Medieval Monetary Problems: Bimetallism and Bullionism Author(S): John H

Medieval Monetary Problems: Bimetallism and Bullionism Author(S): John H

Medieval Monetary Problems: Bimetallism and Bullionism Author(s): John H. Munro Source: The Journal of Economic History, Vol. 43, No. 1, The Tasks of Economic History, (Mar., 1983), pp. 294-298 Published by: Cambridge University Press on behalf of the Economic History Association Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/2120300 Accessed: 14/05/2008 11:50 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available at http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp. JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unless you have obtained prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and you may use content in the JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use. Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained at http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=cup. Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed page of such transmission. JSTOR is a not-for-profit organization founded in 1995 to build trusted digital archives for scholarship. We enable the scholarly community to preserve their work and the materials they rely upon, and to build a common research platform that promotes the discovery and use of these resources. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected]. http://www.jstor.org Workshop Summaries Medieval Monetary Problems: Bimetallism and Bullionism Fourteen papers were given in two sessions held on Thursday,September 23, 1982, with a third session on Friday morningdevoted to generalround-table discussion. This workshop had been inspired by Professor Frederic C. Lane (Emeritus of the Johns Hopkins University, and ninth President of EHA, in 1956-1958), who wished to see what light monetaryhistorians could cast upon the problemsof late medieval bimetal- lism and associated bullionflows. AppropriatelyLane presentedthe firstpaper, and the one that certainly dominated the Friday morning discussion, "Bimetallismand the VenetianBullion Market in the FourteenthCentury." The firstproblem to be posed was the puzzling oscillation in the bimetallic ratio during the century following Europe's resumptionof gold coinages, in 1252. The gold:silver ratio, after rising strongly in the late thirteenthcentury, reacheda maximumof 14.2: 1, at Venice ca. 1305.The bimetallic ratio was maintainedat approximatelythis high level across Europe (Italy, Hungary, France, Flanders)until ca. 1330,when it droppedprecipitously, to about 10:1 by 1350- in some places, to as low as 9.4: 1 (Florence, 1347).Lane does not believe that the much discussed slump in European silver mining can explain this fall in the bimetallicratio (that is, the appreciationof silver), on the grounds that the new silver mines in the Balkansfully compensatedfor declines in German-Bohemianproduction, at least until much later in the fourteenthcentury. The explanationshould instead be sought in the possibly very large increases in gold suppliesboth from the new Hungarianmines (after the Bohemian-Hungarianpact of 1327)and from Italianmaritime trade that drew upon new sources of gold in the Black Sea region (Russiangold) and in Egypt (Sudanesegold from the 1320s). Lane also agreed, however, that another, complementaryfactor may well have been an increased industrialuse of silver in this era, that is, diversion into luxury display. That particulartheme was developed in the paper of Susan Stuard(State University of New York at Brockport), on "The Consumptionof Silver After the 'Defense of the Grosso' in the FourteenthCentury." As Lane himself has recently shown, the second quarterof the fourteenthcentury marked, in Venetian monetaryhistory, not only the plunge in the bimetallicratio, but also, after a long period of deteriorationof the silver coinage, a severe monetary crisis ca. 1321-1332, the virtual abandonmentof the traditionalgrosso silver coinage, and finallyby midcenturya shift fromthe grosso-based silver standardto the ducat-basedgold standardin moneys of account (lire di grosso a oro).1 Furtherelucidating these crucial events, Stuardhas found that in this very era Venice and other Italiancities began manufacturinga wide varietyof productsin silver, largelyfor secular ratherthan (as in the past) sacramentalpurposes: luxury househould articles (salt cellars, incense burners,ewers, bowls, cups, cutlery), but especially silver adornmentsfor male dress-chiefly silver belts and daggers, some weighing 10 pounds. Productionof such adornmentsshe attributes,in part, to new modes of status-seeking and to the currentfashion that began a sharp differentiationbetween male and female attire. Such new fashions with silver adornmentsspread to northernEurope by the later fourteenthcentury. She estimates that possibly as much as 60 percent of the Ragusan- based Balkan silver delivered to the Venetian bullion marketended up in such luxury production. ' Frederic C. Lane, "The First Infidelitiesof the Venetian Lire," The Medieval City, H. A. Miskimin,D. Herlihy, A. L. Udovitch, eds. (New Haven, 1977),pp. 43-63. 294 Summaries of Workshops 295 Lane, after stressinghis second theme that Venice became the world's leadingbullion dealer by this era, concluded by contending that Venice derived very considerable wealth from this role. But, he noted, if Venice undoubtedlycontinued to prosperfrom the bullionflows accompanyingthe fall in the bimetallicratio, Florencedid not. Manyof the great Florentinebanking houses suffereda disastrousreduction in the value of their loan assets previously contracted in gold, a loss that undoubtedlycontributed to the collapse of the Bardi, the Peruzzi, and others in the 1340s. A complete explanation for this sharp fall in the bimetallic ratio may ultimately depend upon an analysis of its earlier rise to 14.2:1. Although this issue was not discussed in the workshop, it was highlighted in the paper by Louise Robbert (University of St. Louis, Missouri), "Bimetallism in the Eastern Mediterranean:A General View from Venice."2 She contended that from the late twelfth century, certainly from the Latin conquest of Constantinoplein 1204, the Venetians had been practicinga de facto bimetallismby requiringpayments in the Greek-speakingEast to be madein terms of the old, full weight Byzantinehyperperon (nomisma, bezant) and those in the Italian West in terms of the silver grosso-based Venetian pound. By her calculations,the thirteenth-centuryratio was between 10.6 and 10.9:1 (dependingupon the actual gold content of the old hyperperon). When Genoa and Florence almost simultaneouslystruck the first western Europeangold coins in 1252,they both assigned a fine gold content of 3.55 g., in the hope of replicatingthe value of the old, undebased hyperperon.Subsequently Venice, in finally issuing its own gold coin in 1284, adopted this same fine gold content for the ducat; and by the value of 18/2 grossi per ducat that meant a bimetallicratio of 10.9: 1. Venetian monetarypower in the eastern Mediterraneanwas furtherdemonstrated in two more papers, the second of which explored the linkages among bullion flows, exchange rates, and credit, a theme pursuedby the two followingpapers. The first, by Alan Stahl (AmericanNumismatic Society) on "Money and Coinage in Late Medieval Greece," documented the absorptionof Greece, with various Frankishand Venetian colonies on the mainlandand on Aegean islands, into the Venetianmonetary orbit. After the Fourth Crusade and conquest of Constantinople(1204), the Frankish victors in Greece displaced the current Byzantine coinages with a billon coin (20 percent silver) based upon the French denier tournois;but this new coinage soon encountereda rivalin the virtuallypure Venetian grosso. Over a century later Venice introduced,ca. 1332, a new coin with less silver than in the old grosso but four times as much as in the Greek tournois: the soldino, whose circulationrapidly expanded in the Greek mainlandand islands. Finally, in 1353 Venice began issuing a new billon coin (just 11 percent silver) specifically designed for Greek circulation: the tornesello, which was deliberately overvaluedand so drove out the other coinages. So importantdid this tornesellocoinage become that one of Venice's three mint-masterswas given the exclusive task of striking it, at a rate of some 20 million a year (7,000 silver marss. The next paper, by ReinholdMueller (University of Venice), on "Bullion Flows and the Foreign Exchange Marketin Late-MedievalVenice," effectively demonstratedthat while bills-of-exchangebanking and the foreignexchange marketwere vitally important to the Venetian economy, bills of exchange could not possibly have obviated Venice's need to ship bullion, vast amountsof which were exportedannually-from the Venetian point of view, simply as a commodity-in transactingits eastern Mediterraneantrade, normallyin deficit. For the period 1384-1410in particular,Mueller documented the very regularseasonal rise and fall of exchange rates at Venice in exact accordancewith the bullion flows in this trade. The sharpest rise always occurred in the summermonths, June to early September,when the departuresof the bullion-laden"Romania," Beirut, 2 In Ibid., p. 53, Lane attributedthe suddenrise in the bimetallicratio to the largeproduction of silver by Bohemianmines. 296 Summaries of Workshops and Alexandriagalleys producedsevere tightness (strettezza)in the money market.But citing BernardoDavanzatti's

View Full Text

Details

  • File Type
    pdf
  • Upload Time
    -
  • Content Languages
    English
  • Upload User
    Anonymous/Not logged-in
  • File Pages
    6 Page
  • File Size
    -

Download

Channel Download Status
Express Download Enable

Copyright

We respect the copyrights and intellectual property rights of all users. All uploaded documents are either original works of the uploader or authorized works of the rightful owners.

  • Not to be reproduced or distributed without explicit permission.
  • Not used for commercial purposes outside of approved use cases.
  • Not used to infringe on the rights of the original creators.
  • If you believe any content infringes your copyright, please contact us immediately.

Support

For help with questions, suggestions, or problems, please contact us