Forms and Values of Number-Like and Nimber-Like Games

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Forms and Values of Number-Like and Nimber-Like Games FORMS AND VALUES OF NUMBER-LIKE AND NIMBER-LIKE GAMES by Neil Anderson McKay Submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy at Dalhousie University Halifax, Nova Scotia August 2016 ⃝c Copyright by Neil Anderson McKay, 2016 To people and other living things of the past, present, and future whose lives benefit us all in ways we may not know. ii Table of Contents List of Tables ................................... vii List of Figures .................................. viii Abstract ...................................... ix List of Abbreviations and Symbols Used .................. x Acknowledgements ............................... xii Chapter 1 Introduction .......................... 1 1.1 Introduction . .1 1.1.1 Background . .1 1.1.2 Purpose . .2 1.1.3 Contents . .4 1.2 Starting from empty . .6 1.3 Outcomes . .8 1.4 Equality and other relations . 13 1.5 Simplification and Canonical Form . 15 1.6 Hackenbush . 18 1.7 Form and heredity . 19 1.8 Incentives . 20 1.9 Numbers . 21 1.10 Nimbers . 24 1.11 Dicots . 26 1.12 Stops . 28 1.13 Infinitesimals . 29 1.14 Reduced Canonical Form . 31 iii Chapter 2 Ordinal sum ........................... 33 2.1 Introduction . 33 2.1.1 Form and Outcomes . 34 2.2 Ordinal Sum Basics . 35 2.2.1 Norton’s Lemma . 36 2.2.2 Atomic Weight . 37 2.2.3 The Atomic Weight Calculus . 39 2.2.4 The Colon Principle . 40 2.3 Domination and Reversibility in Ordinal Sums . 40 2.3.1 Associativity of ordinal sum . 44 2.4 Dicots and ordinal sum . 45 2.4.1 Star-like positions . 46 2.4.2 Atomic weights of ∗-based positions . 47 2.5 Recognizing Ordinal Sums . 48 2.5.1 Literal ordinal sums . 48 2.5.2 Positions equal to ordinal sums . 50 2.5.3 Terminology . 52 Chapter 3 Transitive games ........................ 53 3.1 Introduction . 53 3.2 Transitivity and ordinal sum . 55 3.3 Stops of transitive positions . 56 3.4 Infinitesimals and transitivity . 57 3.4.1 Reduced values of transitive positions . 57 3.5 Hereditarily transitive values . 61 3.6 Making transitive positions . 62 3.7 Primary Options . 65 3.8 Transitive domination . 65 3.9 Simplifying hereditarily transitive positions . 67 3.10 Stratified positions . 72 3.11 HT-values . 74 3.12 Partial order of hereditarily transitive positions . 75 iv Chapter 4 Stalks ............................... 79 4.1 Introduction . 79 4.2 Families of Stalks . 80 4.3 A Simpler Stalk . 84 4.4 Two Stalks . 87 4.4.1 Stalk Incentives . 88 4.5 Three Stalks . 90 4.6 Outcomes of Sums of Nimber-based Numbers . 97 4.7 Recognizing Sums of Stalks . 102 4.7.1 Incentives of Sums of Stalks . 103 4.8 Values of Sums of ∗-based Numbers . 104 4.8.1 Values of Uptimals . 104 4.9 Sums of ∗-based Numbers . 107 4.9.1 Incentives of ∗-based numbers . 107 4.9.2 Comparing killing and non-killing moves . 110 4.10 Group structure . 112 4.10.1 On the Order of ∗-based Positions Including Stalks . 112 4.10.2 On the Group Structure of Stalks . 114 4.11 On the relation of ∗-based positions to ∗-based integers . 115 Chapter 5 Misère-play and ∗-based Dyadic Rationals ........ 120 5.1 Introduction to Misère-play . 120 5.1.1 Ordinal Sums Under Misère-play . 124 5.2 On ∗-based Dyadic Rationals under Misère-play . 126 5.3 Outcomes of Sums . 128 5.4 Distinguishability . 131 5.5 Discussion . 132 Chapter 6 Partizan Euclid ......................... 133 6.1 Game Tree Structure . 135 6.2 Reducing the Signature . 139 v 6.2.1 Algorithm . 143 6.3 Outcome Observations . 144 6.4 Open Questions . 145 Chapter 7 Conclusion ............................ 148 7.1 Open Problems . 148 7.1.1 Ordinal Sum . 149 7.1.2 Hereditarily Transitive . 149 7.1.3 Hackenbush . 149 7.1.4 Infinitesimals . 150 7.1.5 Partizan Euclid . 150 Bibliography ................................... 152 Appendix A .................................... 155 vi List of Tables 1.1 Some very short game trees and their names . .9 1.2 Players . .9 1.3 hackenbush positions with at most one edge . 18 2.1 Outcome of the ordinal sum of G and H ............. 35 3.1 The number of HT-values born by day n ≤ 5 .......... 75 4.1 Families of stalks ......................... 81 4.2 Outcomes of ∗n-based integers . 99 5.1 Misère-play outcome of ordinal sums with non-end bases . 125 6.1 Outcome of a position with exactly one option for each player . 135 6.2 Irreducible signatures with corresponding positions and outcomes 142 6.3 aw(E(q, p)), for q = 11,..., 20, p = 10,..., 15........... 146 6.4 Some atomic weights from partizan euclid .......... 147 vii List of Figures 1.1 The partial order of outcomes . 11 1.2 Relations ρ and possible outcomes of G given G ρ 0....... 15 1.3 A stalks position . 18 1.4 The dyadic rationals . 22 4.1 Values and outcomes of stalks with at most one edge . 79 4.2 Non-green monochrome stalks are integers . 81 4.3 blue-red stalks are dyadic rationals . 81 4.4 green stalks are nimbers . 82 4.5 A sprigs position . 82 4.6 A flowers position . 83 6.1 Some of the game tree of (11, 8) ................. 134 6.2 Paired outcome of signatures. 140 viii Abstract We consider combinatorial games (positions) played by two players who move alter- nately. In a disjunctive sum of positions a player may play in any one summand. Plays in a particular summand may not alternate between players. Play ends in a finite number of moves when a player cannot move in any summand. The winneris determined by the last player to move. We primarily consider the case where the last player to move wins (the normal-play convention). In a sum of nimbers both players have the same available moves (options). In a sum of numbers both players would rather it not be their turn. The canonical form theory partitions positions into equivalence classes which form a group with disjunc- tive sum. The unique (canonical) representative of an equivalence class is called a value. Nimber-valued and number-valued positions are closed under disjunctive sum. It has long been known how to identify positions that are nimbers or numbers. There are other methods to analyze positions that are not nimber-like and number-like, such as reduced canonical forms and atomic weight. Nimbers and numbers are both hereditarily transitive (where no player would benefit from moving twice in a row) and both are hackenbush positions. Dicotic positions (where both players have an option or neither does) are like nimbers and numbers. The dicotic hereditarily transitive positions are described using ordinal sum. We show how to recognize positions whose values are from the ruleset hackenbush stalks (whose summands are described by ordinal sums). We then consider outcomes of hackenbush stalks under the misère-play convention. We end by considering the ruleset partizan euclid, a partizan dicotic ruleset, that is like nimbers and numbers in other ways. ix List of Abbreviations and Symbols Used b(˜ G) formal birthday of G. b(G) birthday of G. GL the Left options of G. GR the Right options of G. G the negative of G, used in misère-play. G → H the move from G to H. G : H the ordinal sum of G and H. L the set of Left win positions. N the set of first player win positions. P the set of second player win positions. R the set of Right win positions. L the outcome (Left, Left). N the outcome (Left, Right). P the outcome (Right, Left). R the outcome (Right, Right). rcf(G) the reduced canonical form of G. G˜ the set of short positions. G the set of short values. LS(G) the Left stop of G. RS(G) the Right stop of G. TL(G) Left-transitive closure of G. TR(G) Right-transitive closure of G. T(G) transitive closure of G. HT(G) hereditary transitive closure of G. D the universe of dicotic positions. 0 {· | ·} “zero”, “the empty position”. 1 {0 | ·} “one”. n {n − 1 | ·} “n”. x ∗ {0 | 0} “star”. ∗n {0, ∗,..., ∗n−1 | 0, ∗,..., ∗n−1} “star-n”. F “far star”. ¨x {0 | {0 | −x}} “tiny-x”. ↑ {0 | ∗} “up”. ↑∗ {0, ∗ | 0} “up star”. ↓ {∗ | 0} “down”. ⇑ {0 | ↑∗} “double-up”. {0 | ⇑∗} “triple-up”. xi Acknowledgements I do not have the space to list the names of all the people I thank. I sincerely thank everyone who has helped me; if you read this wondering if I mean you, I almost certainly do. I thank many people multiple times as they play multiple important roles. For some people I do not have the space to state all the ways they have helped me. First, I thank the Department throughout my time at Dalhousie. In particular I.
Recommended publications
  • On Variations of Nim and Chomp Arxiv:1705.06774V1 [Math.CO] 18
    On Variations of Nim and Chomp June Ahn Benjamin Chen Richard Chen Ezra Erives Jeremy Fleming Michael Gerovitch Tejas Gopalakrishna Tanya Khovanova Neil Malur Nastia Polina Poonam Sahoo Abstract We study two variations of Nim and Chomp which we call Mono- tonic Nim and Diet Chomp. In Monotonic Nim the moves are the same as in Nim, but the positions are non-decreasing numbers as in Chomp. Diet-Chomp is a variation of Chomp, where the total number of squares removed is limited. 1 Introduction We study finite impartial games with two players where the same moves are available to both players. Players alternate moves. In a normal play, the person who does not have a move loses. In a misère play, the person who makes the last move loses. A P-position is a position from which the previous player wins, assuming perfect play. We can observe that all terminal positions are P-positions. An N-position is a position from which the next player wins given perfect play. When we play we want to end our move with a P-position and want to see arXiv:1705.06774v1 [math.CO] 18 May 2017 an N-position before our move. Every impartial game is equivalent to a Nim heap of a certain size. Thus, every game can be assigned a non-negative integer, called a nimber, nim- value, or a Grundy number. The game of Nim is played on several heaps of tokens. A move consists of taking some tokens from one of the heaps. The game of Chomp is played on a rectangular m by n chocolate bar with grid lines dividing the bar into mn squares.
    [Show full text]
  • An Introduction to Conway's Games and Numbers
    AN INTRODUCTION TO CONWAY’S GAMES AND NUMBERS DIERK SCHLEICHER AND MICHAEL STOLL 1. Combinatorial Game Theory Combinatorial Game Theory is a fascinating and rich theory, based on a simple and intuitive recursive definition of games, which yields a very rich algebraic struc- ture: games can be added and subtracted in a very natural way, forming an abelian GROUP (§ 2). There is a distinguished sub-GROUP of games called numbers which can also be multiplied and which form a FIELD (§ 3): this field contains both the real numbers (§ 3.2) and the ordinal numbers (§ 4) (in fact, Conway’s definition gen- eralizes both Dedekind sections and von Neumann’s definition of ordinal numbers). All Conway numbers can be interpreted as games which can actually be played in a natural way; in some sense, if a game is identified as a number, then it is under- stood well enough so that it would be boring to actually play it (§ 5). Conway’s theory is deeply satisfying from a theoretical point of view, and at the same time it has useful applications to specific games such as Go [Go]. There is a beautiful microcosmos of numbers and games which are infinitesimally close to zero (§ 6), and the theory contains the classical and complete Sprague-Grundy theory on impartial games (§ 7). The theory was founded by John H. Conway in the 1970’s. Classical references are the wonderful books On Numbers and Games [ONAG] by Conway, and Win- ning Ways by Berlekamp, Conway and Guy [WW]; they have recently appeared in their second editions.
    [Show full text]
  • Impartial Games
    Combinatorial Games MSRI Publications Volume 29, 1995 Impartial Games RICHARD K. GUY In memory of Jack Kenyon, 1935-08-26 to 1994-09-19 Abstract. We give examples and some general results about impartial games, those in which both players are allowed the same moves at any given time. 1. Introduction We continue our introduction to combinatorial games with a survey of im- partial games. Most of this material can also be found in WW [Berlekamp et al. 1982], particularly pp. 81{116, and in ONAG [Conway 1976], particu- larly pp. 112{130. An elementary introduction is given in [Guy 1989]; see also [Fraenkel 1996], pp. ??{?? in this volume. An impartial game is one in which the set of Left options is the same as the set of Right options. We've noticed in the preceding article the impartial games = 0=0; 0 0 = 1= and 0; 0; = 2: {|} ∗ { | } ∗ ∗ { ∗| ∗} ∗ that were born on days 0, 1, and 2, respectively, so it should come as no surprise that on day n the game n = 0; 1; 2;:::; (n 1) 0; 1; 2;:::; (n 1) ∗ {∗ ∗ ∗ ∗ − |∗ ∗ ∗ ∗ − } is born. In fact any game of the type a; b; c;::: a; b; c;::: {∗ ∗ ∗ |∗ ∗ ∗ } has value m,wherem =mex a;b;c;::: , the least nonnegative integer not in ∗ { } the set a;b;c;::: . To see this, notice that any option, a say, for which a>m, { } ∗ This is a slightly revised reprint of the article of the same name that appeared in Combi- natorial Games, Proceedings of Symposia in Applied Mathematics, Vol. 43, 1991. Permission for use courtesy of the American Mathematical Society.
    [Show full text]
  • Combinatorial Game Theory Théorie Des Jeux Combinatoires (Org
    Combinatorial Game Theory Théorie des jeux combinatoires (Org: Melissa Huggan (Ryerson), Svenja Huntemann (Concordia University of Edmonton) and/et Richard Nowakowski (Dalhousie)) ALEXANDER CLOW, St. Francis Xavier University Red, Blue, Green Poset Games This talk examines Red, Blue, Green (partizan) poset games under normal play. Poset games are played on a poset where players take turns choosing an element of the partial order and removing every element greater than or equal to it in the ordering. The Left player can choose Blue elements (Right cannot) and the Right player can choose Red elements (while the Left cannot) and both players can choose Green elements. Red, Blue and Red, Blue, Green poset games have not seen much attention in the literature, do to most questions about Green poset games (such as CHOMP) remaining open. We focus on results that are true of all Poset games, but time allowing, FENCES, the poset game played on fences (or zig-zag posets) will be considered. This is joint work with Dr.Neil McKay. MATTHIEU DUFOUR AND SILVIA HEUBACH, UQAM & California State University Los Angeles Circular Nim CN(7,4) Circular Nim CN(n; k) is a variation on Nim. A move consists of selecting k consecutive stacks from n stacks arranged in a circle, and then to remove at least one token (and as many as all tokens) from the selected stacks. We will briefly review known results on Circular Nim CN(n; k) for small values of n and k and for some families, and then discuss new features that have arisen in the set of the P-positions of CN(7,4).
    [Show full text]
  • COMPSCI 575/MATH 513 Combinatorics and Graph Theory
    COMPSCI 575/MATH 513 Combinatorics and Graph Theory Lecture #34: Partisan Games (from Conway, On Numbers and Games and Berlekamp, Conway, and Guy, Winning Ways) David Mix Barrington 9 December 2016 Partisan Games • Conway's Game Theory • Hackenbush and Domineering • Four Types of Games and an Order • Some Games are Numbers • Values of Numbers • Single-Stalk Hackenbush • Some Domineering Examples Conway’s Game Theory • J. H. Conway introduced his combinatorial game theory in his 1976 book On Numbers and Games or ONAG. Researchers in the area are sometimes called onagers. • Another resource is the book Winning Ways by Berlekamp, Conway, and Guy. Conway’s Game Theory • Games, like everything else in the theory, are defined recursively. A game consists of a set of left options, each a game, and a set of right options, each a game. • The base of the recursion is the zero game, with no options for either player. • Last time we saw non-partisan games, where each player had the same options from each position. Today we look at partisan games. Hackenbush • Hackenbush is a game where the position is a diagram with red and blue edges, connected in at least one place to the “ground”. • A move is to delete an edge, a blue one for Left and a red one for Right. • Edges disconnected from the ground disappear. As usual, a player who cannot move loses. Hackenbush • From this first position, Right is going to win, because Left cannot prevent him from killing both the ground supports. It doesn’t matter who moves first.
    [Show full text]
  • ~Umbers the BOO K O F Umbers
    TH E BOOK OF ~umbers THE BOO K o F umbers John H. Conway • Richard K. Guy c COPERNICUS AN IMPRINT OF SPRINGER-VERLAG © 1996 Springer-Verlag New York, Inc. Softcover reprint of the hardcover 1st edition 1996 All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced, stored in a re­ trieval system, or transmitted, in any form or by any means, electronic, mechanical, photocopying, recording, or otherwise, without the prior written permission of the publisher. Published in the United States by Copernicus, an imprint of Springer-Verlag New York, Inc. Copernicus Springer-Verlag New York, Inc. 175 Fifth Avenue New York, NY lOOlO Library of Congress Cataloging in Publication Data Conway, John Horton. The book of numbers / John Horton Conway, Richard K. Guy. p. cm. Includes bibliographical references and index. ISBN-13: 978-1-4612-8488-8 e-ISBN-13: 978-1-4612-4072-3 DOl: 10.l007/978-1-4612-4072-3 1. Number theory-Popular works. I. Guy, Richard K. II. Title. QA241.C6897 1995 512'.7-dc20 95-32588 Manufactured in the United States of America. Printed on acid-free paper. 9 8 765 4 Preface he Book ofNumbers seems an obvious choice for our title, since T its undoubted success can be followed by Deuteronomy,Joshua, and so on; indeed the only risk is that there may be a demand for the earlier books in the series. More seriously, our aim is to bring to the inquisitive reader without particular mathematical background an ex­ planation of the multitudinous ways in which the word "number" is used.
    [Show full text]
  • ES.268 Dynamic Programming with Impartial Games, Course Notes 3
    ES.268 , Lecture 3 , Feb 16, 2010 http://erikdemaine.org/papers/AlgGameTheory_GONC3 Playing Games with Algorithms: { most games are hard to play well: { Chess is EXPTIME-complete: { n × n board, arbitrary position { need exponential (cn) time to find a winning move (if there is one) { also: as hard as all games (problems) that need exponential time { Checkers is EXPTIME-complete: ) Chess & Checkers are the \same" computationally: solving one solves the other (PSPACE-complete if draw after poly. moves) { Shogi (Japanese chess) is EXPTIME-complete { Japanese Go is EXPTIME-complete { U. S. Go might be harder { Othello is PSPACE-complete: { conjecture requires exponential time, but not sure (implied by P 6= NP) { can solve some games fast: in \polynomial time" (mostly 1D) Kayles: [Dudeney 1908] (n bowling pins) { move = hit one or two adjacent pins { last player to move wins (normal play) Let's play! 1 First-player win: SYMMETRY STRATEGY { move to split into two equal halves (1 pin if odd, 2 if even) { whatever opponent does, do same in other half (Kn + Kn = 0 ::: just like Nim) Impartial game, so Sprague-Grundy Theory says Kayles ≡ Nim somehow { followers(Kn) = fKi + Kn−i−1;Ki + Kn−i−2 j i = 0; 1; :::;n − 2g ) nimber(Kn) = mexfnimber(Ki + Kn−i−1); nimber(Ki + Kn−i−2) j i = 0; 1; :::;n − 2g { nimber(x + y) = nimber(x) ⊕ nimber(y) ) nimber(Kn) = mexfnimber(Ki) ⊕ nimber(Kn−i−1); nimber(Ki) ⊕ nimber(Kn−i−2) j i = 0; 1; :::n − 2g RECURRENCE! | write what you want in terms of smaller things Howe do w compute it? nimber(K0) = 0 (BASE CASE) nimber(K1) = mexfnimber(K0) ⊕ nimber(K0)g 0 ⊕ 0 = 0 = 1 nimber(K2) = mexfnimber(K0) ⊕ nimber(K1); 0 ⊕ 1 = 1 nimber(K0) ⊕ nimber(K0)g 0 ⊕ 0 = 0 = 2 so e.g.
    [Show full text]
  • When Waiting Moves You in Scoring Combinatorial Games
    WHEN WAITING MOVES YOU IN SCORING COMBINATORIAL GAMES Urban Larsson1 Dalhousie University, Canada Richard J. Nowakowski Dalhousie University, Canada Carlos P. Santos2 Center for Linear Structures and Combinatorics, Portugal Abstract Combinatorial Scoring games, with the property ‘extra pass moves for a player does no harm’, are characterized. The characterization involves an order embedding of Conway’s Normal-play games. Also, we give a theorem for comparing games with scores (numbers) which extends Ettinger’s work on dicot Scoring games. 1 Introduction The Lawyer’s offer: To settle a dispute, a court has ordered you and your oppo- nent to play a Combinatorial game, the winner (most number of points) takes all. Minutes before the contest is to begin, your opponent’s lawyer approaches you with an offer: "You, and you alone, will be allowed a pass move to use once, at any time in the game, but you must use it at some point (unless the other player runs out of moves before you used it)." Should you accept this generous offer? We will show when you should accept and when you should decline the offer. It all depends on whether Conway’s Normal-play games (last move wins) can be embedded in the ‘game’ in an order preserving way. Combinatorial games have perfect information, are played by two players who move alternately, but moreover, the games finish regardless of the order of moves. When one of the players cannot move, the winner of the game is declared by some predetermined winning condition. The two players are usually called Left (female pronoun) and Right (male pronoun).
    [Show full text]
  • Combinatorial Game Theory, Well-Tempered Scoring Games, and a Knot Game
    Combinatorial Game Theory, Well-Tempered Scoring Games, and a Knot Game Will Johnson June 9, 2011 Contents 1 To Knot or Not to Knot 4 1.1 Some facts from Knot Theory . 7 1.2 Sums of Knots . 18 I Combinatorial Game Theory 23 2 Introduction 24 2.1 Combinatorial Game Theory in general . 24 2.1.1 Bibliography . 27 2.2 Additive CGT specifically . 28 2.3 Counting moves in Hackenbush . 34 3 Games 40 3.1 Nonstandard Definitions . 40 3.2 The conventional formalism . 45 3.3 Relations on Games . 54 3.4 Simplifying Games . 62 3.5 Some Examples . 66 4 Surreal Numbers 68 4.1 Surreal Numbers . 68 4.2 Short Surreal Numbers . 70 4.3 Numbers and Hackenbush . 77 4.4 The interplay of numbers and non-numbers . 79 4.5 Mean Value . 83 1 5 Games near 0 85 5.1 Infinitesimal and all-small games . 85 5.2 Nimbers and Sprague-Grundy Theory . 90 6 Norton Multiplication and Overheating 97 6.1 Even, Odd, and Well-Tempered Games . 97 6.2 Norton Multiplication . 105 6.3 Even and Odd revisited . 114 7 Bending the Rules 119 7.1 Adapting the theory . 119 7.2 Dots-and-Boxes . 121 7.3 Go . 132 7.4 Changing the theory . 139 7.5 Highlights from Winning Ways Part 2 . 144 7.5.1 Unions of partizan games . 144 7.5.2 Loopy games . 145 7.5.3 Mis`eregames . 146 7.6 Mis`ereIndistinguishability Quotients . 147 7.7 Indistinguishability in General . 148 II Well-tempered Scoring Games 155 8 Introduction 156 8.1 Boolean games .
    [Show full text]
  • Combinatorial Game Theory
    Combinatorial Game Theory Aaron N. Siegel Graduate Studies MR1EXLIQEXMGW Volume 146 %QIVMGER1EXLIQEXMGEP7SGMIX] Combinatorial Game Theory https://doi.org/10.1090//gsm/146 Combinatorial Game Theory Aaron N. Siegel Graduate Studies in Mathematics Volume 146 American Mathematical Society Providence, Rhode Island EDITORIAL COMMITTEE David Cox (Chair) Daniel S. Freed Rafe Mazzeo Gigliola Staffilani 2010 Mathematics Subject Classification. Primary 91A46. For additional information and updates on this book, visit www.ams.org/bookpages/gsm-146 Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data Siegel, Aaron N., 1977– Combinatorial game theory / Aaron N. Siegel. pages cm. — (Graduate studies in mathematics ; volume 146) Includes bibliographical references and index. ISBN 978-0-8218-5190-6 (alk. paper) 1. Game theory. 2. Combinatorial analysis. I. Title. QA269.S5735 2013 519.3—dc23 2012043675 Copying and reprinting. Individual readers of this publication, and nonprofit libraries acting for them, are permitted to make fair use of the material, such as to copy a chapter for use in teaching or research. Permission is granted to quote brief passages from this publication in reviews, provided the customary acknowledgment of the source is given. Republication, systematic copying, or multiple reproduction of any material in this publication is permitted only under license from the American Mathematical Society. Requests for such permission should be addressed to the Acquisitions Department, American Mathematical Society, 201 Charles Street, Providence, Rhode Island 02904-2294 USA. Requests can also be made by e-mail to [email protected]. c 2013 by the American Mathematical Society. All rights reserved. The American Mathematical Society retains all rights except those granted to the United States Government.
    [Show full text]
  • On Structural Parameterizations of Node Kayles
    On Structural Parameterizations of Node Kayles Yasuaki Kobayashi Abstract Node Kayles is a well-known two-player impartial game on graphs: Given an undirected graph, each player alternately chooses a vertex not adjacent to previously chosen vertices, and a player who cannot choose a new vertex loses the game. The problem of deciding if the first player has a winning strategy in this game is known to be PSPACE-complete. There are a few studies on algorithmic aspects of this problem. In this paper, we consider the problem from the viewpoint of fixed-parameter tractability. We show that the problem is fixed-parameter tractable parameterized by the size of a minimum vertex cover or the modular-width of a given graph. Moreover, we give a polynomial kernelization with respect to neighborhood diversity. 1 Introduction Kayles is a two-player game with bowling pins and a ball. In this game, two players alternately roll a ball down towards a row of pins. Each player knocks down either a pin or two adjacent pins in their turn. The player who knocks down the last pin wins the game. This game has been studied in combinatorial game theory and the winning player can be characterized in the number of pins at the start of the game. Schaefer [10] introduced a variant of this game on graphs, which is known as Node Kayles. In this game, given an undirected graph, two players alternately choose a vertex, and the chosen vertex and its neighborhood are removed from the graph. The game proceeds as long as the graph has at least one vertex and ends when no vertex is left.
    [Show full text]
  • Crash Course on Combinatorial Game Theory
    CRASH COURSE ON COMBINATORIAL GAME THEORY ALFONSO GRACIA{SAZ Disclaimer: These notes are a sketch of the lectures delivered at Mathcamp 2009 containing only the definitions and main results. The lectures also included moti- vation, exercises, additional explanations, and an opportunity for the students to discover the patterns by themselves, which is always more enjoyable than merely reading these notes. 1. The games we will analyze We will study combinatorial games. These are games: • with two players, who take turns moving, • with complete information (for example, there are no cards hidden in your hand that only you can see), • deterministic (for example, no dice or flipped coins), • guaranteed to finish in a finite amount of time, • without loops, ties, or draws, • where the first player who cannot move loses. In this course, we will specifically concentrate on impartial combinatorial games. Those are combinatorial games in which the legal moves for both players are the same. 2. Nim Rules of nim: • We play with various piles of beans. • On their turn, a player removes one or more beans from the same pile. • Final position: no beans left. Notation: • A P-position is a \previous player win", e.g. (0,0,0), (1,1,0). • An N-position is a \next player win", e.g. (1,0,0), (2,1,0). We win by always moving onto P-positions. Definition. Given two natural numbers a and b, their nim-sum, written a ⊕ b, is calculated as follows: • write a and b in binary, • \add them without carrying", i.e., for each position digit, 0 ⊕ 0 = 1 ⊕ 1 = 0, 0 ⊕ 1 = 1 ⊕ 0 = 1.
    [Show full text]