Optimal, Near-Optimal, and Robust Epidemic Control

Optimal, Near-Optimal, and Robust Epidemic Control

Optimal, near-optimal, and robust epidemic control Dylan H. Morris1,3*, Fernando W. Rossine1*, Joshua B. Plotkin2, and Simon A. Levin1 1Department of Ecology & Evolutionary Biology, Princeton University, 106A Guyot Hall, Princeton, NJ 08544, USA 2Department of Biology & Department of Mathematics, The University of Pennsylvania, 433 S University Ave, Philadelphia, PA 19104, USA 3Present address: Department of Ecology & Evolutionary Biology, University of California Los Angeles, Terasaki Life Sciences Building, 610 Charles E. Young Dr South, Los Angeles, CA 90095, USA *these authors contributed equally; correspondence to [email protected], [email protected]. Abstract In the absence of drugs and vaccines, policymakers use non-pharmaceutical interventions such as social distancing to decrease rates of disease-causing contact, with the aim of reducing or delaying the epidemic peak. These measures carry social and economic costs, so societies may be unable to maintain them for more than a short period of time. Intervention policy design often relies on numerical simulations of epidemic models, but comparing policies and assessing their robustness demands clear principles that apply across strategies. Here we derive the theo- retically optimal strategy for using a time-limited intervention to reduce the peak prevalence of arXiv:2004.02209v3 [q-bio.PE] 3 Mar 2021 a novel disease in the classic Susceptible-Infectious-Recovered epidemic model. We show that broad classes of easier-to-implement strategies can perform nearly as well as the theoretically optimal strategy. But neither the optimal strategy nor any of these near-optimal strategies is robust to implementation error: small errors in timing the intervention produce large increases in peak prevalence. Our results reveal fundamental principles of non-pharmaceutical disease control and expose their potential fragility. For robust control, an intervention must be strong, early, and ideally sustained. 1 Introduction New human pathogens routinely emerge via zoonotic spillover from other species. Examples include ebolaviruses1, influenza viruses2, and most recently the sarbecoronavirus SARS-CoV- 23. Many of these emerging pathogens are antigenically novel: the human population possesses little or no preexisting immunity4. This not only can increase disease severity5 but also leads to explosive epidemic spread4. If left unchecked, that explosive spread can result in a large proportion of the population becoming synchronously infected, as occurred during the COVID- 19 global pandemic. Policymakers initially have limited tools for controlling a novel pathogen epidemic; it can take months to develop drugs, and years to develop and distribute vaccines6. If disease symptoms are severe, healthcare systems may be strained to the breaking point as the epidemic approaches its peak7. In the absence of drugs and vaccines, mitigation efforts to reduce or delay the peak (flattening the curve7,8) rely on non-pharmaceutical interventions9 such as social distancing10 that decrease rates of disease-transmitting contact. These measures carry social and economic costs, and so societies may be unable to maintain them for more than a short period of time. Policy design for allocating non-pharmaceutical resources during the COVID-19 pandemic re- lied heavily on numerical simulations of epidemic models10,11, but it is difficult to compare pre- dictions or assess robustness without broad principles that apply across strategies. Since models are not reality, robust model-based policy requires not only generating a desired outcome but also understanding what elements of the model are producing it. This typically requires analyt- ical and theoretical understanding. Relatively little is known about globally optimal strategies for epidemic control, regardless of principal aim12,13 or intervention duration. One result establishes that time-limited interventions to reduce peak prevalence should start earlier than time-limited interventions to reduce the final size14. A number of studies of COVID-19 have used optimal control theory—an approach that relies on numerical optimization to study continuous error-correction15,16. But the optimal time-limited strategy to reduce peak prevalence is not known. Without an ana- lytical understanding of epidemic peak reduction, policy design based on numerical simulation may fail in unexpected ways; policies may be inefficient, non-robust, or both. The early months of the COVID-19 pandemic demonstrated how difficult real-time epidemio- 2 logical modeling, inference, and response can be. Large numbers of asymptomatic and mildly symptomatic cases17, as well as difficulties with testing, particularly in the United States18, left policymakers with substantial uncertainty regarding the virus’s epidemiological parameters and the case numbers in many locations. Countries including the United States and United Kingdom waited to intervene until transmission was widespread; retrospective analyses later claimed that even slightly earlier intervention would have saved many lives19,20. Epidemiological uncertainties mean that no policymaker can intervene at precisely the optimal time. To understand how this limitation can hinder policymaking, we assess the robustness of optimized interventions to timing error: what is the cost of intervening too early or too late? We derive the theoretically optimal strategy for using a time-limited intervention to reduce the peak prevalence of a novel disease in the classic Susceptible-Infectious-Recovered (SIR) epi- demic model21,22. We show that broad classes of strategies that are easier to implement can perform nearly as well as this theoretically optimal strategy. But we show that neither the the- oretically optimal strategy nor any of these near-optimal strategies is robust to implementation error: small errors in timing of the intervention produce large increases in peak prevalence. To prevent disastrous outcomes due to imperfect implementation, a strong, early, and ideally sustained non-pharmaceutical response is required. Results Epidemic model and interventions We consider the standard susceptible-infectious-recovered (SIR) epidemic model21, which de- scribes the fractions of susceptible S(t), infectious I(t), and recovered R(t) individuals in the population at time t22. New infections occur proportional to S(t)I(t) at a rate b, and infectious b individuals recover at a rate g. The model has a basic reproduction number R0 = g and an b max effective reproduction number Re = g S(t). We denote the peak prevalence by I . We consider interventions that reduce the effective rate of disease-transmitting contacts, b(t) below its value in the absence of intervention b, which we treat as fixed. In the context of COVID-19, this includes non-pharmaceutical interventions such as social distancing10, as well as some pharmaceutical ones, such as antivirals that might reduce virus shedding. 3 We permit interventions to operate on b only for a limited duration of time, t. We impose this constraint in light of political, social, and economic impediments to maintaining aggressive intervention indefinitely. That is, we treat costs of intervention implicitly, subsuming them in t. We describe such an intervention by defining a transmission reduction function b(t) such that: dS = b(t) bSI dt − ∗ dI = b(t) bSI gI (1) dt ∗ − dR = gI dt If the intervention is initiated at some time t = ti, it must stop at time t = ti + t. So necessarily b(t) = 1 if t < ti or t > ti + t. During the intervention (i.e. when ti t ti + t), b(t) is an ≤ ≤ arbitrary function, possibly discontinuous, with range in [0;1]. This restriction assumes that we cannot intervene increase transmission above what occurs in the absence of intervention, but also optimistically assumes that b(t) can be adjusted instantaneously, and that the effective reproduction number Re can be reduced all the way to zero, at least for a limited time. The optimal intervention We pose the following optimization problem: given the epidemiological parameters R0 and g and the finite duration t, what is the optimal intervention b(t) that minimizes the epidemic peak Imax? The optimal intervention is of interest for two reasons. It provides a reference point for evaluating alternative interventions. And it will allow us to analyze the inherent risks and shortcomings of time-limited interventions, even in the best-case scenario. We prove (Supplementary Note1, Theorem1) that for any R0, recovery rate g, and duration opt t, there is a unique globally optimal intervention b(t) that starts at an optimal time ti and is given by: 8 g < bS ; t [ti;ti + f t) bopt(t) = 2 (2) :0; t [ti + f t;ti + t] 2 Where f takes a specific value in [0;1]. This solution says that the optimal strategy is to maintain 4 and then suppress. The intervention spends a fraction f of the total duration t in a maintain phase, with b(t) chosen so that Re = 1. This maintains the epidemic at a constant number of opt opt infectious individuals equal to I(ti ), while susceptibles are depleted at a rate gI(ti ). The intervention then spends the remaining fraction 1 f of the total duration in a suppress phase, − setting Re = 0 so that infectious individuals are depleted at a rate gI (Fig.1a,d). The effectiveness of the optimal intervention, when it should commence, and the balance be- tween maintenance and suppression all depend on the total allowed duration of the intervention, t. The longer we can intervene (larger t), the more we can reduce the peak (smaller Imax), the

View Full Text

Details

  • File Type
    pdf
  • Upload Time
    -
  • Content Languages
    English
  • Upload User
    Anonymous/Not logged-in
  • File Pages
    40 Page
  • File Size
    -

Download

Channel Download Status
Express Download Enable

Copyright

We respect the copyrights and intellectual property rights of all users. All uploaded documents are either original works of the uploader or authorized works of the rightful owners.

  • Not to be reproduced or distributed without explicit permission.
  • Not used for commercial purposes outside of approved use cases.
  • Not used to infringe on the rights of the original creators.
  • If you believe any content infringes your copyright, please contact us immediately.

Support

For help with questions, suggestions, or problems, please contact us