Lecture 16: Applications of Subgame Perfect Nash Equilibrium

Lecture 16: Applications of Subgame Perfect Nash Equilibrium

Lecture 16: Applications of Subgame Perfect Nash Equilibrium Mauricio Romero Lecture 16: Applications of Subgame Perfect Nash Equilibrium Ultimatum Game Alternating offers Stackelberg Competition Lecture 16: Applications of Subgame Perfect Nash Equilibrium Ultimatum Game Alternating offers Stackelberg Competition 1. Player 1 makes a proposal (x; 1000 − x) of how to split 100 pesos among (100; 900);:::; (800; 200); (900; 100) 2. Player 2 accepts or rejects the proposal 3. If player 2 rejects both obtain 0. If 2 accepts, then the payoffs or the two players are determined by (x; 1000 − x) I In any SPNE, player 1 makes the proposal (900; 100) I In any pure strategy SPNE, player 2 accepts all offers I In any pure strategy SPNE, player 2 accepts all offers I In any SPNE, player 1 makes the proposal (900; 100) I When extreme offers like (900; 100) are made, player 2 rejects in many cases I Player 2 may care about inequality or positive utility associated with \punishment" aversion I This is far from what happens in reality I Player 2 may care about inequality or positive utility associated with \punishment" aversion I This is far from what happens in reality I When extreme offers like (900; 100) are made, player 2 rejects in many cases I This is far from what happens in reality I When extreme offers like (900; 100) are made, player 2 rejects in many cases I Player 2 may care about inequality or positive utility associated with \punishment" aversion Lecture 16: Applications of Subgame Perfect Nash Equilibrium Ultimatum Game Alternating offers Stackelberg Competition Lecture 16: Applications of Subgame Perfect Nash Equilibrium Ultimatum Game Alternating offers Stackelberg Competition I The players would rather get an agreement today than tomorrow (i.e., discount factor) I Two players are deciding how to split a pie of size 1 I Two players are deciding how to split a pie of size 1 I The players would rather get an agreement today than tomorrow (i.e., discount factor) I Player 2 accepts or rejects the proposal I If player 2 rejects, player 2 makes an offer θ2 I If player 1 accepts or rejects the proposal I If player 1 rejects, player 1 makes an offer θ3 I ... and on and on for T periods I If no offer is ever accepted, both payoffs equal zero I Player 1 makes an offer θ1 I If player 2 rejects, player 2 makes an offer θ2 I If player 1 accepts or rejects the proposal I If player 1 rejects, player 1 makes an offer θ3 I ... and on and on for T periods I If no offer is ever accepted, both payoffs equal zero I Player 1 makes an offer θ1 I Player 2 accepts or rejects the proposal I If player 1 accepts or rejects the proposal I If player 1 rejects, player 1 makes an offer θ3 I ... and on and on for T periods I If no offer is ever accepted, both payoffs equal zero I Player 1 makes an offer θ1 I Player 2 accepts or rejects the proposal I If player 2 rejects, player 2 makes an offer θ2 I If player 1 rejects, player 1 makes an offer θ3 I ... and on and on for T periods I If no offer is ever accepted, both payoffs equal zero I Player 1 makes an offer θ1 I Player 2 accepts or rejects the proposal I If player 2 rejects, player 2 makes an offer θ2 I If player 1 accepts or rejects the proposal I ... and on and on for T periods I If no offer is ever accepted, both payoffs equal zero I Player 1 makes an offer θ1 I Player 2 accepts or rejects the proposal I If player 2 rejects, player 2 makes an offer θ2 I If player 1 accepts or rejects the proposal I If player 1 rejects, player 1 makes an offer θ3 I If no offer is ever accepted, both payoffs equal zero I Player 1 makes an offer θ1 I Player 2 accepts or rejects the proposal I If player 2 rejects, player 2 makes an offer θ2 I If player 1 accepts or rejects the proposal I If player 1 rejects, player 1 makes an offer θ3 I ... and on and on for T periods I Player 1 makes an offer θ1 I Player 2 accepts or rejects the proposal I If player 2 rejects, player 2 makes an offer θ2 I If player 1 accepts or rejects the proposal I If player 1 rejects, player 1 makes an offer θ3 I ... and on and on for T periods I If no offer is ever accepted, both payoffs equal zero The discount factor is δ ≤ 1: If Player 1 offer is accepted by Player 2 in round m, m π1 = δ θm; m π2 = δ (1 − θm): If Player 2 offer is accepted, reverse the subscripts The player that makes the last offer gets the whole pie I Last-mover advantage I There is a unique SPNE: I Consider first the game without discounting I Last-mover advantage The player that makes the last offer gets the whole pie I Consider first the game without discounting I There is a unique SPNE: I Last-mover advantage The player that makes the last offer gets the whole pie I Consider first the game without discounting I There is a unique SPNE: I Consider first the game without discounting I There is a unique SPNE: The player that makes the last offer gets the whole pie I Last-mover advantage I Assume Player 1 makes the last offer I In period T , if it is reached, Player 1 would offer 0 to Player 2 I Player 2 would accept (indifferent between accepting and rejecting) I In period (T − 1), Player 2 could offer Smith δ, keeping (1 − δ) for himself I Player 1 would accept (indifferent between accepting and rejecting) since the whole pie in the next period is worth δ I In the game with discounting, the total value of the pie is 1 in the first period, δ in the second, and so forth I In period T , if it is reached, Player 1 would offer 0 to Player 2 I Player 2 would accept (indifferent between accepting and rejecting) I In period (T − 1), Player 2 could offer Smith δ, keeping (1 − δ) for himself I Player 1 would accept (indifferent between accepting and rejecting) since the whole pie in the next period is worth δ I In the game with discounting, the total value of the pie is 1 in the first period, δ in the second, and so forth I Assume Player 1 makes the last offer I Player 2 would accept (indifferent between accepting and rejecting) I In period (T − 1), Player 2 could offer Smith δ, keeping (1 − δ) for himself I Player 1 would accept (indifferent between accepting and rejecting) since the whole pie in the next period is worth δ I In the game with discounting, the total value of the pie is 1 in the first period, δ in the second, and so forth I Assume Player 1 makes the last offer I In period T , if it is reached, Player 1 would offer 0 to Player 2 I In period (T − 1), Player 2 could offer Smith δ, keeping (1 − δ) for himself I Player 1 would accept (indifferent between accepting and rejecting) since the whole pie in the next period is worth δ I In the game with discounting, the total value of the pie is 1 in the first period, δ in the second, and so forth I Assume Player 1 makes the last offer I In period T , if it is reached, Player 1 would offer 0 to Player 2 I Player 2 would accept (indifferent between accepting and rejecting) I Player 1 would accept (indifferent between accepting and rejecting) since the whole pie in the next period is worth δ I In the game with discounting, the total value of the pie is 1 in the first period, δ in the second, and so forth I Assume Player 1 makes the last offer I In period T , if it is reached, Player 1 would offer 0 to Player 2 I Player 2 would accept (indifferent between accepting and rejecting) I In period (T − 1), Player 2 could offer Smith δ, keeping (1 − δ) for himself I In the game with discounting, the total value of the pie is 1 in the first period, δ in the second, and so forth I Assume Player 1 makes the last offer I In period T , if it is reached, Player 1 would offer 0 to Player 2 I Player 2 would accept (indifferent between accepting and rejecting) I In period (T − 1), Player 2 could offer Smith δ, keeping (1 − δ) for himself I Player 1 would accept (indifferent between accepting and rejecting) since the whole pie in the next period is worth δ I Player 2 would accept since he can earn (1 − δ) in the next period, which is worth δ(1 − δ) today I In period (T − 3), Player 2 would offer Player 1 δ[1 − δ(1 − δ)], keeping (1 − δ[1 − δ(1 − δ)]) for himself I Player 1 would accept... I ... I In equilibrium, the very first offer would be accepted, since it is chosen precisely so that the other player can do no better by waiting I In period (T − 2), Player 1 would offer Player 2 δ(1 − δ), keeping (1 − δ(1 − δ)) for himself I In period (T − 3), Player 2 would offer Player 1 δ[1 − δ(1 − δ)], keeping (1 − δ[1 − δ(1 − δ)]) for himself I Player 1 would accept..

View Full Text

Details

  • File Type
    pdf
  • Upload Time
    -
  • Content Languages
    English
  • Upload User
    Anonymous/Not logged-in
  • File Pages
    115 Page
  • File Size
    -

Download

Channel Download Status
Express Download Enable

Copyright

We respect the copyrights and intellectual property rights of all users. All uploaded documents are either original works of the uploader or authorized works of the rightful owners.

  • Not to be reproduced or distributed without explicit permission.
  • Not used for commercial purposes outside of approved use cases.
  • Not used to infringe on the rights of the original creators.
  • If you believe any content infringes your copyright, please contact us immediately.

Support

For help with questions, suggestions, or problems, please contact us