.e., self-insurance) Other sources of saving: Life-cycle saving to smooth consumption over the life-cycle relative to life-cycle profile of income Saving due to patience/impatience. If 1/β 6= (1 + r) household will tilt consumption profile (down if impatient, up if patient) Steinsson Consumption 14 / 55 HOW MUCH BUFFER STOCK SAVING? Depends crucially on β(1 + r) If β(1 + r) = 1: Households will save themselves out of constraint I.e., save enough that they will eventually never hit constraint At that point, full consumption smoothing If β(1 + r) < 1 Households sufficiently impatient that they don’t eventually save themselves out of the constraint Finite amount of buffer stock savings Lack of full consumption smoothing even in the long run If β(1 + r) > 1: Asset holdings explode in the long run Steinsson Consumption 15 / 55 ZELDES-DEATON-CARROLL MODEL Households maximize 1 1−γ X C βt t ; E0 1 − γ t=0 subject to Wt+1 = R(Wt + Yt − Ct ] Yt = Pt Vt Pt = Pt−1Nt where Vt and Nt are i.i.d. log-normal random variables. R is given exogenously (partial equilibrium) Household income shocks are uninsurable See Zeldes (1989), Deaton (1991), Carroll (1992, 1997) Steinsson Consumption 16 / 55 ZELDES-DEATON-CARROLL MODEL Problem Set 2 asks you to solve a version of this model Zeldes-Deaton-Carroll argue that model helps explain: High MPC out of transitory windfalls That consumption tracks income over the life-cycle (need impatient households for this) Sometimes called the “buffer stock model” General equilibrium version called Bewely-Aiyagari-Hugget model Steinsson Consumption 17 / 55 OPTIMAL CONSUMPTION WITH STOCHASTIC INCOME 287 CCEQ 120 - I_ 1. d. and XL__ _ _ >\randomwalk -j 100 income(2) z 0 F 20 g 'i.id. income (#i A 0~ m 60 - 100 200 300 400 500 600 WEALTHLEVEL T=15 IncomeProcesses: #IA,# 2 C1-A A=3 Expectedfuture income equals iOper period U 1-A Source: Zeldes (1989) FIGURE II Steinsson Optimal Consumption forConsumption Two Different Income Processes 18 / 55 The first example uses distribution #2, the combination ran- dom walk/i.i.d. process. The time horizon is 15 periods, and the coefficient of relative risk aversion is set equal to three.23 Consump- tion as a function of initial financial assets is plotted as the middle line in Figure II. Both initial income and expected income in all future periods are equal to 100. The results, especially at low levels of assets, are quite striking. First, notice that the slope of the curve, which is equal to the marginal propensity to consume out of a transitory change in income, is considerably larger than that pre- dicted by certainty equivalence.

View Full Text

Details

  • File Type
    pdf
  • Upload Time
    -
  • Content Languages
    English
  • Upload User
    Anonymous/Not logged-in
  • File Pages
    62 Page
  • File Size
    -

Download

Channel Download Status
Express Download Enable

Copyright

We respect the copyrights and intellectual property rights of all users. All uploaded documents are either original works of the uploader or authorized works of the rightful owners.

  • Not to be reproduced or distributed without explicit permission.
  • Not used for commercial purposes outside of approved use cases.
  • Not used to infringe on the rights of the original creators.
  • If you believe any content infringes your copyright, please contact us immediately.

Support

For help with questions, suggestions, or problems, please contact us