Socialism Is Dead But Leviathan Lives On CIS Occasional Papers 30 Socialism Is Dead But Leviathan Lives On James M. Buchanan The Seventh John Bonython Lecture Delivered at the Sheraton Wenworth, Sydney 27 March, 1990 THE CENTRE FOR LNDEPENDENT STUDIES Published May 1990 by The Centre for Independent Studies Limited All rights reserved Views expressed in the publications of the Centre for Independent Studies are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the Centre's staff, Advisers, Trustees, Directors or officers. National Library of Australia Cataloguing-in-Publication Data Buchanan, James M. (James McGill). Socialism is dead but Leviathan lives on. ISBN 0 949769 57 6. 1. Socialism. I. Centre for Independent Studies (Australia). I. Title. (Series : CIS occasional papers; 30). (Series : John Bonython lectures; 7). Cover design by Hand Graphics O The Centre for Independent Studies Limited 1990 Opening em arks Michael Darling i Deputy Chairman, CIS Executive Board ADIES and Gentlemen, on behalf of the Centre for Independent Studies may I welcome you to the seventh annual John Bony- thon Lecture. The Lecture was established in 1984 with the aim mining the links between individuals and the economic, social and political elements that go to make up a free society. Even at a time when the number of free societies around the world is increasing, the underlying principles that constitute this freedom can never be taken for granted, and always repay close attention. The Lecture is named in honour of the first Chairman of the Board of Trustees of the Centre for Independent Studies, John Bonython. Mr Bonython, who is from Adelaide, was founding Chairman of Santos Ltd and was for many years Chairman of the Advertiser group of newspapers. Unfortunately, he is unable to travel from Adelaide to be with us tonight, but he sends his best wishes. We do have, however, our current Chairman of Trustees, Ian Roach, and a former Chairman of Trustees, Hugh Morgan. The John Bonython Lecture is given annually by a person, not necessarily a professional scholar, selected because of the valuable insights he or she may have developed in support of the fundamental objectives for which the Centre for Independent Studies has been established. The first Lecture was presented in Adelaide by Professor Israel Kirzner of New York University, and in the following years by Professor Max Hartwell, Lord Harris of High Cross, Mrs Shirley Robin Letwin, Dr Thomas Sowell, and Lord Peter Bauer. Tonight we are particularly fortunate to have a person of the eminence of Professor James Buchanan to deliver the 1990 John Bonython Lecture. We are also fortunate to have with us tonight Professor Geoffrey Brennan, of the Australian National University. He has been one of Professor Buchanan's closest colleagues, and has collaborated with him on two major books. I shall now invite him to introduce our guest. Professor Brennan. GeofErey Brennan Professor of Economics The Australian National Universiq Thank you, Michael. It is a very great personal pleasure for me tonight to welcome and introduce James Buchanan, Harris Professor of Economics in the Center for Study of Public Choice at George Mason University, Fairfax, Virginia. It's a particular pleasure because Jim is a good friend as well as a colleague, and because his work and his manner of doing it have long been a source of inspiration to me, something that was true well before we became colleagues in the mid- 1970s. It remains true now that our relationship has become a trans- Pacific one. There are many things that I could tell you about Jim - perhaps too many. I want to focus on just a couple. The first is this: When Jim won the Nobel Prize in 1986, he became thereby a kind of patron saint for outsiders. Perhaps Jim doesn't imagine himself naturally in the patron saint role, but it's certainly true that he didn't fit the Nobel pattern. For one thing, he was a Southerner, obstinately so, because he not only came from Tennessee originally, but after obtaining his doctorate at Chicago University he went back to the South - to Florida and then Virginia. And this was in a period in which, at least within the intellectual Establishment, the idea of a Southern intellec- tual was virtually a contradiction in terms. For another, Jim was a free- market economist when [he Academy was overwhelmingly leftist in disposition and strongly interventionist in its orientation. In addition, Jim never used fancy mathematics or econometrics, and indeed had always made clear his contempt for both in a profession increasingly preoccupied with its own technical tricks. His work in public choice - an area described by the Nobel citation as 'the synthesis of economic and political decision-mal<ingl- was in an area that was cordially regarded by the profession as eccentric, not to say ridicu- lous. So Jim over most of his career was an outsider; he was never recognised in the United States in quite the way that his North-Eastern intellectual Establishment contemporaries were. He'd swum for most of career very firmly against the tide, and the Nobel triumph was the more sweet for that. The second thing I want to tell you about Jim is embedded in a kind of riddle which Jim used to pose, occasionally at least, for job applicants and tenure candidates. It goes like this: Imagine that you have three mutually exclusive choices. Tomorrow you can be re- garded by the press and the politicians as the authoritative expert on all economic affairs. You'll be consulted, rung up by the press at 6 a.m., and so on, all the time for twelve months. That's one prospect. Or, in 30 years, you'll win the Nobel Prize. Or, in 200 years, historians of thought will look back and say that you, at this time, did important, significant work in this place. Which would you choose, given that you can only have one? Well, many people were puzzled by this, needless to say; many of them thought it was a problem in discount- ing, that you ought to prefer the earlier benefits to any later ones. Some of them thought, knowing that there is an important principle in economics of compromise - that indifference curves are supposed to be convex - that you ought to take the middle option. But for Jim there was only one option that was consistent with the academic vocation: that was the last. That orientation, that desire to engage in significant issues, issues that transcend the concerns of his profession at the time, has influenced and coloured Jim's work throughout his long career. I've told you these things not just to give you a context for Jim's lecture and tell you something about his history, but to make a slightly different point as well: which is that it is particularly suitable that Jim should be giving this Bonython lecture tonight under the aegis of CIS. I think Jim embodies in himself the two values that CIS stands for. First, the independence - the doing one's own thing, whatever the trends, and whatever the cost, and the love of ideas for their own sake; and second, a belief in the power of ideas to shape the world we live in, and finally to shape it for the better. Ladies and gentlemen, I give you James Buchanan. vil James Buchanan James M. Buchanan is Harris Professor of Economics at the Center for Study of Public Choice, George Mason University, Fairfax, Virginia. He has held academic posts at the University of Florida, the University of Virginia, the University of California, and the Virginia Polytechnic Institute. In 1986 he was awarded the Nobel Prize for Economics in recognition of his work on political processes. He is the author of numerous works on public choice, including The Calculus of Consent (1962; coauthored with Gordon Tullock); The Limits ofLiberty(1975); Freedom in Constitutional Contract (1977);The Powerto Tax(1980;coauthored with Geoffrey Brennan); The Reason of Rules (1985; coauthored with Geoffrey Brennan); and Liberty, Market andState(l986). He contributed the essay 'The Limits ofTaxationJto the 1982 CIS collection The Constitutional Challenge. Socialism Is Bead ]But Leviathan Lives On James M. Buchanan appreciate the opportunity to give this John Bonython Lecture, and especially to follow in that very distinguished succession of previous lecturers, all of whom are friends of mine. More than a century ago, Nietzsche announced the death of God. Behind the drama of its presentation, this statement was intended to suggest that the omnipresence of God no longer served as an organising principle for the lives of individuals or for the rules of their association, one with another. If we can disregard the revival of fundamentalism, notably in Islam, we can refer to this century as one 'without God'. And, indeed, many of the horrors that we have witnessed find at least some part of their explanation in the absence of human fear of a deity's wrath. I want to suggest here that, since Nietzsche, we have now passed through an interim period of history (roughly a century) during which, in one form or another, the God pronounced dead was replaced in man's consciousness by 'socialism', which seemed to provide, variously, the principle upon which individuals organ- ised their lives in civil society. And I want to match Nietzsche's an- nouncement with the comparable one that 'socialism is dead'. This statement seems much less shocking than the earlier one because it has and is being heard throughout the world in this year, 1990. I suggest, further, that the gap left by the loss of faith in socialism may, in some respects, be equally significant in effects to that which was described by the loss of faith in the deity.
Details
-
File Typepdf
-
Upload Time-
-
Content LanguagesEnglish
-
Upload UserAnonymous/Not logged-in
-
File Pages27 Page
-
File Size-