Arsenault (2018) Vol. 9, No. 1 Spring / Printemps 2018 ANSERJ pp. 58 – 75 Canadian Journal of Nonprofit and Social Economy Research Revue canadienne de recherche sur les OBSL et l’économie social Explaining Québec’s Social Economy Turn Gabriel Arsenault Université de Moncton ABSTRACT Québec has been structuring and promoting a social economy sector since the mid-1990s. What explains this specificity of the Québec social model? Careful process tracing analysis reveals that the mobilization of Québec’s left in the mid- 1990s, followed by coalition engineering during the 1996 economy and employment summit, account for Québec’s distinct trajectory. Consistent with power resource theory (PRT), at the agenda-setting stage, protagonists of Québec’s social economy policies were associated with the left. Contrary to what is assumed by PRT, however, at the decision stage, the right’s consent to social economy policies was not conditioned by a weak bargaining position or by a fear of antagonizing voters. RÉSUMÉ Le Québec appuie et structure un secteur de l’économie sociale depuis le milieu des années 1990. Comment expliquer cette spécificité du modèle social québécois? Une analyse attentive du retraçage des processus révèle que la mobilisation de la gauche québécoise au milieu des années 1990, suivie d’une coalition autour de l’économie sociale formée au mo - ment du Sommet sur l’économie et l’emploi en 1996, expliquent la trajectoire distincte du Québec. De façon cohérente avec la théorie des ressources de pouvoir (PRT), à l’étape de la mise à l’agenda, les protagonistes des politiques visant à appuyer l’économie sociale au Québec étaient associés à la gauche. Contrairement à ce qui est supposé par la PRT, cependant, à l’étape de la prise de décision, l’appui de la droite à ces politiques ne reposait pas sur un faible rapport de force ou sur une crainte de s’aliéner les électeurs. KEYWORDS / MOtS clÉS : Social economy; Social policy; Québec; Power resources; Coalitions / Économie sociale; Politique sociale; Québec; Ressources de pouvoir; Coalitions INTRODUCTION This article highlights an overlooked distinctive feature of the Québec social model: the government institutionalization of the social economy. In the mid-to-late 1990s, the Québec welfare state took a veritable social economy turn by launch - ing, expanding, or consolidating various networks of social economy enterprises (SEEs), delivering subsidized social services, especially in the areas of childcare, home assistance, community housing, and social insertion (Vaillancourt, To be notified about new ANSERJ articles, subscribe here . / Afin d’être avisé des nouveaux 58 ANSERJ articles dans ANSERJ, s’inscrire ici . Arsenault (2018) 2013). No other province “adopted” the concept of the social economy to this extent (Downing & Charron, 2010). What accounts for Québec’s distinct trajectory? Surprisingly, this puzzle has received very little attention from students of the Canadian welfare state. Existing studies have sought to explain cross-provincial differences in only some of these sectors, including childcare (Haddow, 2015; Jenson, 2002) and home assistance (Jenson & Phillips, 2000; Tremblay & Vaillancourt, 2002). Also, while several studies have tangentially proposed causal explanations of Québec’s distinct general social economy turn (as further discussed below), no study has really focused on doing so. This article fills this gap by investigating how Québec first came to rec - ognize and promote the social economy sector. The article makes two main arguments. First, consistent with power resource theory (PRT) (Esping-Andersen, 1985), it argues that it was the left that put the social economy on the Québec government’s agenda in the mid-1990s. In particular, pressures from the women’s movement and a major union federation, the Confédération des syndicats nationaux (CSN), led to the creation of a task force on the social economy during the 1996 economy and employment summit. Second, it argues that the concertation setting of the 1996 summit enabled a left/right coalition on the social economy. More specif - ically, the social economy projects proposed by the task force satisfied both the left and the right as they were thought to create jobs and address unmet social needs while infringing upon neither the public nor the private sector. Contrary to what is assumed by PRT (Korpi, 2006), the right’s consent was not conditioned by a weak bargaining position or by a fear of antagonizing voters. The remainder of this article is divided into six sections. The first clarifies the concept of the social economy and introduces Québec’s social economy policies; the second outlines the main hypotheses possibly accounting for Québec’s distinct trajectory; the third explicates the methodological approach employed; the fourth and main section tests the hypotheses; the fifth explores alternative explanations; the sixth concludes the article. QUÉBEC’S SOCIAL ECONOMY POLICIES In Québec, the “social economy” broadly refers to co-operatives, mutual societies, and nonprofits providing goods or ser - vices in the market (Groupe de travail sur l’économie sociale, 1996; Québec, 2013). Self-recognized SEEs typically also share certain ideals, such as to provide “genuinely” useful goods and services (in contrast to simply responding to the demands of a consumerist society) and to have democratic or empowering governance (Groupe de travail sur l’économie sociale, 1996; Québec, 2013). Identification to the social economy is thus highly political, and actors on the ground con - stantly debate and negotiate whether specific organizations satisfy the ideals of the social economy. The Québec gov - ernment nonetheless estimates that there are over 7,000 social economy enterprises in the province, representing about four percent of total employment (Québec, 2015). A strategic economic sector In March of 1996, at the Conference on the Social and Economic Future of Québec, where social partners agreed on the short-term priorities of stimulating employment and eliminating the public deficit, the government decided to establish three task forces: one on the private sector, presided over by pharmacy magnate Jean Coutu; one on the social economy (Groupe de travail sur l’économie sociale [GTES]), presided over by Nancy Neamtan, who then represented the Coalition des organismes communautaires pour le développement de la main-d’oeuvre; and one on Montréal, presided over by André Bérard, then leading the National Bank. 1 When the GTES presented its recommendations the following October during the summit’s second phase, a large consensus between community groups, unions, employers, and government officials formed around the necessity to promote the social economy (Lévesque, 2013). To be notified about new ANSERJ articles, subscribe here . / Afin d’être avisé des nouveaux 59 ANSERJ articles dans ANSERJ, s’inscrire ici . Arsenault (2018) This article focuses on this critical juncture. Giovanni Capoccia (2015) identifies three key steps to the study of critical junctures. First, there needs to be a “phase of political uncertainty in which different options for radical institutional change are viable” (p. 151). As emphasized below, the 1996 economy and employment summit constituted such a phase of high uncertainty and contingency, where political agents could play a decisive role. At that summit, the Québec government could have rejected the reforms proposed by the GTES, but instead decided to innovate and implement them. Second, “antecedent conditions constrain the range of limited options” (p. 151). The contingency of the 1996 summit was not ab - solute. Prior developments made a limited number of social economy projects politically mature. Third, the selection of the option at hand “generates a long-lasting institutional legacy” (p. 151). Two decades later, it is possible to identify the 1996 summit as such a “critical” juncture with respect to the social economy, as most of social economy reforms that it helped launch have survived to this day. In the aftermath of the summit, sectoral social economy policies were launched to support, inter alia, Québec’s networks of early childhood centres, community housing, training businesses, disability-friendly enterprises, and home-assistance social economy enterprises. Québec’s financial support to these social economy projects increased from just under $0.2 billion in 1996–1997 to over $1 billion in 2002–2003 (Québec, 2003) and then to an annual average of $1.7 billion between 2003 and 2008 (Québec, 2008), with about 70 percent of these latter sums being channelled toward early childhood cen - tres (Québec, 2008). Québec also put in place a number of transversal policies (Chaves, 2002) to recognize and promote its social economy sector more broadly. First, since 1999, the Social Economy Worksite (Chantier de l’économie sociale) has been recognized, along with the much older Quebec Council of Cooperation and Mutuality (CQCM), as one of the sector’s two permanent peak associations (Québec, 2013) and receives an annual governmental grant of about $600,000 (Québec, 2015). Second, in 2002, a permanent Office of the Social Economy was created to research and advise the responsible cabinet minister on matters related to the social economy. The office has so far helped produce three social economy action plans (Québec, 2003; 2008; 2015). Provincially funded regional development bodies have similar social economy committees. Third, legislative adjustments were made to recognize and
Details
-
File Typepdf
-
Upload Time-
-
Content LanguagesEnglish
-
Upload UserAnonymous/Not logged-in
-
File Pages18 Page
-
File Size-