
BACKGROUND TO THE KKOIKHOI REBELLION OF 1799-1803 by Susie Newton-King Nearly every potted histoxy of South Africa begins with the observation that the initial purpose of white settlement in the region was to provide a source of fresh provisions to the ships of the Dutch East India Company. It is also generally agreed that, owing to a combination of factors, such as the nature of shipping demand, the price of grain in Ebmpe and Batavia, the inferior quality of Cape wines, the aridity of the Cape hinterland and the difficulties of transport (l), the prime importance of the Cape to East Indian commerce, apart from its strategic position, lay in its role as a supplier of meat. But what is now under dispute is the extent to which the market for meat and other pastoral products conditioned the expansion and social organization of white settlement in the interior of the Colony. S. D. Neumark has argued that there was a direct relationship between the pace of colonial expansion and the fluctuations in shipping demand at the Cape, and hence, by implication, that the settler economy was highly responsive to market forces. (2) Leonard Guelke, by contrast, argues that frontier expansion depended on demographic pressure rather than on market demand, that market forces were weak in the interior (g), and that this, combined with the ready availability of land, created an egalitarian and homogeneous settler comm~ty.(4) Clearly an analysis of the background to the Khoikhoi rebellion of 1799 will be seriously lacking unless the questions raised by this debate are answered, for the rebels were servants of stock-farmers on the eastern frontier; but I would contend that an answer adequate to this specific purpose must await a detailed exsunination of the economies of individual farms and farming localities in the region concerned, such as has not yet been attempted. Pending the attempt, it must suffice to say that the market for livestock and other pastoral products (and products of the hunt) was an ever-present factor in the frontier econony and that, while it may not have been a sufficient cause of expansion, it did affect "the ww in which men, women and children were set to workf1. (5) During the first 40 to 50 years of the Colony's existence, the bulk of the Company's livestock requirements were met by the Khoikhoi of the western Cape. The Companps initial intention was that the free bw&ers should supply arable products rather than livestock: it is well known that cattle barter between burghers and Khoikhoi was strictly prohibited. However, the exchange between Company and Xhoikhoi, which became overtly coercive in the later years of the 17th century and which was accompanied by direct intervention in Khoikhoi politics, initiated a process of economic decline which eventually reduced the western Cape Khoikhoi to poverty and permanent dependence on the Colony. (6) The official trade in itself was not of sufficient magnitude, in relation to the size of Khoikhoi herds, to bring about irrevocable impoverishment (7), but the official trade was supplemented by the seizure of cattle and sheep as tribute or booty in war, and, by the late 1680s and 16908, by an escalation in illegal trading and robbery on the part of freemen. (8) The impact of this increasing drain of livestock was the greater because cattle and sheep in Khoikhoi society were owned by families and individuals, not by the community as a whole. (9) The loss of breeding stock could have very serious consequences for a family with a small herd, and political disintegration made it difficult to recoup stock losses in battle. Against this background of Khoikhoi impoverishment the Company opened the stock trade to freemen (in 1700) and, for the first time, allowed the expansion of white settlement into the hinterland north of Drakenstein. (10) Thus was the moving white cattle frontier encouraged and given sanction. Thenceforth, Khoikhoi in the line of the graziers' advance were to suffer from dispossession of their pastures and watering places and loss of their stock on a scale unknown in the 17th century. Under these condition, the boundaries between Khoikhoi herders and San or Sonqua hunter- gatherers, which had always been flexible (11) , became still more blurred. Some impoverished Khoikhoi or "Xhoisan" waged drawn-out guerilla campaigns against the invading settlers (12); others retreated inland with their herds; but many became employees or, more rarely, labour tenants, on white-owned farms. It could be argued that the Company's acquiescence in the displacement of its Xhoikhoi suppliers by white graziers involved more than capitulation to the importunities of the free burghers - that it implied a tacit recognition of differences in the modes of production of Khoikhoi communities, on the one hand, and Boers, on the other, and a realization that the latter were better equipped than the former to aid the Company in its pursuit of commercial gain. Kate Crehan has made a thorough and perceptive analysis of these differences, which can only be briefly summarized here. (13) First, she has shown that, in the early stages of colonization, Boer social units were dependent upon commodities acquired through exchange (on the monetized market of Cape own) to an extent which the Khoikhoi were not. (14) Boer herds were thus regarded by their owners as repositories of exchange value, thou& they also served as use-values in domestic consumption. For the Khoikhoi, livestock were first and foremost use-values, though some were exchanged against other goods. Second, she has shown how the institution of private land ownership in Boer society allowed for its division into a class of land-owning non-labourers, on the one hand, and landless labourers, on the other. (15) On the basis of this division, she argues, the colonists were able to appropriate a tradeable s&lus of livestock on a scale which was impossible in Xhoikhoi communities where land was communally owned.(l6) Nevertheless, these differences in the mode of production of the two groups cannot be used to explain the process of displacement and subjugation of the one by the other, under the aegis of merchant capital. Such an explanation would involve an unjustifiably static approach to modes of production. In the first place, while Khoikhoi dependence on commodities may have been sligbt in the 17th century, it increased with time: 18th century travellers and the colonists themselves exchanged a variety of manufactured goods against cattle (17); Khoikhoi illegally bartered horses from the colonists after this was prohibited. Indeed, by the 18th century the limited range of goods exchanged for Khoikhoi livestock in the official trade was a reflection of the Company's avarice as well as the wants of the Khoikhoi. Secondly, one cannot assume that the relations of production in Khoikhoi society were destined to inflexibility in the fac;e of market forces. Even within the "traditional" scheme of things individuals were able to accumulate large herds: Klaas and Koopman, 17th century Chainouqua Captains, did so as middle men for the Company (18); Scipio of the Peninsulars had more than 200 cows and 2,000 sheep in 1712. (19) As 'the colonists advanced, pushing the Khoikhoi from their lands, opportunities for the development of social differentiation within Khoikhoi society were inevitably curtailed, but they emerged and were utilized in the frontier communities of the Kamiesberg and Transorangia. Finally, it should be emphasized that the class divisions characteristic of Boer society were not given, but made. The colonists~assertion of private control over land and hence over the labour of its inhabitants was the product of constant struggle between themselves and the indigenous people. It has been remarked that this struggle was less violent than in similar situations elsewhere (20), because of the mobility and low density of Xhoikhoi and San populations and the fragmentation of Khoikhoi leadership in the face of manifold pressures. However, while military resistance to colonization was confined to border areas until the eastern rebellion of 1799, Xhoikhoi resistance to proletarianization took other less dramatic forms, such as stock theft, desertion and migration, the effect of which was the bewildering variety of social relations in frontier areas. In the last resort, however, force was the guarantor of colonial social relations. Whatever the historian's judgment, there was no doubt that in the eastern Cape at the turn of the 18th century this was how both colonists and Khoikhoi had come to see their situation. The eastern rebellion came after more than 30 years of interaction between whites and Xhoikhoi in the lands east of the Gamtoos River and south of the Sneeuwbergen. What follows is an account of these years. Neumark has argued that the number of foreign ships calling at the Cape was particularly important in stimulating the expansion of settlement, since the meat contractors were allowed to supply them at prices higher than those set by the Compq. (21) The late 1760s saw the beginning of an unprecedented rise in the number of foreign ships (see Appendix I), and it would seem likely that the rapid eastwards expansion of white settlement along the south-east coast beyond the Gamtoos River and along the mountains bordering the Great Karroo into the plains of Camdebo and the Sneeuwberg range was stimulated thereby; though Guelke has shown that a marked iacrease in the annual number of loan-places issued occurred in the 1760~~ before the shipping bo'om began. (22) In 1770 the south-eastern boundary of the Colony was moved to the Gamtoos river, but by this time a number of colonists had begun to graze their cattle in the exceptionally rich pastures between the Gamtoos and the Zwartkops rivers.
Details
-
File Typepdf
-
Upload Time-
-
Content LanguagesEnglish
-
Upload UserAnonymous/Not logged-in
-
File Pages12 Page
-
File Size-