The Mexican Peso Crisis.” Photocopy

The Mexican Peso Crisis.” Photocopy

TT he Mexican Peso Crisis Joseph A. Whitt, Jr. n the early 1990s the Mexican economy seemed healthy. It was grow- ing again after the “lost decade” of the 1980s, when the 1982 debt cri- sis and the 1986 collapse of oil prices sent the economy reeling. Moreover, inflation was being reduced substantially, foreign investors were pumping money into the country, and the central bank had accu- Imulated billions of dollars in reserves. Capping the favorable developments was the proposal to reduce trade barriers with Mexico’s largest trade partner, the United States, through the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA). The agreement eventually took effect at the beginning of 1994. The hard times of the 1980s seemed to be history. Less than twelve months after NAFTA took effect, Mexico faced eco- nomic disaster. On December 20, 1994, the Mexican government devalued the peso. The financial crisis that followed cut the peso’s value in half, sent inflation soaring, and set off a severe recession in Mexico. What went wrong? After reviewing the events leading up to the devalua- tion, this article examines whether Mexican policy mistakes made devalua- The author is an economist tion inevitable. The discussion then considers Mexico’s policy actions in the macropolicy section during 1994, along with options Mexico did not take. The final section re- of the Atlanta Fed’s views market response to the devaluation and Mexican and U.S. government research department. efforts to cope with its aftermath. Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta Economic Review 1 In equation (1), the symbol ^ over the variables denotes Mexico’s Wild Year of 1994 percentage changes. Accordingly, the percentage change in the real exchange rate over a particular span As 1993 drew to a close, the economic outlook for of time equals the difference between inflation at home Mexico appeared bright. Recently approved by the and abroad less the percentage change in the market U.S. Congress, NAFTA was slated to take effect at the exchange rate. For example, if Mexico’s inflation (Pˆ) beginning of 1994. By lowering trade barriers be- were 15 percent, U.S. inflation (Pˆ*) were 3 percent, and tween the United States and Mexico, NAFTA was the market exchange rate depreciated 12 percent (Eˆ), expected to encourage foreign investors to take ad- then the exchange rate depreciation would exactly off- vantage of Mexico’s privileged access to the U.S. set the inflation differential, resulting in no change in market. Moreover, NAFTA merely culminated a se- the real exchange rate—that is, Rˆ would equal zero. ries of reforms the Mexican government undertook During the early 1990s, Mexico’s inflation rate was during the administration of Mexican President Car- consistently higher than the sum of U.S. inflation and los Salinas. These prior measures included a restruc- peso depreciation, so the real exchange rate was rising. turing of Mexico’s foreign debt under the Brady Plan, Adjusted for changes in the market exchange rate, sharp reductions in Mexico’s budget deficit and infla- prices of Mexican goods were rising relative to U.S. tion rate, unilateral cuts in protectionist trade barriers, goods, thus encouraging Mexican residents to buy and privatization of various government-owned enter- more imported goods and discouraging Mexican ex- prises.1 ports. Nevertheless, the Mexican government seemed The main fly in the ointment was Mexico’s cur- unconcerned about the current account deficit, in part rent account deficit, which ballooned from $6 billion because its reserves of dollars were growing through in 1989 to $15 billion in 1991 and to more than the end of 1993. $20 billion in 1992 and 1993.2 To some extent, the In hindsight, Mexico’s central bank blamed a series current account deficit was a favorable development, of political shocks in 1994 for the December devalua- reflecting the capital inflow stimulated by Mexican tion and ensuing financial crisis (Banco de Mexico policy reforms. However, the large size of the deficit 1995, 1-5, 35-55). The first shock, at the beginning of led some observers to worry that the peso was becom- the year, was a rebellion in the southern province of ing overvalued, a circumstance that could discourage Chiapas. The armed uprising only seven months be- exports, stimulate imports, and lead eventually to a fore a presidential election raised doubts about Mexi- crisis. co’s political stability. Nevertheless, daily data on At that time Mexico had a crawling peg exchange international reserves (not released publicly until after rate system. Government intervention kept the ex- the peso’s collapse the following December) show lit- change rate vis-à-vis the dollar within a narrow target tle, if any, market reaction to the initial reports of the band, but the upper limit of the band was raised slight- rebellion.4 ly every day by a preannounced amount, allowing for A much more severe political shock occurred when a gradual nominal depreciation (a “crawling peg”) of the ruling party’s presidential candidate, Luis Donal- the peso.3 However, in real (price-adjusted) terms, the do Colosio, was assassinated on March 23. At the peso was appreciating, contributing to the ballooning time, Colosio was considered a virtual shoo-in for current account deficit. election; his death heightened fears of political insta- What does real appreciation of the peso mean? The bility and set off a brief financial panic. The sharp real exchange rate, call it R, is defined as P/(P*E), drop in Mexico’s international reserves (see Chart 1) where P is the domestic (in this case Mexican) price from February to April 1994 reflects the loss of re- level, P* is the foreign (U.S.) price level, and E is the serves as the government intervened heavily to main- market exchange rate in pesos per dollar. Rises in R tain the value of the peso during this time of indicate real appreciation of the peso, meaning that upheaval. In about four weeks, Mexico lost nearly relative to the past, a peso will purchase more goods $11 billion in reserves. and services after conversion into dollars that are spent Colosio’s assassination had other effects as well. in the United States than if the same peso were spent Mexican interest rates rose sharply, and the peso de- in Mexico. Changes in the real exchange rate can be preciated. For instance, much of Mexico’s government calculated using the following equation: debt was in the form of cetes, short-term bonds similar to U.S. Treasury bills, that were sold on a regular ba- Rˆ =Pˆ–Pˆ*– E.ˆ (1) sis. Following Colosio’s assassination, the interest rate 2 Economic Review January/February 1996 Chart 1 Mexican International Reserves (December 1993–December 1994) Billions of Dollars 30 20 10 0 Dec Feb Apr Jun Aug Oct Dec 1993 1994 Source: International Monetary Fund (IMF), International Financial Statistics. on twenty-eight-day cetes averaged 16.4 percent in A2). In addition, the kidnapping of a prominent Mexi- May, compared with only 9.5 percent in February can businessman, Alfredo Harp, may have contributed (Banco de Mexico 1995, 220). The government ex- to market jitters (NYT, June 25, 1994, 6). This time re- ploited the maneuvering room in the exchange rate tar- serves fell about $2 1⁄2 billion in three weeks, while in- get band provided by allowing the peso to depreciate terest rates rose modestly. Because the exchange rate roughly 8 percent, to a point just below the top of the had remained near the top of its target band since target band. Chart 2 shows the path of the exchange Colosio’s assassination, it had little room to depreciate rate, as well as the floor and changing ceiling of the further. band, from the beginning of 1993 until the peso was Despite these shocks, the presidential election went devalued late in 1994. As the chart shows, for more off fairly smoothly in early August, and Zedillo appar- than a year prior to the assassination Mexico usually ently won by a solid margin. However, in late Septem- had kept the exchange rate near the unchanging floor ber another prominent figure was assassinated. This of the band, even though the ceiling rose steadily to al- time the victim was one of the highest officials of the low for modest depreciation. ruling party, José Francisco Ruíz Massieu (NYT, Following Colosio’s assassination, the ruling party September 29, 1994, A1). While the Mexican stock chose Ernesto Zedillo as its new presidential candi- market dropped sharply at first, the foreign exchange date. Although he was not as well-known as Colosio, markets reacted only slightly. The third episode of after a period of uncertainty he pulled his campaign pressure on reserves began in mid-November, when together. Nevertheless, additional political shocks Deputy Attorney General Mario Ruíz Massieu, a broth- were in store for Mexico. er of the slain Francisco Ruíz Massieu, made sensa- Reserves were under stress again in late June. One tional accusations and resigned. He claimed that factor was the resignation (later withdrawn) of the important figures in the ruling party had ordered his Minister of the Interior, Jorge Carpizo, whose agency brother’s assassination and that his superior, the attor- oversaw Mexico’s national election (Banco de Mexico ney general, as well as other prominent party officials 1995, 40-41; New York Times (NYT), June 27, 1994, were obstructing his investigation of the murder (NYT, Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta Economic Review 3 November 18, 1994, A6; November 24, 1994, A5). Unprecedented in recent years, such disarray and in- Was Devaluation Inevitable? fighting at the top levels of the Mexican government severely bruised public confidence in Mexico’s politi- In the aftermath of Mexico’s financial meltdown, cal and economic stability, which had been built up at did economic policy mistakes make devaluation in- considerable cost over the previous few years.

View Full Text

Details

  • File Type
    pdf
  • Upload Time
    -
  • Content Languages
    English
  • Upload User
    Anonymous/Not logged-in
  • File Pages
    20 Page
  • File Size
    -

Download

Channel Download Status
Express Download Enable

Copyright

We respect the copyrights and intellectual property rights of all users. All uploaded documents are either original works of the uploader or authorized works of the rightful owners.

  • Not to be reproduced or distributed without explicit permission.
  • Not used for commercial purposes outside of approved use cases.
  • Not used to infringe on the rights of the original creators.
  • If you believe any content infringes your copyright, please contact us immediately.

Support

For help with questions, suggestions, or problems, please contact us