Punishment and Cooperation in Nature

Punishment and Cooperation in Nature

Review Punishment and cooperation in nature 1,2 3 4 Nichola J. Raihani , Alex Thornton and Redouan Bshary 1 Department of Genetics, Evolution and Environment, University College London, Gower St, London, WC1E 6BT, UK 2 Institute of Zoology, Zoological Society London, Regent’s Park, London, NW1 4RY, UK 3 Department of Experimental Psychology, University of Cambridge, Downing St, Cambridge, CB2 EB, UK 4 Universite´ de Neuchaˆ tel, UniMail, Institut de Biologie, Eco-Ethologie, Rue Emilie-Argand 11, CH-2000, Neuchaˆ tel, Switzerland Humans use punishment to promote cooperation in In doing so, the punisher reduces the payoffs of the cheat laboratory experiments but evidence that punishment and thereby promotes cooperative behaviour from the plays a similar role in non-human animals is compara- cheat in subsequent interactions (Box 1). Thus, punish- tively rare. In this article, we examine why this may be ment is equivalent to ‘negative reciprocity’ [1,14]. This the case by reviewing evidence from both laboratory functional definition is useful for studying punishment experiments on humans and ecologically relevant stud- among non-human animals because punishment is not ies on non-human animals. Generally, punishment contingent on a capacity for mental state attribution and appears to be most probable if players differ in strength does not require the punisher to be aware of how its or strategic options. Although these conditions are com- behaviour might influence that of the target [1]. Punishers mon in nature, punishment (unlike other forms of ag- need not always be involved in the initial interaction with gression) involves immediate payoff reductions to both the cheat. For example, in ‘policing’ or ‘third party punish- punisher and target, with net benefits to punishers ment’, a bystander observes a cheat and is willing to reduce contingent on cheats behaving more cooperatively in its own current payoffs to reduce the payoff to the cheat. It future interactions. In many cases, aggression yielding is still largely unclear how punishers benefit from third- immediate benefits may suffice to deter cheats and party punishment, however [14–18]. might explain the relative scarcity of punishment in As with punishment, some other control mechanisms also nature. rely on responses to cheating that reduce the payoffs to cheats. However, unlike punishment, such responses do Punishment in nature: unresolved issues not necessarily reduce the current payoffs of the actor. Individuals are often tempted to cheat in social interac- Instead, several responses to cheating described in the tions, thereby gaining a benefit at the expense of coopera- literature are immediately self-serving and, hence, do not tive partners. To encourage partners to behave relyonfuturebenefits arisingfromtheincreasedcooperative cooperatively, individuals might therefore use control behaviour of the target to be under positive selection. These mechanisms that render cooperative behaviour a more examples do not fit the negative reciprocity concept but are profitable option than cheating for the partner. One such mechanism is punishment (see Glossary) [1]. Several lab- Glossary oratory studies have shown that punishment promotes Centralised punishment: punishment devolved to a legitimate authority. cooperation among humans, typically using stylised labo- Coercion: occurs when one player is forced into interacting with and ratory games (e.g. [2–6]). By comparison, only a handful of cooperating with an aggressive partner. Under coercion, the coerced individual studies have shown that punishment promotes cooperation would do better to terminate the interaction but is somehow prevented from doing so. among non-human animals [7–11]. This relative paucity of Negative pseudo-reciprocity: occurs when a cheating behaviour by one evidence prompted arguments about why initial predic- individual allows the partner to perform a self-serving response, which harms tions that punishment should be common [1] do not fit the cheating individual as a byproduct. Negative reciprocity: see punishment. current data [12,13]. Peer punishment: punishment carried out by other members of the social Here, we critically assess empirical evidence for pun- group of a cheat. Prisoner’s dilemma games: two-player games in which players have the option ishment in non-human species. We first outline how pun- to either cooperate or defect. In a one-shot game, players receive the highest ishment can be distinguished from other forms of payoff from defecting, regardless of the behaviour of the partner. However, aggression that promote cooperative behaviour, such as mutual payoffs are highest when both players cooperate. Public goods games (PGGs): players are endowed with an initial sum of coercion and sanctions, and then go on to discuss specific money, some or all of which they may contribute to the communal pot. empirical examples of punishment. We end by discussing Contributions to the communal pot are increased by the experimenter and then the conditions that are likely to favour punishment over divided among all players in the game, regardless of who contributed. In these games, the most profitable strategy is to withhold contributions and ‘free-ride’ alternative control mechanisms and whether these condi- on the investments of others. tions are likely to be met in non-human species. Punishment: occurs when an individual reduces its own current payoffs to harm a cheating partner. In doing so, the punisher reduces the payoffs to the What is (and what is not) punishment? cheat and thereby promotes cooperative behaviour from the cheat in subsequent interactions. Following the seminal paper by Clutton-Brock and Parker Sanctions: one form of negative pseudoreciprocity. Sanctions occur when two [1], we assert that punishment occurs when an individual or more players interact and one player cheats by withholding investment. The reduces its own current payoffs to harm a cheating partner. cheated partner then performs a self-serving behaviour to terminate the interaction, which harms the cheating partner as a byproduct. Corresponding author: Raihani, N.J. ([email protected]). 288 0169-5347/$ – see front matter ß 2012 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved. doi:10.1016/j.tree.2011.12.004 Trends in Ecology and Evolution, May 2012, Vol. 27, No. 5 Review Trends in Ecology and Evolution May 2012, Vol. 27, No. 5 Box 1. Payoffs associated with punishment and sanctions Figure I shows categories of interactions among non-kin. The arrows indicate the initial instigator and recipient and the + or À signs represent fitness changes (as in [1]). Punishment In punishment (Figure Ia), one individual cheats a partner, thereby increasing its immediate payoffs (++ relative to the payoff increase associated with cooperating, +) and imposing a fitness cost, À, on the partner. The partner then retaliates with a behaviour that reduces its immediate payoffs further, À, which imposes a fitness cost on the cheat. The fitness costs experienced by the cheat can be equal to (À) or greater than (ÀÀ) the payoff losses to the punisher of executing the punishment. In response to punishment, the cheat behaves more cooperatively in subsequent interactions with the punisher. Note that the cooperative interaction is mutually beneficial (in fitness terms) to both players compared to outside options (not interacting) but that, in the absence of punishment, the cheat could gain higher payoffs from exploiting a cooperative partner. Also note that some effects are on TRENDS in Ecology & Evolution lifetime fitness (the effects of being cheated, of being punished and of mutual cooperation), whereas others are on immediate payoffs (the Figure II. A coral-dwelling goby. Dominant gobies sanction subordinates that effects of cheating and of punishing). In interactions where coopera- breach a defined size threshold by evicting them from the group. Reproduced, tive behaviour is binary, the cheating is simply the opposite of with permission, from Joao Paulo Krajewski. cooperative behaviour. In interactions where cooperative behaviour can be a continuous investment, then cheating can be defined as any investment that is less than the population mean [55]. from a territory or group also fits the sanctions concept. For example, in coral-dwelling gobies (Paragobiodon xanthosomus; Figure II) domi- Sanctions nant individuals sometimes evict similar-sized subordinates, because Sanctions (Figure Ib) occur when one individual cheats a partner, subordinates that grow too large can threaten the superior status of thereby gaining a payoff increase relative to cooperating [56]. In their dominant neighbour [62]. Dominant gobies benefit from evicting response, the partner performs a self-serving behaviour that imposes overgrown competitors without the need for subordinates to behave costs on the cheat as a byproduct (2). This self-serving behaviour also more cooperatively (by reducing growth rate) in future. Indeed, evictees serves to end the interaction. Thus, sanctions fit the concept of negative rarely return to their group and there is therefore little or no potential for pseudo-reciprocity. We note that the term ‘sanction’ has also been used them to cooperate more in response to eviction from dominants. Noe¨ differently in the literature (e.g. [57–59]). Under the concept of [63] pointed out that sanctions often occur within a biological market in sanctions, there is no future to the interaction. Classic examples which individuals choose the best partner out of a possible range.

View Full Text

Details

  • File Type
    pdf
  • Upload Time
    -
  • Content Languages
    English
  • Upload User
    Anonymous/Not logged-in
  • File Pages
    8 Page
  • File Size
    -

Download

Channel Download Status
Express Download Enable

Copyright

We respect the copyrights and intellectual property rights of all users. All uploaded documents are either original works of the uploader or authorized works of the rightful owners.

  • Not to be reproduced or distributed without explicit permission.
  • Not used for commercial purposes outside of approved use cases.
  • Not used to infringe on the rights of the original creators.
  • If you believe any content infringes your copyright, please contact us immediately.

Support

For help with questions, suggestions, or problems, please contact us