"Pigou Effect": Rendez-Vous with the Author1

"Pigou Effect": Rendez-Vous with the Author1

Munich Personal RePEc Archive Pigou and the "Pigou Effect": Rendez-Vous with the Author Melitz, Jacques Tulane University 1967 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/84890/ MPRA Paper No. 84890, posted 10 May 2018 13:17 UTC Pigou and the "Pigou Effect": Rendez-Vous with the Author1 Jacques Melitz Southern Economic Journal, Vol. 34, No. 2 (Oct., 1967), pp. 268-279 Summary: This article attempts to show that Pigou does not rely on the "wealth effect" in his attack on the doctrine of "unemployment equilibrium" with flexible money wages (a doctrine which, incidentally, he never considers clearly Keynesian). Instead, he depends on a form of "substitution effect," hinging on a change in the "convenience yield" on money relative to the yield on physical capital. This particular line of thought is much closer than the "wealth effect" to the sort of reasoning concerning stock adjustments to differences in yields which has become popular today. In this view of Pigou's position, the principal mechanism in his work for restoring full employment under flexible wages is the "substitution" rather than the "wealth effect" of wage-price reductions. The "substitution effect" requires a mere rise in the ratio of real money to real wealth, while the “wealth effect” requires a rise in real wealth. INTRODUCTION The "wealth effect" is generally considered as A. C. Pigou's basic reply to J. M. Keynes concerning possible "unemployment equilibrium" under flexible money wages. But a scrutiny of Pigou's major writings soon gives rise to a number of suspicions regarding this interpretation of his stand. For example, it is curious that in the one section of his 1943 article on "The Classical Stationary State"2 dealing with the impact of a general wage reduction on unemployment as such, he ignores the "wealth effect" and concentrates on a different argument. It is also odd that later in this article and throughout the 1947 companion piece on "Economic Progress in a Stationary Environment,"3 in treating the way in which the "wealth effect" eliminates an excess supply of commodities, Pigou assumes that there would be no un- employment in the first place if money wages were flexible downward. In addition, wherever the question of the impact of money wage reductions on unemployment occurs in Pigou's late writing, there is not the least allusion to the "wealth effect." He utilizes this effect strictly in order to analyze the case of a general over-production of commodities at a theoretical minimum interest rate. I will attempt to show here that Pigou does not rely on the "wealth effect" in his attack on the doctrine of "unemployment equilibrium" with flexible money wages (a doctrine which, incidentally, he never considers clearly Keynesian). Instead, he depends on a form of "substitution effect," hinging on a change in the "convenience yield" on money relative to the yield on physical capital. This particular line of thought is much closer than the "wealth effect" to the sort of reasoning concerning stock adjustments to differences in yields which has become popular today. In this view of Pigou's 1 I would like to thank the Social Science Research Council and the Tulane University Faculty Research Council for their support during the period of this study. I am also grateful to Professor William J. Baumol, and my colleague, Professor Seymour S. Goodman, for helpful comments. 2 Arthur C. Pigou (1943). 3 Pigou (1947), pp. 180-90. 1 position, the principal mechanism in his work for restoring full employment under flexible wages is the "substitution" rather than the "wealth effect" of wage-price reductions. It is important, therefore, to be clear at the start about the difference between these two effects, both of which pertain to an influence of a change in real money. The "substitution effect" requires a mere rise in the ratio of real money to real wealth, whereas the "wealth effect" hinges on a rise in total wealth. An increase in real balances necessarily raises the ratio of real money to total wealth (thus producing a movement in the relative yields on different assets), but may not augment total wealth. The reason is that, in a wage-price fall, private real indebtedness to the monetary sector may increase as much as the value of money balances, thus keeping total wealth the same. Therefore, though a "substitution effect" necessarily follows a wage-price reduction under constant money, there may be no "wealth effect." Further, the two effects must operate, at least in part, in different markets. In the immediate aftermath of a real balance change, the "substitution effect" cannot occur in the consumption goods market. Any influence on consumption requires a movement in the general yield on wealth relative to consumption, whereas initially, a rise in real balances only affects the yield on a few particular assets. Consequently, immediately after a real balance change, if tastes and productivity are unchanged, all movements out of assets into consumption (as opposed to movements between assets) must be attributable to a variation in total wealth. On the frequent assumption of no "budget restraint" among firms, furthermore, there never can be a "wealth effect" on the demand for physical investment. In accord with these distinctions Pigou relates the "substitution effect" to the demand for investment goods but not desired saving, while strictly applying the "wealth effect" to the consumption demand in the commodities market. Still the issue may appear to be basically of historical interest. There is, however, an important analytical question involved. One major assumption of the Keynesian debate, still thriving in many quarters, is that the so-called "liquidity trap" leaves no room for any legitimate criticism of Keynes besides the "wealth effect." If so, Pigou's "convenience yield effect" is an invalid objection to Keynes's theory under the "liquidity trap." Per contra, however, I will try to show that Pigou's argument holds in this case. On this view, the dramatic postwar emphasis on the "wealth effect" respecting Keynes has been much exaggerated. First in order of presentation will be Pigou's famous 1943 and 1947 contributions to the Economic Journal and Eco- nomica, which have been the center of attention thus far. Next we will also examine the evidence from Pigou's other writings. In the final section, the focus will be on the validity of Pigou's treatment in the context of Keynes's peculiar interest rate floor. MAIN TESTAMENTS As Pigou makes clear in the first few pages of "The Classical Stationary State," this article is a response to a few critical passages in Alvin Hansen's Fiscal Policy and Business Cycles,4 which develop the important yet secondary theme of the General Theory that highly industrialized countries have a secular tendency toward a position of "unemployment equilibrium." According to Hansen, the classicists were right in 4 Alvin Hansen (1941), p. 288. See also pp. 334-35. 2 arguing that there is a long run tendency toward zero net investment, but they were wrong in supposing that this "stationary" equilibrium position is necessarily one of full employment. Due to the strength of saving habits, "stationary equilibrium" might be attainable only at levels of output far below those which the economy has the capacity to produce. Consequently, the "classical stationary state" might involve large-scale unemployment. In reply, Pigou first explains that under usual classical conditions, which require equality of the rate of interest and the marginal rate of time preference in equilibrium, the interest rate mechanism would suffice to bring about equilibrium in the commodities market. He maintains, however, that this classical view hinges on the assumption that people save only for the sake of future income receipts. Contrary to this view, though, Pigou considers that people save partly for safety reasons and for purposes such as prestige. In the light of these further motives, equilibrium can be said to hold only when the marginal rate of time preference equals a certain "amenity yield" plus the market rate of return.5 Saving then may be positive at a zero rate of interest, since at this rate the "amenity yield" on saving might outweigh the positive marginal rate of time preference (favoring consumption). Therefore, a position of "stationary equilibrium," where desired saving and desired investment are zero, may require a negative rate of interest. A negative rate of interest, however, is impossible, because saving always can be made in the form of money, which Pigou regards as a sure means of earning a zero market rate of return.6 This brings Pigou to the central problem of his discussion: the possibility of an excess of desired saving over desired investment at all positive or zero interest rates. Before tackling this problem, however, Pigou turns briefly to Hansen's contention of the possibility of unemployment under flexible money wages in the stationary state, which he dismisses at the opening, saying: "It is not necessary to examine it [Hansen's argument] at any length."7 Since Pigou's argument on this point forms a central pillar of my revision, I may quote him at length: With any known type of banking system, and equally under an arrangement in which the stock of money is rigidly fixed, money income must be a function of the rate of interest, being lower or higher according as that rate is lower or higher. This follows from the fact that, for equilibrium, the convenience and so on yielded to the representative man by the marginal unit of resources held in the form of money must be equally attractive with the interest yielded by the marginal unit invested in real capital.

View Full Text

Details

  • File Type
    pdf
  • Upload Time
    -
  • Content Languages
    English
  • Upload User
    Anonymous/Not logged-in
  • File Pages
    16 Page
  • File Size
    -

Download

Channel Download Status
Express Download Enable

Copyright

We respect the copyrights and intellectual property rights of all users. All uploaded documents are either original works of the uploader or authorized works of the rightful owners.

  • Not to be reproduced or distributed without explicit permission.
  • Not used for commercial purposes outside of approved use cases.
  • Not used to infringe on the rights of the original creators.
  • If you believe any content infringes your copyright, please contact us immediately.

Support

For help with questions, suggestions, or problems, please contact us