This dissertation has been microfihned exactly as received 68—14,805 LUCEY, Denis Ijgnatius, 1942- IMPACT OF INDUSTRIALIZATION ON TWO RURAL COMMUNITIES IN WESTERN .

Iowa State University, Ph.D., 1968 Economics, general

University Microfilms, Inc., Ann Arbor, Michigan IMPACT OF INDUSTRIALIZATION ON TWO RURAL COMMUNITIES IN WESTERN IRELAND

by

Denis Ignatius Lucey

A Dissertation Submitted to the Graduate Faculty in Partial Fulfillment of The Requirements for the Degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY

Major Subject: Economics

Approved :

Signature was redacted for privacy.

In Charge of Major Work

Signature was redacted for privacy.

Head of Major Department

Signature was redacted for privacy.

Dean of Graduate Iowa State University Of Science and Technology Ames, Iowa 1968 PLEASE NOTE: Not original copy. Several pages are blurred and indistinct. Filmed in the best possible way.

UNIVERSITY MICROFILMS ii

TABLE OF CONTENTS

Page I. INTRODUCTION 1 II. INDUSTRIALIZATION AS A TOOL IN ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT 7 III. IRELAND 52 IV. THE STUDY LOCATION 72 V. THE PLANT EMPLOYEES 88 VI. HYPOTHETICAL INDUSTRIALIZATION EFFECTS 123 VII. METHODOLOGICAL CONSIDERATIONS l60 VIII. EMPLOYMENT EFFECTS 183 IX. POPULATION EFFECTS 212 X. INCOME EFFECTS 223 XI. EXPENDITURE EFFECTS 262 XII. FARM BUSINESS EFFECTS 281 XIII. SELECTIVITY FACTORS 303 XIV. SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS 322 XV. LITERATURE CITED 329 XVI. ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS 3^0 XVII. APPENDIX A 342 XVIII. APPENDIX B 343 I. INTRODUCTION

The development problem of a less developed area is nor­ mally regarded as that of converting a "traditional" society 'A'hich is largely dependent on subsistence or near-subsistence agriculture, though possibly combined with the export of a few primary commodities, but providing a low level of income per capita, into a "modern" society in which secular growth of income per capita is incorporated in the economic and scci system through the development' of automatic icechanisms foster ing capital accumulation, technological advance and sustained increases in the skill of the labor force. Sven a cursory examination of the economies of what are conventionally referred to as the "developed" countries sug­ gests that one of the more notlceeble features of d eve lop:? en t is the abundsnce of manufacturing industry;- froic which the wealth of the developed countries would appear to spri"n~. A- a result of this, in the view of those having concern for the sdyancement of the less developed areas-, to quote Mount job ( S9, p. 66), "it is not surprising that the introduction of manufacturing industry should be regarded uncritically as a panacea". Less developed countries thus tend to favor policies of "Industrialization" in order to further such objectives as tl- provision of employment for growing populations (or even already under-employed populations), the raising of incosv-; pc capita and thus presumably of standards of living, the improve­ ment of a balance of payments situation or even the desire for national prestige which an industrial•economy might provide in relation to other producers of primary products. However', in the developed countries there is also considerable interest in the promotion of industrial development in rural areas. Kost of these areas within the developed countries have in the relatively recent past been characterized by declining employment opportunities frequently accompanied by net emigra­ tion of population. In comparison with other areas within the same country, these areas would be ones having relatively low levels of income per capita. Furthermore, these areas have scarcely any manufacturing activity.. Recourse has frequently been had to the fostering of manufacturing activity in such areas as a means of maintaining or even expanding the economic base of those areas. Hence, the implementation of policies to promote manu­ facturing activities has been of interest, not alone to the governments of the less developed nations, but also to the governments of the more developed nations because of the exist­ ence of relatively less developed areas within their own countries. The establishment of a new manufacturing plant in a com­ munity may be expected to have both economic and social effects on that community. One may expect that the incidence and magnitude of these effects will vary with the type and size of the new manufacturing plant and also with certain character­ istics of the community involved. One of the more apparent effects to be expected would be an increase in the avail­ ability of employment opportunities. Frequently, the establishment of such manufacturing plants in economically depressed areas is encouraged in the hope that they will play an important part in the process of providing off-farm employment opportunities locally for those who might otherwise be obliged to leave those areas in search of employ­ ment. This is considered as a policy alternative to the move­ ment of labor from those areas to the relatively more indus­ trialized areas within the country. A number of studies have been conducted in the United States of America with the object of elucidating the economic and social effects on rural communities following the intro­ duction of new industrial plants to those communities.' Related research, though mainly of a sociological nature, has been con­ ducted in some European countries. The object of the present study is twofold: (1) to examine the impact which the recent establishment of manufac­ turing plants has had on two predominantly rural communities in Western Ireland; (2) to compare the impact observed in Ireland with that observed in the United States, in order to obtain information on the differential impact of industrial development on communities which have different levels, of income per capita. These manufacturing plants, one located . . at Tubbercuïry, County and the other at Scarriff, , are situated in the relatively less developed part of Ireland. Incomes per capita in these areas would be substan­ tially lower than in the more developed countries like the United States. However, these areas are at a much more advanced stage of development than most areas of Africa, Asia: and Latin America. More specifically, the first broad objective listed may be subdivided as follows. a. to determine, the relative amount of transfer of agricultural manpower to industry. b. to determine the direct effects of industrial­ ization on employment, population, income and hou s ehold exp endi tur e. c. to determine the direct effects of industrial­ ization on agricultural resource efficiency, farm organization, farm investment and the level and mix of farm output. d. to estimate the spatial incidence of the direct effects of industrialization. e. to determine the nature of any selectivity forces operating to affect the incidence and magnitude of the direct effects. Knowledge of the specific effects of industrial develop­ ment in Irish rural communities should be of interest to resi­ dents of those communities. In addition it should be of interest to residents or groups in other areas in Ireland who are interested in communtiy development. Furthermore, this knowledge should be of interest to local governmental and cen­ tral governmental agencies, providing them with some measure of 5 the effectiveness of programs and policies designed to fo-ter industrial development in such areas. Hb^ever, a wider base of interest is also claimed for this study. This arises from the comparative analysis of the effects of industrial development on rural comunities at dif­ ferent levels of income per.capita. Many resources, both in terms of professional manpower and other physical and monetary resources, are currently being devoted by the governments of the developed countries and by international organizations to the problem of aiding the developmental processes of the yery underdeveloped countries. Lacking specific information on the degree to which therintroduction of various policies, programs or institutions will affect these countries, the organizations responsible have frequently had to rely almost exclusively on their knowledge of the impact which such policies et cetera have had in countries like the United States or the more de­ veloped Western Europea.n nations as a guide to formulating developmental programs for these underdeveloped countries. In a recent evaluation of the successes and failures of developmental policies aimed at the modernisation of subsist­ ence agriculture, Wharton has stated (126, p. 266): "The real dot-aifall in agricultural development programs to date has been the failure to recognize - tl'iat agricultural development must be analyzed in its complex totality, focusing on the key interact­ ing facets, each of which must be studied in a particular context and in a continuing ongoing fashion.,.. Moreover, the critical problems In any one country or region need not be the same as in another. Even where a program attacks successfully a coabination of critical factors, we raust recog­ nize tliat there is very little transferability to another problem situation." Ireland, especially Western Ireland, lies at an inter­ mediate level of development. 7!f it can be demonstrated that, for any specific policy or program, the effect of its intro­ duction in advanced countries like the United^tates and in intermediate countries like Ireland has been roughly similar, then a much stronger case can be made for an a priori expec­ tation that such a policy would have a success potential in the less developed countries greater than the success poten­ tial of a policy which had produced widely differing results following its introduction in the advanced countries and in intermediate countries such as Ireland. It is with the modest hope of contributing some informa­ tion on both these facets of concern that the present study was undertaken. 7

II. IimUSTRIALIZA-TION AS A TOOL ITT ECOÎXOMIC DEVSLOPKEIfP

The role played by the. process of industrialization in furthering goals of economic development is examined in this chapter, which contains four sections. Section A contains a general overview of the theory of economic groxcth and develop­ ment, especially as it applies to the less developed economies focusing particularly on the degree to which attention has been directed towards policies of industrialization in these economies. Some economic problems of the developed economies are examined in Section B, especially the emergence of economi cally distressed areas within these economies, resulting also in consideration of policies of industrialization in certain areas within the developed economies. Various measures taken by governments to foster the development of local industrialization are documented in Sec­ tion C, while Section D contains a review of other research . conducted to determine the- economic impact follotsring the intro duction of industrial establishments into predominantly rural areas.

A. Economic Development of the Less-developed Economies

Problems of economic growth and development are matters of critical concern to economists of the current era. The 8 critical nature of these problems is obvious in the case of the many relatively underdeveloped countries who have achieved independence since World War II, Problems of growth are likewise important to the devel­ oped countries both in terms of their own economies and also in relation to their programs of assistance to the less deve­ loped countries. This widespread current concern with problems, of growth and development is further evidenced by the désigna- . tion of the nineteen sixties as- "United Nations Development Decade" by the United Nations Organization (33» P. 1). Economic growth, of a country or an area may be defined as an upward secular trend in its real income. Many writers use the terms economic growth and economic development interchange­ ably. However, strictly speaking, economic development refers to the process by which an economy passes from a "traditional" to a "modern" stage, whereas economic growth can occur within each of these stages and during the transition, A further source of confusion in the literature is the apparent lack of distinction between economic growth and economic progress which may be defined as an upward secular trend in real income per capita. Thus, depending on the direction and magnitude of changes in its population, an area may experience various com­ binations of growth and progress over any given interval of time, Rudiments of a theory of economic growth are apparent in the writings of the Mercantilists who flourished in the seventeenth century. They regarded the non-agricultural sector as the strategic one in this connection and "...iden­ tified the merchant*s profit with the national good, i.e. the strengthening of the power of the realm" (103, p. 63). Their concern, according to Spengler (114, p. 52) was with "...ac­ celeration of the rate of growth of aggregate, rather than average, output". The French Physiocrats in the ei^teenth century assigned the critical role to agriculture, which they regarded as the only part of the economy capable of producing a "surplus". This "surplus" was regarded as the Taasic growth-generating factor in the economy. They believed, to quote Spengler once again (114, p. 55), "that the non-agricultural sectors of an agrarian economy would grow at an optimal rate and in sym­ pathy with, and in response to, the growth of the agricultural sector, so long as there was an absence of government inter­ vention, of special privilege and monopoly, and of other inter­ ferences with the competitive process". The classical economists from Adam Smith onwards were mainly concerned with economic growth. Here, specialization and division of labor played an important role, both in the agricultural and non-agricultural sectors of the economy. "When", according to Smith (110, p. I63), "by the improvement and cultivation of land the labour of one family can provide food for two, the labour of half the society becomes suffi­ cient to provide food for the whole. The other half, therefore 10 or at least the greater part of them, can be employed in pro­ viding other things, or in satisfying the other -wants and fancies of mankind". The creation of an agricultural surplus, then, would produce a demand for other goods and services, thus stimulating the development of manufacturing industries to sat­ isfy this growing demand. David Eicardo, while -focusing on the problem of growth, dwelt with it mainly within the framework of returns to the factors of production. The key to growth in his system was the formation and accumulation of capital. While profits were positive, capitalists (through whose hands the total income . of the country passed) would be willing to forego current con­ sumption and save some of their income which would be rein­ vested in the production of more capital goods. Demand for workers would thus increase, inducing a rise in money wages. This, in turn, would stimulate population expansion, thus in­ creasing demand for food, which could only be obtained by more intensive cultivation of currently used land or by bringing "poorer" land into cultivation. The consequent increase in food cost, necessitating hi^er wages would cause a reduction in the rate of profit and hence would act as a disincentive to further saving and investment. Eicardo, along with Maithus, visualized the continuation of such a process until a stationary state would be reached, with stable population, subsistence wages, zero profits and a lack of new capital accumulation. . 11

Karl Marx, developing further some of Eicardo* s ideas, predicted the doom of the capitalistic system because of the appropriation to themselves by the capitalists of the "sur­ plus value", the excess of current production over that re­ quired to pay the workers and to maintain the current stock of capital. Because of the use of this "surplus value" by capi­ talists to create more capital, an increasing divergence would be induced between the purchasing power of the workers and the production of consumer goods. This oversupply of goods would induce a series of severe business fluctuations, or "crises" to use Marx*s terminology, which would increase in intensity and severity, thus bringing about the eventual collapse of the capitalistic system. In the late nineteenth century rapid economic growth occur­ red in Western Europe and the United States, The interest of economists in the factors affecting growth subsided, to be replaced by the development of theories of resource allocation and pricing, which occupied the forefront of economic thought from that time until the nineteen thirties. In the aftermath of the great depression of the nineteen thirties, most economists, following Keynes (77). focused on the problem of maintaining full employment and the aggregate real demand for goods and services. Interest in the alloca­ tion problem thus waned, while in the wake of the post World War II economic boom interest in the stagnation theory declined 12 also. There was a resurgence of concern with problems of economic growth, both in the developed countries and also in the newly emerging nations. The immediate post-Keynesian growth theories were of a unisectoral nature, notably those of Harrod (42) and Domar

(27}. These general theories tended to stress"the importance of a sustained increase in capital accumulation so that an economy might realize its growth potential in terms of income. Attention was then focused on the capital-labor and capital- output ratios. These earlier models assumed that production took place under conditions of fixed proportions. Eckaus (30) examined the implications of relaxing this assumption. He considered the introduction of multiple processes for the production of a single output. He then incorporated into his model a second sector, relatively more labor-intensive and having variable technical coefficients. His conclusion was that with a high labor-capital ratio in an economy, structural unemployment of labor in the labor-intensive, variable-coefficient sector vfas almost certain to occur. Solow (113) demonstrated that with variable technical coefficients the capital-labor ratio will tend to adjust over time in the direction of an equilibrium ratio. He has also indicated the possibility of multiple equilibria, some of which would be unstable. The implication of this would be that if 13 an tinderdeveloped economy were currently functioning at a stable equilibrium between a low rate of growth and capital- labor ratio; it would tend to return to such a position fol­ lowing an increase in its capita-labor ratio unless the addi­ tion to capital stock was sufficiently large to enable the economy to move towards a higher stable equilibrium rate of growth. This train of thought led to the development of the "Critical Minimum Effort Thesis" by Leibenstein, who states that "in order to achieve sustained secular growth, in the general case, it is necessary that the initial stimulant or stimulants to development be of a critical minimum size" .

(79, p. 94). The concept of dualism was developed by many writers in an attempt to analyze systematically the apparent stagnation of the less developed areas. It was felt by some that the integration of orthodox economic and social theory, with the choice of such assumptions as were appropriate to the insti­ tutional framework of these areas left much to be desired. Attempts were, accordingly, made to develop a new general theory. It will suffice in this regard to examine the work of J. H. Boeke, one of the leading theorists involved. Bo eke (l6, p. 4) defined dualism in social terms. "Social dualism", he said, "is the clashing of an imported social system with an indegenous social system of another style". Because of 14 great differences in social systems. Bo eke felt that most of western economic theory was inapplicable to the less developed areas, "Me shall do well", quoth he, "not to try to transplant the tender, delicate plants of western theory to tropical soil, where an early death awaits them" (16, p. 143). Boeke believed that wants in these areas were limited and that profit seeking motives were absent. Hence, he concluded that there is little which can be done by the western coun­ tries to assist such areas and that any industrialization must necessarily be a slow, protracted process. The relevance of economics to problem solving in the less developed areas has, however, been vehemently supported by Bauer. "I am now convinced", he stated, "of the very wide applicability to underdeveloped countries of the basic methods of approach of economics and. of the more elementary conclusions stemming from these" (10, p. 15). Referring to the alleged inflexibility of wants in these areas, he held that ",..even a static pattern of wants would not destroy the relevance of economics, because the population would presumably wish to satisfy these wants with least effort, and this at once restores the relevance of our subject" (10, p. 22). The emergence of a serious study of the economics of under­ development 2er_se began to occur in the nineteen forties, with the consideration of problems of economies characterized 15 by economic dualism,, that is, economies having a large "tradi­ tional" sector (usually assumed to have a significant amount of "disguised unemployment") existing alongside but practially economically independent of a small "modem" sector. Rosen- stein-Eodan (104, p. 202) asserted in 19^3 that there existed an "agrarian excess population" in Eastern and South-Eastern Europe amounting to 20 - 25 million people out of the total population of 100 - 110 million. "If the principles of inter­ national division of labour are to be applied," he wrote, "labour must either be transported towards capital (emigra­ tion), or capital must be transported towards labour (indus­ trialization)". Rosenstein-Eodan felt that emigration and resettlement would, however, present so many difficulties in immigration areas (and in emigration areas) that it could not be considered feasible on a large scale and hence, "a very considerable part of the task will have to be solved by industrialization" (104, p. 202). Mandelbaum in a 19^5 monograph (8?) presented a detailed model of an industrialization process in South-East Europe. In setting forth his case for industrialization as a policy measure for this area, Mandelbaum (8?, p. 2) also focused on the availability of a pool of labor from the agricultural sector. "They are tied to the land, where in the absence of other outlets they participate in their family*s income without contributing to it to any noticeable extent. An expanding population adds continually 16

to the nvmber of people who are forced to work on fragmented or overcrowded holdings and on inferior soil where their productivity is nil or almost ail (disguised unemployment). If these surplus workers were withdrawn from agriculture and absorbed into other occupations, farm.output would not suffer, while the whole new output would be a net addition to the community's income". Once again, the view was that a substantial reduction of the agricultural labor force of this region would not involve a decline in agricultural output, Mandelbaum goes on to state succinctly that "the economic case for the industrialization of densely populated backward countries rests upon this mass phenomenon of disguised rural unemployment" (8?, p, 2), The views of economists concerned with economic develop­ ment can be regarded as diverging from this stage onward. Some, because of many reasons associated with foreign exchange, changes in factor prices ^ cetera have placed a high priority on industrial development, holding that agricultural develop­ ment would follow in train, Leibenstein (79» p. 264) asserted that ",,.if non-agricultural employment opportunities are created rapidly enough a gradual shortage of labor on the land will arise, the incentive for the introduc­ tion of labor-saving capital on the land will increase steadily, and at the same time the industrial sector, if it expands rapidly enough, should provide the economic climate that is conducive to the expansion of the growth agents". Hirschman (45, pp. 66-67), claimed that ",,,the sequence that *leads away from equilibrium* is precisely an ideal pattern of development from our point of view; for each move in the sequence is induced by a previous disequilibrium and in turn creates a new disequilibrium that requires a further move," 17

He based his argument on the rationale that expansion of one industry would lead to external economies appropriable by another industry which would consequently expand, generating further economies external to itself but subsequently appro­ priable by the first or another industry which is then induced to expand. After briefly commenting on the development of the "doc­ trine" of agricultural fimdamentallsm in the United States, Schultz recently commented (109, p. 133) that "inrecent decades, awholly different doctrine has been espoused in some countries. It holds that industry is always the basic sector in achieving eco­ nomic gro-^h, that farm people are not only bound by tradition but are innately more backward than non-farm people, and that a substantial part of the farm labor force has a marginal productivity of zero value. • The appropriate label for this doctrine is industrial fundamentalism". Balough, writing recently regarding his experiences dur­ ing the early nineteen fifties when he was engaged in inter­ national consultations regarding economic development, stated: "I vividly remember my apprehension of the descent of an PAO mission on-Malta. My fears were amply just­ ified. They came up with a programme costing about as much annually as the value of output. The idea that agricultural, fishery or forestry development was ^ aspect of, and had to be correlated with. general economic planning was regarded as disturbing if not subversive" (63, p. 80). Other economists have recommended that priority should be given to investment in agriculture during the developmental process. Coale and Hoover, for example,. conclude relative to the situation in India that "...if one sector limits the 18

growth of the other, it is mere likely to be a case of agri- culttiral growth limiting non-agricultural than vice versa" (23. p. 139). More recently. Christens en and Yee have stated that "because of the overwhelming size of agriculture and its penetrating links with other sectors, national economic devel­ opment largely depends upon improvement of agricultural pro­ ductivity" (20, p. 106l). In a I963 article, Nicholls set out to demonstrate "...the almost universal importance of having a substantial and reliable agricultural surplus as a basis for launching and sustaining growth" (92, p. 28). Nicholls subsequently drew attention to the vulnerability of the position of those who claim that while increases in agricultural productivity are desirable, they can only be accomplished by giving top priority to a "big push" indus­ trialization program. Their position, he claims, is all the more vulnerable when it is used as a basis for short-run economic planning. In this regard, he states (93, p. 16); "By seriously underestimating the time,, effort and resources required to bring about drastic structural changes in underdeveloped countries, they overlook (and even deprecate) the short-run potentialities of raising agricultural output with given supplies of land and labor and existing small-scale farming units". Similarly, Heady (43, p. 28) has stated that "agriculture may ' have an advantage in development over durable and producers* goods industries in the sense that high payoff is in prospect for the near term". 19

Most economists have tended to favor a balanced approach, recognizing that effective industrial development cannot pro­ ceed without corresponding appropriate development of agri­ culture, In 1954, Lewis stated (82, p. ^33) that "...it is not profitable to produce a growing vol­ ume of manufactures unless agricultural production is growing simultaneously. This is why industrial and agrarian revolutions always go together, and why economies in which agriculture is stagnant do not show industrial development", Lewis* concern was with the development of an economy where population was so large relative to capital and natural resources that there were large sectors of.the economy where the marginal productivity of labor was negligible, zero, or even negative. Such disguised unemployment, he felt, while common in the agricultural sector of most of the less developed areas, was also prevalent in the spheres of casual labor (e.g. among dock workers), petty trades and domestic service. This "unlimited" supply of labor would be available to industry at a "subsistence wage", which might be conventionally determined or else set equal to the average product per capita in agri­ culture, plus a margin to cover such factors as the higher cost of living involved and the psychological cost of transfer from agricultural to industrial emplosnnent. Employment in such an economy would expand as capital formation occurred in the capitalist sector, A rigorous model of the development of a dual economy has been presented by Jorgensen (71), who has considered such 20 development under the assumption that if an agricultural sur­ plus comes into existence it will persist. Another rigorous version of the development of what they refer to as "the typical labor surplus type of underdeveloped economy" has been recently developed by Fei and Banis. Their theoretical construction in this regard is one of the more elaborate in the field of economic development. Postulating the existence of a small industrial sector alongside a predominant agri­ cultural sector characterized by disguised underemployment, the authors state (34, p. 7): "In such a dualistic (two-sector) setting the heart of the development problem may be said to lie in the gradual shifting of the center of gravity of the economy from the agricultural to the industrial sec­ tor, Such a process can be gauged in terms of the re­ allocation of the population between the two sectors in order to promote a gradual expansion of industrial employment and output. Simultaneously, increases in agricultural productivity must be sufficient to permit a relatively smaller percentage of the total popu­ lation to support the entire economy with food and raw materials". There has been considerable controversy regarding the availability of a labor surplus from agriculture. It is generally conceded that there exists some underemployment in agriculture. However, some of the economists quoted earlier have suggested that there was a significantly high number of people in the agricultural labor force who had zero marginal productivity, ^.e. their removal from the farm labor force without their replacement by any capital items would not cause a fall in agricultural production. Eosenstein-Eodan (104) 21 and MandelTaatim (8?) in the nineteen forties were quite opti­ mistic regarding the availability from agriculture of labor for industrialization purposes. Later, Lewis stated in 1955 that "detailed calculations for India, where there are currently about twenty-seven persons gainfully employed in agriculture for each one hundred acres under cultivation have led to.the conclusion that at least a quarter of the agricultural population is surplus to requirements" (84, p. 32?). He further asserted that "this phenomenon,..repeats itself in China, in Indonesia, in Egypt and in many countries of Eastern Europe" (84, p. 327). Opposition to this position was voiced by Schultz (108) in 1956 and by Viner (123, P. 18) in 1957. who stated that he found it "...impossible to conceive a farm of any kind on which, other factors of production being held con­ stant in quantity, and even in form as well, it would not be possible, by known methods, to obtain some addition to the crop by using additional labor in more careful selection and planting of the seed, more intensive weeding, cultivation, thinning and mulching, more painstaking harvesting, gleaning and cleaning of the crop". Kao, Anschel and Eicher (74) have reviewed a number of empirical studies some of which have purported to show that there was a considerable amount of disguised unemployment in agriculture, while other studies have concluded that there was little if any. For example, Pepelasis and Panaghioto- poulos (101) claimed to demonstrate that in the Greek eco­ nomy between 1953 and I960 surplus labor in agriculture was 22 virtually non-existent. In fact, they claimed that seasonal shortages of labor occurred in six of the eight years involved. The authors, using secondary data, measured surplus labor by comparing labor available with the labor required for the given volume of output in the agricultural sector. This study has been criticized strongly in I967 by Dovring (29, p. I66), who pointed out that the labor norms used were essentially the same as those used in a 1939 study by Evelpides, despite the fact that one would expect that techni­ cal progress since 1939 should have lowered the labor require­ ments, even allowing that the 1939 standards were "correct"! Kao, Anschel and Eicher conclude their review (74, p. 141% by stating that; "To date, there is little reliable empirical evidence to support the existence of more than token - 5 per­ cent - disguised unemployment in underdeveloped countries as defined by a zero marginal product of labor and the conditions of ceteribus paribus". Schultz (109, p. 50) suggested that the typical situation in many poor agricultural conmmnities is that the marginal product of labor is very low in agriculture because of the factors at the disposal of the community, but that agricul­ tural labor produces approximately the same at the margin as does comparable labor in other sectors when costs of transfer are properly reckoned. This concept of disguised unemplosnnent in agriculture has been discussed at length because if there is disguised 23 unemployment in agriculture, then the transfer to another sector of the economy of that labor which has zéro marginal, productivity in agriculture will not result in any decrease in agricultural output. If, on the other hand, there is no disguised unemployment, labor transfers from the agricultural sector will result in a loss of output in agriculture, unless other measures are taken to counteract this. The concept of underemployment in the agricultural labor force refers to the situation where the marginal value product of labor in agriculture is less than;that of comparable labor in other sectors of the economy (after costs of transfer are taken into account). In such a case, transfer of labor from agriculture to other sectors would be expected to raise the value of the total product of the economy, but the value of the agricultural product would decrease, unless other inputs were substituted for the labor which was transferred. It is clear, then, that one can expect that the impact of industrial development on the agricultural sector will be dif­ ferent according as that sector is characterized by unemploy­ ment or by underemployment. The historical evolution of the theory of economic devel­ opment has been fraught with bouts of both optimism and pessi­ mism. Many writers have referred to various "circles"; chief among them has been Nurkse (95) who developed the concept of a vicious circle of poverty in which low productivity is due largely to lack of capital, which in turn is the result of the

\ 2!j. low capacity to save, thus completing the circle. The concept of such a vicious circle involves the existence of a circular constellation of forces which tend to act and react on one another in such a way as to keep a poor country in a state of poverty. The process of development involves instituting policies and programs which would induce, in Myrdal*s terminology (90, p. 12), "circular relationship between less poverty, more food, improved health and higher working capacity which would sustain a cumulative process upwards instead of downwards". It has been strongly argued by Eostow (105) when he revived the notion of the existence of stages in the develop­ mental process that all economies can be identified as lying within one of five fairly well defined, stages, of ^qwth. As argued by Galbraith (40, p. 12), "we must recognise that economic development is a process—one that extends in range from new nations in Africa but slightly removed from their tribal structure to the elaborate economic and social apparatus of Western nations. At each stage along this continuum there is an appropriate policy for further advance. What is appropriate at one stage is wrong at another". Some, such as Frankel, have argued for a new international division of labor with the older manufacturing nations assuming "...a higher division of labour by a planned ^ exchange of manufactured products of greater value and quality against foodstuffs, raw materials and manufactured goods of simple design" (36, pp. 193- 194). In other cases, to quote Kellogg (75, p. 157), "the expansion 25 of industry has been looked to for developing the economy "With the unconscious assumption that this can be done with the same old inefficient agriculture with its very low labor in­ come", Bhagwati has recently stated that "it is possible to argue that poor countries should continue producing primary products only if it can be established that they could always earn enough foreign exchange to import their manufactures" (14, p. 165). It is not at all clear that this can be established in the present international trade situation, since in this regard most producers of primary commodities are faced with a situa­ tion of' inadequately expanding exports. Thus the discussion continues. The broad aspects of the theory of development as enunciated herein are widely held. However, it is in the precise application of these aspects that differences emerge. Nearly always these differences revolve around the degree of priority which underdeveloped countries should place on industrialization. The trend towards indus­ trialization as a means of furthering the economic development process is obvious. "The world", according to Kerr ^ al. (76, p. 1), "is entering a new age—the age of total indus­ trialization". The concept of industrialization has been broadened by many writers to include a whole chain of economic social and cultural phenomena. Brzezinski, in 1956, wrote (18, p. 61): 26 "Industrialization involves a number of things. It means "building factories; it means the dis­ placement of the small handicraft entrepreneur; . it means overpopulation of the urban centers; it means the flow of labor away from rural areas; it means the breakdown of the kinship system, rooted in the villages; it means in brief, a tremendous change in the existing way of life". Referring in 196? to the concept of industrialization, Johnson (69, pp. 45-46) used it in a wide context. "By this term", he asserted, "is meant something dif­ ferent from the establishment of *industry* (the production of manufactured products) as distinct from and in replacement of * agriculture * (the pro­ duction of commodities from the soil)". He elaborated this concept as follows; "Industrialization properly speaking involves the organization of production in business enterprises, characterized by specialization and division of labor both within and among themselves; this spe­ cialization is based on the application of techno­ logy and of mechanical and electrical power to supplement and replace human effort and motivated by the objectives of minimizing costs per unit and maximizing returns to the enterprise.... So con­ ceived, industrialization is an economy-wide phenomenon, applying to agriculture and the service trades as well as to manufacturing;: the essence of it is not the production of the products typically considered^ * industrial* but the rational approach to the production process itself that it embodies". While recognizing the broader ramifications of indus­ trialization processes, the author proposes to use this term in the more conventional context of the production of those products which are typically considered "industrial". Des­ pite the emphasis placed on industrialization as a policy measure in the less developed economies, little is really known regarding the specific impact of industrial development 27 on economies which are at different levels of income, or within Eostow* s framework, at different stages of growth. It is imperative, therefore, that such information be gener­ ated, since its availability for intelligent decision making regarding developmental policies should by now be obvious. In addition to the prevailing viewpoint that indus­ trialization is an extremely important avenue towards a rise in levels of living. Bonne (1?) has adduced two further reasons for the apparent world-wide trend towards industrialization, viz. "(a) the lesson of dislocation and shortages caused by the war-time interruption of supply channels between countries providing goods and the lands dependent on them; (b) the trend towards political independence, implying a maximum degree of economic autarchy in the orbit of the great movements for obtaining national and political freedom" (17, p. 99). The occurrence of industrialization arising from such motives as these renders even more importance the elucidation of its economic impact.

B. The Developed Economies

It is generally agreed that the conomic development of what are now regarded as the developed economies originated sometime during the eighteenth century. Much attention has been given to the role played in this developmental process by the so-called "Industrial Revolution", with its attendant inventions and steady increases in productivity in the indus­ trial sector. 28

As suggested by Currie (25, p. 83), insufficient atten­ tion has probably been devoted to "the steady growth in agricultural productivity that not only made the rapid popu­ lation growth possible but also markedly changed the distri­ bution of the labor force". This viewpoint was reinforced by Lewis when he stated (83, p. 124) that "an agricultural and an industrial revolution always go together, the first releasing the labour which the second draws off the land", . In this vein, Currie states further: "The growth in agricultural output per worker released the manpower needed for the great growth in the production of all the other things, and until recent times, the released manpower could be absorbed" (25, p. 83). Problems arising from this relatively recent lack of absorp­ tion of underemployed rural labor into other activities have arisen in many areas within the developed countries. The problem in the developed countries revolves around the,question of whether the development process, to quote Demas (26, pp. 11-12), "ought to imply a fair degree of equality in per capita product and income between different geographical regions or between different econo­ mic sectors of the particular country". Both of these aspects have been combined by Myrdal who asserts their necessity in order to attain "national economic integra­ tion" (91). It is therefore appropriate to review briefly (a) the role of agriculture in economic development, (b) the interrelation­ ships between agricultural and industrial development, (c) the 29 problems of commercial agricult-vire in developed economies, (d) the problems of distressed ireas in developed economies and (e) the contribution which the location of industry in rural areas might make to the solution of such problems as well as to the further development of the a^icultural sector.

The role of agriculture Especially in a closed economy, agricultural progress is normally considered a prerequisite for industrial development. Increases in agricultural productivity can sustain and support industrial development in many ways. Ehke (32) has demonstrated that, given certain assumptions regarding income and price elasticities of demand among agricultural workers, increased agricultural productivity will expand the industrial sector of a closed economy. In developing from a largely agricultural economy, the early non-agricultural sectors would be associated with the provision of transportation, government and other such services, together with some rural crafts. Eventually some inputs would become available from the non-agricultural sector which would hàve""a high productivity relative to other conventional agri­ cultural inputs and relative to their supply price to agricul­ ture. Such items as small tools et cetera might be considered in this category of inputs. The use of these highly productive inputs in the agricultural sector would permit agricultural production to be raised above subsistence level, thus freeing 30 some labor and allowing for some capital accumulation. Hence agriculture would "be releasing part of its labor force for industrial employment and at the same time meeting the increasing food needs of the non-agricultural sector. Secondly, an increase in agricultural incomes resulting from increased productivity of resources within agriculture would provide (a) the rural purchasing power needed to buy the newly-produced industrial goods and (b) a stream of rural savings which may subsequently be used (given appropriate transfer mechanisms) for further industrial development. Thirdly, productivity increases in agriculture can enable the food-needs of the non-agricultural sectors to be supplied at prices favorable to the profitability of new industry. The contribution of rising agricultural productivity may be less in an open economy, since, if Its comparative advan­ tage lay in the production of non-agricultural products, such an economy could choose to import most of its food requirements. However, in such a case, increasing agricultural productivity is advantageous, since (a) rural savings may ease the burden of financing the imports of industrial capital goods and (b) such increases in productivity by raising rural incomes would contribute to the "integration" of the economy (in the Myrdal context). If the rises in agricultural productivity were of a sufficiently high order, such an economy could pro­ duce an exportable surplus of food products which,-if export­ able on favorable terms, might, as pointed out by Johnston and 31

Mellor (70), be one of the best ways of earning the foreign exchange needed for other development projects.

2, Agric-u.ltural~industrial interrelationships There is a high degree of complementarity between the agricultural and non-agricultural sectors during the develop­ mental process. Initially, industrialization increases the demand for "wage-goods". In the early stages of development, food products are the most important goods in this category. This results in more favorable markets for agricultural pro­ ducts and stimulates crop and animal production on a cash basis* However, improvements in agricultural productivity even­ tually have a heavy dependence on the availability (^.e. pro­ duction by the non-agricultural sector) of sufficient ferti­ lizers, tools, machines and other inputs required to take advantage of technological innovations. These inputs, in turn, raise the productivity of the agricultural sector. Industrialization also makes available to the population in the agricultural sector an increased volume and range of consumption goods. If the existence of these new goods raises the "wants" of the farm population in terms of consumption goods, then a further economic incentive is provided for greater productive effort in the agricultural sector. The creation of more productive labor employment oppor­ tunities in the non-farm sector provides a means of diverting 32 from agriculture labor which is underemployed because of the high productivity of the new forms of capital inputs being used in the agricultural sector. Such transfer, if labor resources are mobile, would benefit both those who leave the agricultural sector and those who remain in it, the latter by permitting the combination of greater quantities per capita of land and the newer capital inputs with the remaining mem­ bers of the agricultural labor force. It is usually claimed that an industrial environment creates conditions more favorable to the development of entre­ preneurial talents than does the environment of the agricul­ tural sector. To the extent that this is so, it would, in the development of transportation, storage and processing facilities for agricultural products, create an improved dis­ tribution system for the products resulting from the rising productivity of the agricultural sector and would meet the need for increased quantities of food to be handled by the transportation and processing sectors, arising from a migra­ ting labor from farms to urban areas in the industrialization process.

Problems of commercial agriculture in developed economies Investment in education and research in many developed economies has led to the introduction of many new forms of reproducible capital inputs (e.^, fertilizers, pesticides, machinery ^ cetera) which can substitute for and'increase the 33 productivity of conventional agricultural resources. There have also "been improvements in a number of the conventional agricultural inputs which have increased their productivity also (e._2. improved seed varieties, breeds of animals et cetera). These new inputs and improved conventional inputs have had a high marginal product (high marginal rate of sub­ stitution) relative to other conventional inputs in the agri­ cultural sector. These new inputs have usually been produced by the non- agricultural sector and their supply has been highly elastic. Since the value of the marginal product of these inputs has been quite high relative to their price and since their supply elasticity to the agricultural sector has been quite high, these new inputs and improved conventional inputs have been readily introduced into the production process of the.agricul­ tural sector in most of the developed countries. Their intro­ duction has also been facilitated by the fact that most of these new and improved inputs are highly divisible (e.g. fer­ tilizers, spraying materials, better seed varieties et cetera). Furthermore, many such inputs require little capital and so have been readily adopted. In addition, the supply of credit to agriculture has been relatively elastic in most developed countries, hence further facilitating the adoption of some relatively more expensive new inputs. The rapid adoption of these new and improved inputs by the agricultural sector has led to a substantial shift to the 34 right of the supply function for farm products (as usually defined). This need not necessarily result in an over supply of farm products or a depressed income in the agricultural sector (because of the demand for farm products being of less than unitary elasticity), The increased food production following the introduction of the new and improved inputs and the resultant fall in food prices would, through the market mechanism, bring about a readjustment of the quantities of other inputs in the agricultural sector, if there were free mobility of resources, until all inputs in the agricultural sector would obtain marginal returns comparable to those ob­ tained by comparable inputs in the non-agricultural sector. However, some conventional agricultural inputs have a very low short-run supply elasticity. Labor has a low supply elas­ ticity to agriculture, due to such influences as values, train­ ing, lack of knowledge about alternative employment cetera. Much agricultural machinery is highly specialized to agricul­ tural production and also depreciates slowly. These items have a high supply elasticity into agriculture. However, the short- run supply functions for these items are not reversible once these inputs have been added to the agricultural sector. In other words, many of these inputs also have an extremely low supply elasticity out of agriculture. Once these resources are committed to agriculture, they tend to remain and accept low imputed returns. . 35

Consequently, technological innovation resulting in the development of highly profitable new inputs and improved con­ ventional inputs for use in the agricultural sector of most developed countries has led to rapid increases in farm output in the short-run, with consequent reduction in the price of farm products since demand for farm products has not expanded to the same extent. Given that the price elasticity of demand for farm products is less than unitary, this has resulted in a decline in aggregate farm income in these countries. Thus the marginal value productivity and the imputed returns to the resources of low elasticity have declined. Much of the fore­ going conceptualization draws heavily on research conducted by Heady and Tweeten (44). This, then is the problem of commercial agriculture in many of the developed countries. It has arisen because of the low supply-elasticity of certain resources in the farm sector. Its seriousness has been a matter of national concern in such countries because one of the resources with low supply elasti­ city in the agricultural sector is farm labor. Thus, agricul­ tural incomes per capita tend to lie below the incomes of mem­ bers of the non-farm labor force. Bellerby (12) has demon* strated the existence of large differences between relative incomes obtained by labor in agricultural and non-agricultural occupations in practially all countries. Even allowing for probable divergences of measured incomes from real incomes. 36

Bellerby's data indicate that there is a difference in labor incomes in the two sectors. Kaldor and Saupe (73) recently demonstrated that a reor­ ganization of the farm sector of the North Central States in the U.S. to satisfy the criteria of income-efficiency (j^.e. production of farm output at minimum total factor cost and adjustment of the total level of farm output so that factors employed in the farm sector would obtain returns comparable to those obtained by seminar factors in the non-farm sector) would involve a reduction of 66 percent in the labor input and of 44 percent in the capital input, while involving a reduction of only 9 percent of farm output in terms of the 1959 organization of the farm sector in those states.

4. The "distressed areas" problem Arising from this commercial farm problem there has been large-scale movement of labor out of agriculture. This move­ ment of labor from agriculture tended to be higher in certain - areas than in others, depending partly on the extent to which the forces generating disequilibrium in agriculture acted on different areas and also on the extent to which the agricul­ tural sectors of those areas experiencing the relatively greater disequilibria were enabled to adapt to the changing circumstances throu^ resource adjustments. In many cases, the movement of labor from agriculture has involved migration to local urban centers, to other urban 37 centers within the same country or to emigration from the country involved, the latter phenomenon being of relatively higher frequency in many European countries and in the less developed economies of the world. As pointed out by Olson (99). other secularly declining industries from the employment point of view have existed in the advanced countries since World War II. The more notable in the U.S. have been the coal mining industry and the cotton textiles industry. Similarly in Great Britain and other European countries the coal mining industry has been exhibit­ ing a secular decline in employment. However, employment has also fallen substantially in the U.S. in such industries as the manufacture of earthenware food utensils. "Yet", as Olson reminds us, "the decline of these industries has not created nearly the ratés of unemployment, or the extent of underemployment. or the social dislocations, or the political pres­ sures that have characterized the declines of agriculture, coal mining and cotton textiles" (99, p. 985). It appears obvious, therefore, that the industries which have as they declined left serious economic or social problems in their wake have been those which hâve dominated the com­ munities in which they have been located. Coal mining had been a dominant industry in the Appalachian region of the United States, in South Wales and in certain other regions of Europe now regarded as economically distressed areas. Textile manufacturing had been a major industry of many New England 38 conmnmities in the U.S. Workers in these areas frequently lacked local alternative employment opportunities when these industries declined. Similarly, in the case of agriculture, there has been a role of dominance in the economic affairs of many communities. "In the rural areas and in small country towns there are normally no enterprises apart from farms, and those businesses that sell capital inputs or consump­ tion goods to farmers, or that market farm products. Thus when there is a secular decline in agriculture, there is normally also a secular decline in whatever other businesses exist in the farming area" (99» p. 986), It is clear that as farm employment has declined, with the attendant decline in farm population and as transportation systems have improved, many small rural towns have, lost a con­ siderable degree of their raison d*etre. hence contributing to the economically distressed area problem. Smith (111) has recently compared the problems and charac­ teristics of many such areas with the characteristics of many of the underdeveloped economies of the world who, too, are in quest of industrialization. He has concluded that most of the problems involved in both types of area imply cost disadvan­ tages of varying durations and magnitude to those who venture their capital in such areas. In referring to the problems of industrial.development in the less developed economies, he noted: "The list of problems has a monotonously familiar ring to those who have concerned themselves with the Appalachian area—lack of strategic categories of skilled labor, an inadequate supply of entre­ preneurial and managerial skills, the sometimes 39

irresponsible, unstable or incompetent local govern­ ments, poorly developed or non-existent industrial sites, poor transportation facilities and other items of social overhead capital, problems of market organi­ zation or market penetration in the domain of estab­ lished brand names, developed technologies not suited to local resource configurations, etc."(Ill, p. 1228),

5. Rural industrialization The question arising from the existence of economically distressed areas has been admirably posed by Clawson and Held (22, p. 1031): "Many rural areas cannot possibly expect to hold their populations at present levels over the next decades, but to what extent can the same general area...offer these people reasonable economic opportunity?" Considerable interest has been generated in the possi­ bility of developing new industries in such predominantly rural areas to provide non-farm job opportimities for those people who would otherwise migrate to other areas for employ­ ment, It is claimed that this could enhance the development prospects of both agricultural and non-agricultural sectors in such areas. The development of agriculture depends to a large extent on (a) investment which improves the level of farm technology and the quality of human and reproducible physical resources used in farming and (b) the efficient allocation and use of existing resources in agricultural communities. The develop­ ment of local industrial activity can provide alternative employment opportunities for underemployed farm labor, both 40 in the less developed economies and in those areas within the developed economies where such a problem exists. By providing such alternative employment opportunities, a new source of income for farm investment and perhaps a new spirit of progress, local industrialization may set in motion a set of forces inducing higher levels of agricultural resource productivity, increased farm production, hi^er levels of farm family income and may also lead to a reduction in spatial and personal income inequality, thus contributing to Myrdal*s "national economic integration".

C. Government and Other Programs Designed ^ to Encourage and Promote Industrialization

1, Historical Contrary to popular belief, the initiation of government programs to encourage and promote industrialization is not a phenomenon unique to this century. There is much evidence available which shows that the first efforts at industrial development were assisted (and often initiated) by governments at various stages during the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries in Western Europe, the United States and Mexico. Many such programs have been reviewed by Aubrey (7)# In 1785, the French government stimulated the cotton industry by promoting the French manufacture of cotton-spinning machinery. They provided a factory building, a large cash grant for 41 equipment, a yearly pension to the manufacturer and a bounty on each set of cotton-spinning machines produced. A Belgian law of 1821 set aside certain quantities of customs revenue for the purpose of assisting new and unprosperous industries. In I83O, the Mexican government, less than ten years after the cessation of Spanish colonial rule, placed a customs duty on the importation of cotton goods. One fifth of the customs revenue from such imports was to be placed in a special fund to be used by the Banco de Avio to buy abroad the best manufac­ turing machinery available and to pay the cost of transporta­ tion of such machinery to Mexico. The machinery would then be handed over to prospective manufacturers as a loan and addi­ tional cash loans would also be granted from the fund to cover plant construction and to subsidize the operating costs of the plant in its early years. One of the earliest American public promotions of industry occurred in 1775 when the Assembly of Connecticut granted a loan for the production of textile machinery. In 1776, the Pennsylvania Assembly decided to distribute one spinning machine free to every county. The independent Irish Parliament (Grattants Parliament), which flourished in Ireland from about I78O until the passage of the Act of Union in 1800, granted large sums for the execu­ tion of public works and the encouragement of industry. O'Brien (96, p. 338) stated: 42

"From 1780-85 the annual sum granted for these pur­ poses was about<£50,000; "between I785 and 1790, about <*5100,000; and between 1790 and 1793 about ^150,000. Very large grants were sometimes made for special purposes—for instance, in 1783, «650,000 was given to the proprietors of the Grand Canal, and /25,000 to Captain Brooke to aid him in establish­ ing his cotton manufacturing in County Kildare".

2. Recent programs Efforts to foster industrial development in recent times have been conducted by (a) local groups, either public or private, whose aim has been to promote certain local interests and (b) by governments, either directly or through subsidiary bodies, in order to further policies of broader scope. A further classification is possible based on whether these pro­ grams aided individual industrial enterprises or promoted the development of industrial estates. The literature outlining the merits and demerits of these two methods of industrial promotion is copious. The United Nations Department of Econo­ mics and Social Affairs published a comprehensive study of the role which industrial estates could play in the economic devel­ opment of the less developed countries (120). Three main types of policy can be distinguished: a. Policies based on indirect control These policies aim at inducing (i) decentralization of industry and/or (ii) its development in certain areas by offering special induce­ ments. However, industrialists may commence operations any­ where within the country. The inducements offered usually ^3 provide a differential advantage regarding plant establishment. This is effected by the provision of sites or factories on favorable terms, the payment of grants or the provision of low interest loans to cover site acquisition, plant establishment and training of workers. Sometimes inducements are offered to provide a differential advantage regarding profit expectation. Measures designed to give effect to this may include tax exemptions, provision of public utilities (electricity, water et cetera) at reduced rates and reductions of customs duties on certain imported materials. Examples of this type of policy are the United States Rural Area Development Program initiated in 1955 and the addi­ tional measures undertaken following the passage of the Area Redevelopment Act of I96I in the United States (85); early British policy regarding the "Special -^eas", under the Special Areas (Amendment) Act of 1937 (98, p. 33^); policy in Ireland arising from the Undeveloped Areas Act, 1952 (66); the spon­ soring of three "industrial cities" in Mexico (120, p. 27); the "Policy for the Economic Development of the Northeast" in Brazil (39, p. 284); the establishment of the Cassa per il Mezzogiomo in 1950 to further the development of Southern Italy (88, p. 236); the establishment of the Uganda Develop­ ment Corporation under the "Worthington Plan'L in 1952 (31, p. 247); the development of "rural industrial estates" located in places having less than 2,500 population in India, as 44 reported by Lewis (81, p. 186); the policies for developing Southern Yugoslavia under the 1957-1961 five year plan (19). b. Policies based on direct controls Under such policies, all plans to establish new industry in any part of the country must obtain goverzment approval. Current British policy practically excludes new industry from the London and Midlands areas, thus inducing new location in the less devel­ oped areas (120, p. 32). Ç. Policies based on inducements to investors from abroad Such policies involve inducements such as tax exemp­ tions. Usually intensive promotional work is launched in those countries from which it is hoped to attract investors. Puerto Rico has employed such policies to attract United States investors (120, p. 25). The Irish Government has exempted from tax until 1983 all profits on export sales of products manufactured in the Shannon Airport Customs Free Zone, the development of which has. been documented by Quigley (102), A similar drive has been made to attract United States indus­ trialists to Northern Ireland (94), It is apparent that policies of all three kinds have at various stages been adopted by governments of the developed and less developed countries. In some cases, e.£. Ireland, policies of more than one type may be in effect simultaneously. In addition to official government programs and policies to promote industrial development in certain areas, many local 45

bodies, both local governmental and private, have engaged in campaigns to promote the industrial development of their own locality. Chambers of Commerce, local Development Committees and the like have been active in this respect. The general activities of such bodies would include pre­ paration and distribution of brochures and other literature extolling the advantages (locational and other) which their area had in comparison to other areas, development of "contacts" in the industrial world, arrangement of local tours by indus­ trialists, organization of suppliers of potential new factories et cetera. Furthermore, such bodies might assist in site development and other activities involving local investment. If local governmental bodies are involved, they could offer other inducements. One might claim that these local developmental organiza­ tions have become ubiquitous. In fact, Conway (24) has prepared a directory of area development, organizations in the U.S. which amounts to over three hundred pages I Conway has estimated that "...some 20,000 area development organizations are functioning in the world today" (24, p. 320).

D. Review of Relevant Research Results

The labor force of an industrial plant in South Carolina was studied in 1948 by Stepp and Plaxico.(11?). At that time the plant had 313 employees, whose mean distance of residence 46 from the plant was 8.4 miles. It was estimated that between 77 and 90 percent of the labor force resided within a 30-mile radius of the plant at their time of recruitment. About 40 percent of the employees resided on farms, but less than one- third of these reported that they did any fa.rm work during the year of the interview. Stepp' and Plaxico also interviewed a number of local businessmen and reported that "...the general feeling of the businessmen was that the new mill had brought very little new purchasing power into the community" (117, p. 23). 8tames, Wilkins and Wisman (ll6) studied the labor force of two rural industrial plants in Virginia in 1951. One plant had 247 wage employees while the other had 488. Sixteen per­ cent of the employees at the smaller plant lived on farms, while 25 percent of the employees at the larger plant did so. Eighty-four percent of the employees at the smaller plant re­ sided within 20 miles of the plant; seventy-eight percent of those at the larger plant resided within this distance of the plant. Businessmen in both areas reported that these plants had resulted in a substantial increase in local.business activity. A study in West Virginia in 1957 reported that 70 percent of the employees in a 900-employee plant resided within 30 miles of the plant. However, a substantial number of the skilled workers at the plant had moved into the community on accepting employment at the plant (121). 47

Almon, in 1956, concluded that two large plants located in Kingsport, Tennessee drew "...a little more than half their workers from farm backgrounds (1, p. 836), He also indicated that "...men reared on the farm and men reared in the town make about equally good workers". Hural industrialization studies have also been conducted following the location of industrial plants in Mississippi (86), Louisiana (13), Central Utah (21), Northern Utah (15) and Iowa (72, 119, 38). Twenty-nine percent of the plant em­ ployees in the Mississippi study lived on farms, ninety percent of these being part-time farmers. While 35 percent of the Louisiana plant employees were farm residents, only half of these were farm operators. In Central Utah, 25 percent of the plant employees wçre farm operators, the corresponding percen­ tage being 11 in Northern Utah and 7 in the Iowa study. The possibility of the existence of some selectivity factors was hinted at by Maitland and Wilber in 1958 at the conclusion of their report on the Mississippi study. They state that "perhaps opportunities for industrial employment tend to draw away from farming those who have the weakest attachment to agriculture,... Hural persons with lesser attachment to agriculture tend to be younger...and to be members of lower income farm families" (86, p. 15). The majority of the farm operators employed in the Louisiana plant made no changes in their farm operations as a result of taking a job at the plant. Those who made changes reported only minor adjustments. Farm operators in Central 48

Utah who took jobs at the plant there reported little change in farm operators since -unpaid family labor was usually avail­ able to substitute for some of the work which they had been doing. Two-thirds of such farm operators in Northern Utah reported no change. After investigating the effect of new industry on an Iowa rural conmunity, Kaldor, Bauder and Trautwein (72, p. 82) con­ cluded that there was a high degree of selectivity involved in determining which farm operators took jobs at the new plant. Farm operators accepting such employment tended to be younger and to come from smaller, low income farms with lower than average investments in machinery, equipment and livestock. They found that industrialization had little direct effect on farm output. Of the farm operators who took a non-farm job.

So percent reported no change in farm output, 14 percent a decrease in total output and 6 percent reported an increase. The impact of the . same Iowa plant on local business firms was studied by Punk (38), who found that all kinds of busi­ nesses experienced increases in sales volume as a result of the new plant. However, on the cost side, there were increases in wage rates as a result of the new plant, so that increases in net income as a result of the new mamifacturing plant were reported by 70 percent of the business firms in the town where the plant was located and by 50 percent of the business firms in the other towns in the area included in the study. 49

Stevens and Wallace (118, p. 1) concluded that "employ­ ment and income "leakages" substantially reduced the local impact of local industrial development" in Howard County, Indiana during the period 1947-1960. An employment multi­ plier of 1.444 was calculated for the county. Wadsworth and Conrad in 1966 reported that in Linton, Indiana "...the econo­ mic and social characteristics of the area were the important factors in reducing the employment and income benefits of a new industrial plant" (124, p. 1). They reported that as a result of 100 new industrial jobs created, only two new ser­ vice positions were created in that community. Elsewhere, the same authors state that "in rural labor- surplus areas, the presence of excess labor and idle business capacity reduces the size of the multiplier below that expect­ ed in more rapidly growing areas" (125, p. 1202). More recently. Ruttan has forcefully commented that "the employment-oriented programs are failing to make a significant aggregate impact on under­ employment in rural areas because the resources in rural areas in which major effort is being concentrated (the Appalachians, the Ozarks, the Upper Midwest and others) are not under-developed— they are redundant" (106, p. 1111). Most of the European research which has been conducted regarding rural industrialization has been of a sociological nature. In particular, attention has been focused on the psycho-social adjustment problems faced by rural workers who accept industrial employment. Such search for and acceptance 50

of industrial employment by rural workers in Continental Europe usually has involved migration from rural areas, fre­ quently to other countries within Europe. Hence, a number of international seminars have been organized by the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development in an attempt to elucidate the nature and magnitude of these adjustment problems and to suggest measures designed to facilitate such adjustments, especially by foreign workers arriving in a new country. These matters have been reported in detail by Krier (78), Barbichon (9) and Beijer (11). A few studies have investigated economic aspects of indus­ trialization. One of the more notable of these was conducted by Solli (112), who investigated the economic effects of the establishment of a new steel mill in Eana, Northern Norway, which commenced production in 1946. It was expected that labor

* would be attracted, from agriculture by the new plant, thus inducing changes toward a less labor-intensive agricultural sector in the area. Simultaneously, the large rise in urban population expected as a result of migration of workers from outside the area to accept employment was expected to increase demand for local agricultural products, thus inducing an orientation of the many local subsistence-type farms towards a market economy, Solli found that, by the early nineteen fifties, no significant changes in these directions had occurred. His 51 findings indicate that the Eiain impact of local industriali­ zation on agriculture in the Hana area consisted in a decrease in the agricultural labor force, which, apparently, did not appreciably affect the organization of other agricultural resources in the area. Presumably, sufficient other family labor was available to substitute for any losses involved in farm operators or workers accepting industrial employment, thus minimizing the need for other resource adjustments. 52

III. IRELAND

This chapter contains three sections, the first of which pertains to the Irish economy in general, while the second section describes certain attributes of Western Ireland, which is regarded as the less developed part of the country. Finally, the third section contains a discussion of Irish regional industrial development policies, as they apply to Western Ireland.

A. Ireland

Ireland (Figure 1) is an island which lies to the west of Great Britain. Excluding the larger lakes, rivers and tide­ ways, the area of the island is 20.376 million acres (50, pp. 8 and 356). In all there are 32 counties, 26 of which (containing 17.024 million of the above acreage) form a politi­ cally independent republic, while the remaining six counties form part of the United Kingdom of Great Britain and Northern Ireland. The area referred to hereinafter as Ireland is to be interpreted as meaning Ireland exclusive of the six counties. Geologically, the country consists of a framework of southwest trending Caledonian hills and east-west Armorican chains around which lowlands spread in unbroken continuity (37# p. 7). The Caledonian uplands in the north and west are . separated from those of Scotland by a narrow break. The 53

& I %% (.5 a.?!-» ftttUitJ, A', ^ Oannnyf^c««tr> -u® rw«dI « ,P6rt«.h Rothmullen limtiUl V Î CviHcndun Rethmellon /W/nCoIcfom*/ — *• Lchcfkemny ondonderry L a;ft ML LOKOONOgRftY N( _ Corncfeferg'js Antrim Killybeg» Domegor U \S T BcjfcSt ^NoMowm. DoMW/Jky Collyshonnoft ,^"V®9\0wgoBnon • ^ U^orm 9^/ \ E L A^N Boltjrnohinch A i MAGH £mMi ArmoghT^ Imullet KiUolo Bolltno Vs u I o'-o "^"yînAÎs. Behurbel Duneelk AMH , I 8??re.û^ 5 " \ & A V A N ^Wtflh* AdaL oriShontioii A»*"y r-- ArdS O»/. Wcslpert t ff^Coillereo longFonl Slone^ ( nr^hedo LAW* worries M»inii tf9 Kowth A OUHTY GOIWOY Athonry OolKnoslo^ Ye ** O \^ns>*6wn lovghreo 4^ E I S iT W Wicwow/ VkUpmHi, S / ' Aughnm ^Corlovft— Nenogh AfUow ^ Limenck /Torbert TlJ^ojtow ÊnnîKorrhy gnmonL ; VEXPORD NcwRp» ...wexîoro / . ^Ro«Ior« Ding:* Co»tl^^e^^^y*Cosilpitlond MaUow ! Usmoro < « jjiflcitiwifty Ferni "Dh ^ iSIAM u. Vrfln»*** /* •CoMtciveem^^^,^; MoerQomC 6w,WL ^ Cork j^^rSg^Ounmonwoy London Kinsolo^ C. "•» defchoven BonW/KTf^ lonokilt/. SCAU OP Mills DHumtHhs it. to :0 99 49 Awmef U.W&

Pi gure.1, Ireland 54

Armorican chains in the south have a structiiral continua­ tion in South Wales, England and continental Europe. Most of the country's uplands and mountains lie close to the coast, while the interior of Ireland is a lowland lying mainly between 200 and 400 feet above sea level. In 1966, the total population was 2.884 million people, representing an increase of 2.3 percent from the I961 level of 2.818 million (48, p. 3). This increase contrasts sharply with a decline of 79,923 between 1956 and I96I and a decline of 62,329 between 1951 and 1956. A decline, in population has been reported at each census since l84l, except for the 1966° census and the 1951 census, when an increase of 5,486 per­ sons was reported. Leser (80, p. 200), in 1965, projected that the population would reach a level of 2.920 million in 1971. The Irish crude birth rate (births per 1,000 population) throughout the present century has varied from 23.2 to 19.0 (51, p. 89). The I9OI-I9IO average was 22.5, declining to an average rate of 19.3 during 1931-1940. During and immediately after World War II the rate rose again, reaching a high of 23.2 in 1947. Throughout the following 15 years the rate declined to about 21.0, but by I962 another upswing had begun and in 1964 a crude birth rate of 22.5 was again reported (50, p. 28). The Irish crude death rate (deaths per 1,000 population) has fallen from a I90I-I910 average of I6.9 55

(51, p. 103) and for the past ten years has varied within the range 11.0 - 12.5 (50, p. 28). There is, then, a substantial rate of natural increase in Irish population. However, as noted earlier, population has fallen since 1841, except for two intercensal periods. There has been a substantial emigration from Ireland since 1841. The average rate of net emigration per 1,000 average population was 8.2 in the I9OI-I9II period, falling to 5.6 during I926-I936, but again being'8.2 during 1946-1951 (51, p. 20). The average annual rate climbed to 13.4 during I95I-I956, reached 14.8 during 1956-I96I (50, p. 26), but had fallen to 5.7 during I96I-I966 (48, p. 5). The relative contributions of the major sectors of the Irish economy to Gross National Product (GNP) and the relative magnitudes of the principal items of national expenditure may be seen in Table 1, which contains provisional figures for 1966. GNP in 1966 at current market prices amounted to«61,065 million or^369 per capita®-. National income was «6884 million or/306.5 per capita.- External trade occupies an important place in the Irish economy. Visible exports amounted to .6235 million in 1966. Of this total, «6123 million (52 percent) were classed as agricul­ tural exports. Visible imports, on the other hand, were at a

^ 1 = $2.80 at the time this study was conducted. Table 1. Irish national income and expenditure in 1966 (provisional)^

Income million Expenditure £, million

Agriculture, forestry and fishing 160 Personal consumption 739

Industry 266 Net current expenditure by public authorities 139 Distribution, transport and communication ^ 145 Gross domestic fixed capital formation 191

Public administration and defence 54 Value of physical changes in stock 12

Other domestic 179 Exports of goods and services 337

Rest of the world 46 less Imports of goods and services -399

Allowance for stock appreciation -6 Net factor income from abroad 46

NNP at factor cost 884

plus depreciation 77

GNP at factor cost 921

plus taxes on expenditure ) 144 less subsidies )

GNP at current market prices 1,065 GNP at current market prices 1,065

^Source; (53) 57 level of^364 million. The deficit on visible trade each year is largely offset by a substantial surplus of invisible exports, mainly tourism, income from investments and emigrants* remittances. Arising from a number of circumstances which character- . ized Irish economic life in the early 1950*s and whose rele­ vance has been explored by Eyan and 0*Donoghue (107), con­ siderable attention was devoted during the mid and late fifties in professional and civil service circles in Ireland to the problem of economic development. A study of the Irish economy was conducted by Whitaker during 1958; it was later published by the Irish Government (127). The aims of Whi taker's study were to examine the existential economic situation in the main sectors of the Irish economy and to isolate failure elements and success elements in these sectors from the point of view of achieving economic growth. Carefully distinguishing between the concept of a "pro­ gramme" and that of a "plan", the Irish Government introduced a "Programme for Economic Expansion" in November 1958. A 2 percent per annum rate of growth of GNP was projected in this program for the period 1958-1963. However, a substantially higher rate of growth in GNP occurred during that period. A highly detailed "Second Programme for Economic Expansion" was prepared for the period 1964-1970 and published in two parts, one in 1963 (63) and one in 1964 (64). A target of an average 58 annual rate of real increase in GNP of 4,3 percent was adopted. Sectoral targets were set (consistent with the over-all target). For example, a target of 3,8 percent average annual rate of increase in the sectoral product of agriculture was decided upon, while a target of 7,1 percent was set for indus­ try, The means to achieve these ends were examined in detail in Part II of the Programme. The role of the agricultural sector was examined in detail in a subsequent publication which also contained an analysis of the various policies designed to achieve the targets set for the agricultural sector (52), Progress to date in reaching the targets of the Second Programme for Economic Expansion must b^ regarded as disap­ pointing. During 1966, GOT? in real terms increased by approxi­ mately 1 percent over the 1965 level (53, p. 30). Admittedly, during I966, many policy measures had to be directed towards reducing the deficit on current account in Ireland*s balance of international payments from its I965 level of almost £^2 million. The corresponding deficit in I966 was

occupations (including forestry). The number of males gain­ fully occupied (aged years and over) -was reported as 821,529 or 74- percent of the total. Males engaged in agri­ cultural occupations numbered 350,56^ or 42.6? percent of all males gainfully occupied (aged 14 and over). The gross value of agricultural output (including value of changes in livestock numbers) was«£252 million in I965 (47, p. 95). The value of changes in livestock numbers amounted to 20 million of this total. The remaining «6232 million consisted of «€18? million worth of livestock and livestock products together with 45 million worth of crops and turf. Output of cattle and calves was ;f64 million or 27.6 percent of the total (excluding value of changes in livestock numbers). Milk and related farm products (chiefly butter made on farms) accounted for a further ^57 million or 24.6 percent of gross agricultural output. As might be inferred from the foregoing, grassland farm­ ing occupies a prominent place in Irish agriculture. In 1964, the acreage of crops and pasture was estimated to be 11.517 million. The remainder of the state consisted of "other land", which includes woods, plantations, grazed or barren mountain, turf bogs, marshes, water, roads, railways and land in other uses, e.£,, urban and industrial. Of the land devoted to crops and pasture, 8.147 million acres (70.7 percent) was under pasture. A further 1.932 million acres (I6.8 percent) was » 6o under hay, leaving 1.^38 million acres (12,5 percent) under all corn, root and green crops, flax and fruit. Of the acreage under the latter crops, about 1 million acres was devoted to com crops, while practically all of the remainder consisted of root and green crops. Barley acreage amounted to 4^4,000, oats to 289i000 ^d wheat to 214,000. Potatoes accounted for 182,000 acres, turnips, mangels and fodder beet for a further 151,000 acres, while about 80,000 acres were devoted to sugar beets. In 1965 the total number of cattle in the state, as recorded at the June enumeration, was 5.359 million, of which 1.547 were milch cows (50). Sheep numbered 5.014 million, while there were 1.266 million pigs, over 11 million poultry and 172,000 horses. Irish agricultural output remained relatively stagnant in the immediate years subsequent to World War II, thus dif­ fering from the experience of most other western nations. The index of the volume of gross agricultural output including turf and the value of changes in livestock numbers (base year; 1953 = 100) stood at 91.4 in 1938-1939 (47, p. 95). By 1956, 11 years after the war, this index had reached a level of 103.5, while its 1958 value was 99.8, following the unfavorable harvest conditions of that year. The I965 level of this index was 124.0.

) 61

The Commission on Emigration and other Population Problems, appointed by the Irish Government in 1948, considered the agricultural sector of the economy and made a number of recom­ mendations aimed at increasing farm incomes throu^ reduction of farmers* costs, to be achieved by a number of investment schemes, the cost of which would be borne by the government sector, e.£., public schemes for land improvement, animal disease control, et cetera (51). During the period 1955-1958, the National Farm Survey was conducted. According to the 1955 results of this survey, the mean family income per unit of family labor on farms between 30 and 50 acres" in size was 264 per annum, practically equivalent to. thé then wage rate for hired agricultural laborers (97, p. 99). As a result of these findings, considerable attention was devoted to the agricultural sector, as noted earlier, in the First and Second Programmes for Economic Expansion. Statistics in relation to Irish industries are classified for census purposes in the following manner. The category Transportable Goods Industries include mining, quarrying, non- farm turf production and manufacturing industries. The desig­ nation All Industries includes the transportable goods indus­ tries, building and construction, local and central government, railways, canals, public utilities (electricity, gas and water) and laundry, dyeing et cetera.Commerce, personal services, education, professional services, entertainment et cetera are 62 not included in the industrial census. However, occupational data pertaining to these latter activities are collected in the Census of Population, When the Irish.Free State was established in the early 1920*s, industrial activity played a relatively minor role in its economy. Slightly over 1.22 million people were reported as being "at work" in 1926, of whom 53 percent were engaged in agriculture (127, p. 150). The average number engaged in All Industries (as defined) was 103,000 in 1926, about 11.5 percent of those "at work". During the period 1932-193^, measures were introduced to encourage the development of new manufacturing plants which were protected against foreign competition in the home market. Since 1936, the index of net output of the Transportable Goods Industries (as defined earlier) has risen from 59 to a level of 178 in 1966 (base year; • 1953 = 100), while employment in these industries has risen from'100,000 to an estimated 205,000 persons during the same period (53* p. 9).

B. Western Ireland

The western have for long been regarded as a special area having social and economic problems more severe than those found elsewhere in the country. The Congested Districts Board was established under the Purchase of Land (Ireland) Act of I89I. This board was empowered to 63 aid agriculture, forestry, fishing and home industries in the Congested Districts which were defined at that time as including portions of all the western counties, ezcept for Clare, The Congested Districts were enlarged by the Irish Land Act of I909 to include eight whole counties, Gialway, • Lei trim, Sligo, Mayo and Roscommon (which comprise the province of Connaught), together with counties Donegal, Clare and Kerry along with part of West Cork. The eight counties contain 43.3 percent of the total area of the state; omitting "other land", these counties contain 33«5 percent of the total agricultural area. In 1966, the population of these counties was 696,881 or 24.2 percent of the total population of the state, a fall of over 26,000 from the 1961 level. These counties have historically been charac­ terized by high rates of net emigration, as shown in Table 2. In each intercensal period from 19^6 to 1966, each of the counties had a higher rate of net emigration than had the state as a whole. In some instances the rate in some western counties has been twice as high as the national rate. The data obtained in the National Farm Survey indicate that labor and family farm income per unit of total labor was substantially lower in the north and west than elsewhere in the state. Similarly, labor and family income per acre (ad­ justed to allow for pasture equivalent of "other land") was lower in the north and west. These differences hold for all farm sizes surveyed (49). Table 2. Average annual rate of net emigration from each county in western Ireland per 1,000 of average population

Average annual rate of emigration Area 1946-1957& 1951-I956® 1956-1961* 1961-1966%

Galway 15.3 15.2 16.2 10.6 Leitrim 18.7 23.1 22.7 19.1 Mayo , 15.3 19.1 20.3 17.1 Roscommon 15.9 16.1 17.9 11.7 Sligo 10.8 17.1 16.6 12.7 Donegal 14.6 20.2 17.9 15.0 Clare 15.9 15.9 14.9 6.3 Kerry 17.7 14.0 15.2 11.2

Ireland 8,2 13.4 . 14.8 5.7

^Source!• (50). ^Source: (48). 65

Attwood and Geary (6) estimated that personal income per capita in Ireland was200 in i960. In all eight western counties personal income per capita was lower than the national average, ranging from «6153 in Mayo and Donegal tojfl78 in Gaiway, In fact. Mayo and Donegal had the lowest level of. personal income per capita in the state, Hannan (41) studied the factors involved in the migration decisions of rural youth in Conty Cavan, which had a i960 personal income of 164 per capita and which is adjoining the eight counties in question. His conclusion was that beliefs about one*s ability to fulfill occupational and income aspira­ tions in the home community (occupational and income frustra­ tion) were the most significant variables in explaining the emigration plans of rural youth, even if such youth felt that their families had work expectations for them, which could only be fulfilled by remaining in the home communtiy. Declining population and high rates of emigration from the western counties have induced discussion regarding the feasibility of maintaining an adequate population and taxation base in these areas for the functioning of local government • units, schools, churches, hospitals, recreational facilities, distribution channels and other economic and social institu­ tions. As suggested by 0*Mahony (100,p. 14), "When the decline in population occurs through emigra­ tion, it is possible—though by no means always certain . —that the more enterprising and ambitious people leave..." 66

If this were so, it would tend to induce a certain degree of stagnation in these areas. 0*Mahony further asserts that "emigration seems also to produce certain attitudes of mind and patterns of behavior which are prejudicial to economic development" (100, p. 14). Arensberg, who studied rural social structure in County, Clare during the 1930*8, concluded, relative to the "Irish countryman", that (4, p. 71): "He finds his role in life and farm labour made for him in the groups to which he belongs. His activities, incentives and rewards take shape within the habitual expectation and mutuality which make up the pattern of his family", Arensberg and Kimball, in a subsequent publication on Irish rural life state that "...the sociological conditions of Irish rural life are those"determined in a system of relationships among persons based upon the Irish form of the family, family subsistence and familistic custom" (5» p. 309). They describe a traditional economy in western Ireland, which they claim has "an equilibrium which it regains after each "disturbance" (5, p. 310), However, the more recent work by Hannan indicates that views of rural youth regarding familistic expectations of them are not a deterrent to migration if these youths exper­ ience income and occupational frustration. In addition to migration to places outside Ireland, there has been consider­ able migration to Dublin. Recent research into the family 67

organization of such migrants to Dublin "by Humphreys (46) has shown that, following this migration, "although the family retains other very important functions, the loss of its productive function has effected a decline in the interfamilial solidarity and in the power and functions of the family and of familial organizations in general" (46, p. 251). As noted earlier, slightly over 35 percent of those gain­ fully employed (aged 14 years and over) in the state were engaged in agricultural occupations (including forestry) in 1961, When fishing, turf production, mining and quarrying are included along with the foregoing, it is found that 36.9 percent of those gainfully employed are engaged in primary production. However, in the eight-western counties, the proportion engaged in primary production in 196I ranged from 55.35 percent in Donegal to 72.42 percent in Leitrim. Much attention has accordingly been devoted to the possibility of developing additional nonfarm employment opportunities in these counties in hopes of satisfying occu­ pational and income aspirations in these areas, thus tending to reduce net emigration from the western counties. There have been, however, substantial obstacles to be overcome in fostering such a process. As stated recently by Donaldson (28, p. 117): "This section of Ireland, in contrast to Cork or Dublin, has been since time immemorial an agri­ cultural area. The ways and thoughts of an 68

agricultural community have "been instilled in each succeeding generation over the centuries..,. Factories are alien, suspect. They are not part of the established order of things, of nature. It is a country where the same plot of rocky soil and whitewashed farmhouse have often been in the family for 500 years. Trading villages have flourished for a time...But, in the end they're gone. The land, the sheep, the customs and thoughs of an agricultural way of life remain...These are eternal".

C. Regional Industrial Development Policy in Ireland

. Specific financial and other assistance designed to in­ duce the establishment of industrial plants in western Ireland was offered by the Irish Government following the passage of the Undeveloped Areas Act of 1952 (66). Section 3 of the act delineates its area of application as (a) the congested districts (j^,e,, the area referred to in the last section) and (b) any other area to which, by order of the Minister for Indus and Commierce, the act is for the time being declared to apply. Any area to which the act applied was referred to as "an undeveloped area". wide powers to acquire land, way-leave or other land or water right (if necessary, by cumpulsory means), to construct, adapt and maintain buildings, to provide services in connec­ tion with land, to make grants to individuals to (a) acquire land, (b) construct, adapt and maintain buildings and other works, (c) acquire machinery and equipment for an industrial 69 undertaking, (d) provide training (either in Ireland or abroad) of workers, to make grants where necessary for the provision of infrastructural elements, specifically the construction and repair of roads, bridges, harbor works and railway lines and facilities together with the provision of houses, canteens and other places of refreshment or recreation for persons employed in any such undertaking. The goals and criteria of the new policy were set out in Section 5 of the act, which states (66, p. 7): For the purpose of providing and facilitating the provision of sites and premises for the establish­ ment, development or maintenance in an underdeveloped area of an industrial undertaking in respect of which the Board are satisfied that— (a) it would be likely to provide or maintain employment in such area, and (b) financial assistance is necessary to ensure its establishment, maintenance or develop­ ment, and (c) it is of a reasonably permanent nature and will be carried on efficiently, the Board may, on such terms as they think proper,...". Some minor legislatives amendments were contained in the Undeveloped Areas (Amendment) Act of 1957 (67), but this act dealt mainly with continuation of the legal powers of the board established under the 1952 act. Most of this act was subsequently repealed in I963 by the Undeveloped Areas (Amend­ ment) Act of 1963 (68). Separate grants for buildings and equipment were abolished and replaced by a single over-all 70

grant. The maximum grant payable in the undeveloped areas set at two-thirds of the total estimated cost of a project where the total grant would not exceed250,000. For pro­ jects in respect of which grants in excess ofjTZ^O.OOO were to be paid, the maximum was set at 50 percent of estimated ' total cost of of1,000 per additional job expected by the board to be created as a result of the industrial project.

I Excluding projects for which grants were approved but which did not proceed, a grant total of/10,472 million was approved for 165 projects in the undeveloped areas during the period from January 1952 to March 31, 1966 (6l). The estimated employment expected to be directly generated by the projects for which grants were approved was 15,130. This represents a grant approval of «6692 per estimated addi­ tional industrial worker. However, of the amount approved, slightly over if6.5 million had been paid out by March 31, 1966, Fennell (35) has estimated that the establishments to which ^1.723 million was paid in grants up to March i960 actually had an employment of 2,632 workers, representing a grant expenditure of nearly«6650 per job. Schemes to foster industrial development in western Ireland are regarded by the Irish Government as a part of an over-all strategy to increase incomes in these areas. Refer­ ring to western Ireland, in the I967 Budget Statement, the Irish Minister for Finance stated (62, p. 19): 71

"Althou^ every effort is "being made to intensify agricultiiral development, the expansion of incomes of the rural community can be achieved only by a comprehensive development programme aimed at in­ creasing employment and income derived from indus­ try, tourism, angling, forestry and fishing as well as a;griculture'.'.

\ 72

IV. THE STUDY LOCATION

In an endeavor to select suitable sites for conducting the present study, Irish industrial and agricultural statis­ tics pertaining to the west of Ireland were examined in detail. Certain criteria were established to aid in the area selection process. First of all, it was desired to study- plants which had been located in predominantly rural labor market areas, in order to elicit information regarding indus­ trialization effects on agriculture. Secondly, in order to enhance measurability of industrialization effects, preference was given to areas containing plants which had a reasonably large size of operation, in terms of labor force employed, relative to other nonfarm employment in those areas. It was also felt that plants which had exhibited a reason­ ably substantial rate of growth in employment during the previous five or six years would be most suited to the study. Furthermore, plants having a large proportion of males employed were sought, since the economic impact of such plants, espe­ cially on the farming sector, was expected to be greater than that of plants having a mainly female labor force. Consideration was also given to the presence of natural geographic features which might facilitate the delineation around the plants to be studied of areas in which the bulk • of the effects of the new plants might be expected to be felt» Ideally, it was desired to identify plants of reasonable size. 73

located, with the assistance of An Foras Tionscal, in places where formerly there was no other manufacturing activity and around which well defined areas could be delineated such that confounding of effects would be minimized and measure­ ment of effects facilitated. On these bases, two areas were selected. One was around , Co. Sligo, about 120 miles northwest of Dublin. The other area was around Scarriff, Co. Clare, which is about 120 miles west by southwest of Dublin. These two areas are shaded in Figure 2. Section A of this chapter contains a description of these two areas, while the new industrial plants which were established in these areas are discussed in Section B.

A. The Two Areas

1, The Tubbercurry area The town of Tubbercurry is situated in the southwestern part of . In 1956, Tubbercurry had a population of 933 persons. Population had declined to 878 by I96I, but by 1966, the population had risen to 937 persons. Most of the land near Tubbercurry is between 200 and 400 feet above sea level. There are few level tracts of land in this lowland which is mainly composed of drumlin-drift terrain. Reference to Figure 3 shows that to the west of Tubbercurry lie the Ox Mountains, a Caledonian ridge, varying in height 74

Abe>(M« OonrvmfJ ^rtrvsh RolnmwUem^ Rothinelton«< _v^M?Ay4C6rcromc/ -f •.Lciterkenny ^ 'Londonderry 0 O N 6 o A L rflf *--?*--1 Î.OMOONOE8RV>_ ..M y, • «f «.kW "» CwvrMfw J [sirobose. U i T " •" Çtentîc^ N CL-IV~T^H s "Ei Nt _ CorricVfcrj-js •'OoBogo^^' ^ y BO N ev^/> U ^ »-/mwa»^Dtti>3onnon # V,,' -j sTT"- Do«rg<,fISt* ' IK £ L • A{

fiw» MA rf

ImuKet Kiilolo I L ^Newtown Wier r *V^\Ncwfy* ( ] * 6oKîno MONAGWAN,/ J "^4 n'OondoIk •!>eW uy <%w Q •CUnL^Bar —^«rWMlport ; »-^CMlIereo . J: , CON ,U/Gr\H T. ^VSoven >-^1^ RoKommon, . Alhbo^* ^olbnggom Sollînrabe MolKngofV fT-t Ikoffîes -:. VV '• %Swofcl$ Kilcoek Srv^AiirfK Golwoy oUHTY leughraa 4^ ^ortarlmgîon^J • Portvmna* I >E 1 rè s E \% ' / crv(_^ul7M COÎNT?^^'' nC^CV^

K'llnuh Limerick:!%Wirick /y ^'%.^^'^*^g^l(llKENNY%KILKENNY ^ ,'/'NcWlownbortyl Nc^^nborrA UvM •Torbert Mmlltrf>l" ^ Kttylid. %! ^ ^ Cohc^ V/exford^o..lore 1 ' Oîjgio Co»l!emo;fl/^Co.ite;U^nd /ïàCZT^ t « ° •« gl»'»"''» Femioy-V^J 4*"——ys^*^forra sf scAie o# Miies » 99 49

10

Figure"2. The study areas 75

J,, '\;j:yriCh^^fA>-«w tnr- .r \/.rCh!%omci^K Xtiuuptiy rl. utjhria UT^ XiUlU/HIJJ V a •" f- Str^àtlhiU. RA % V«*«»'ltN».*IV

^nrtinuàd l/>.' _ . îi-—/i v^snrrsifj

- Sfu>otutff Z*,

'firtuiçnjUU

K-

ouffhXt \J>rus£i£iv. ^^CattLii _ •^rmr.n •2as o^msa ' T.Matnma<^^ ^JjCOOUsU^ \^A (y-. mxz \ ^tofufUfrfc jui^ighhonaiut $ Ciinv Cù>o*ùaffl^^

UumuitaKSS^tuiijj^-Vïïi?.ÏC Bruhrr ll'fV 3htjj;jsfy, |:'.y^ % nw/ •

hnttM

Figure 3, The TuTDbercurry area (based on the Ordnance Stirvey by permission of the Government of the —Permit Ho. 997) 76

from 600 to 1,800 feet above sea level and extending in a northeast-southwest direction. As stated by Freeman (37, p. 44-9), "...they form a clear population divide between the closely settled lowland on either side: the only important break is ' the gap, which carries the road and railway to Sligo. The moun­ tains are a desolate expanse of spongy bog, which has a depth of 2 feet on the numerous massive erratics that occur on the high ground". • On the basis of preliminary information, an area was defined around Tubbercurry, such that it was expected to contain the residences of practically all of the plant employ­ ees. This area comprised the Rural District of.Tubbercurry together with some additional adjoining Distric Electoral Divisions, a list of which is contained in Appendix A, For Irish census purposes, a "Census Town" is defined as a cluster of twenty or more occupied houses. The delineated area con­ tained seven such towns of which the largest was Tubbercurry in 1966. These towns together had a I966 population of 3,130 persons, a decline of 83 from the I96I level. The total 1966 population of the area was 16,793 persons. Hence, the vast majority of the area*s residents were farm and rural nonfarm people. Farms in the area are relatively small and are largely pastoral, cattle production being the predominant enterprise. In i960, less than 3 percent of the land in the Tubbercurry Rural District was under grain, root and~green crops. Say- occupied about 9 percent, while 46 percent was under pasture. 77

The other 42 percent was classed as "other land", a term whose interpretation has been discussed earlier. Total grain crops occupied 1.73 percent of the land. Oats comprised 93 percent of this acreage. Total root and green crops occupied 1.15 percent of the land, about $4 percent of 'the root and green crop acreage being devoted to potatoes. The Rural District contained about 30»000 cattle, of which 25 percent were milch cows. In addition there were about 3,000 pigs, 30,000 sheep and 1,000 horses. Immediately prior to the establishment of the manufactur­ ing plants on which the present study is based, there was no manufacturing activity in the Tubbercurry area. However, it was not always so. The celebrated chronicler of yesteryear, Arthur Young, visited the area in 1776 and reported-that Lord Shelbume came to the area some 20 years previously, the area then being "...a wild uncultivated region, without industry or civility; and the people all roman catholicks, without an atom of manufacture, not even spinning" (128, p. 188). Lord Shelbume then attempted to establish a weaving enterprise in , but the project met with little success, as Lord Shelbume died shortly after its inception. In 1774", a Mr. Pitzmaurice erected a bleachmill in Ballymote and installed looms, of which there were 90, when Young visited the area in 1776. Young observed that the 80 looms which were in operation in 1775 78

"...besides the 80 weavers, employed 80 persons more, which are usually women, quilling warping and winding; the quilling by children and half as many children for quilling; in all, 80 men, 80 women and 40 children" (128, p. 190). Subsequently, the plant expanded somewhat but, during the following century declined and, eventually, ceased operations.

2. The Scarriff area The second location chosen was in the eastern part of County Clare, The town of Scarriff had a population of 698 persons in 1956, 600 in 196I and 673 in 1966, As may be observed in Figure 4-, Scarriff is situated on the western edge of Lough Derg, one of the lakes on the Biver Shannon. Thus, this lake forms quite an effective boundary on the eastern side of the area being delineated around Scarriff, since the first bridge across the Shannon to the south of

Scarriff is at Killaloe, about 10 miles distant, while to the north of Scarriff, the lake extends to Portumna, Co.

Galway, which is over 20 miles distant. On the northern side, the Slieve Aughty Mountains form an effective divide roughly coinciding with the Clare-Galway county boundary. The town of Killaloe, situated on the west bank of the

Eiver Shannon, about 10 miles south of Scarriff had a I966 population of 816 persons and is joined by bridge to Ballina which is on the east bank of the Shannon and had a I966 popu­ lation of 271 persons. However, Ballina lies in County Tipperary, the Shannon forming the county boundary at this point. 79

-. fAww/.à

'•StoifA^ hpr^iKyV. ^w^yhwLl 5%%Upmi

i^fwonl^m J »»vv.^ 4/Kn^ «S Vwi- jr I -W4Zp% , \hv" \ '4* ". y'''•"" ^//tûr%

»T»#. .•'^V V . Jft • a a y^ J# - '

• % r f SILVtItMfjVf•Çjitf/^WJAwwArm

Figure 4. The Scarriff area (based on the Ordnance Survey by Permission of the Government of the Republic of Ireland—Permit No. 997) 80

Since none of Cotinty Tipperary has been included in the Congested Districts or in the Undeveloped Areas and since the interest of the present study lay in these latter areas, it was decided not to include any of County Tipperary in the area to be delineated' around Scarriff. It was realized, of course, that some of the Scarriff employees were likely to be residents of Ballina, County Tipperary, since the two towns are about 11 miles apart. The area delineated contains the entire Rural District of Scarriff, together with some addi­ tional District Electoral Divisions (from and Meelick Sural Districts), which adjoin the west and southwest bound­ aries of the Scarriff Rural District. A- complete listing of these District Electoral Divisions is contained in Appendix A. In all, the area defined around Scarriff, contained 6 towns, of which Killaloe was the largest, having a I966 popu­ lation of 1^3 more persons than had the town of Scarriff. These 6 towns had a combined 1966 population of 2,086 persons, representing an increase of 59 over the I96I level of 2,027. The area defined had a 1966 population of 7,572 persons. Thus, as in the case of the Tubbercurry area, the vast majority of the population of the area were farm or rural nonfarm residents. The land utilization pattern of the Scarriff Rural District in i960 showed some differences from that of the Tubbercurry Rural District. The land devoted to grain, root and green crops was slightly over 3 percent of the total, slightly. 81 larger than the proportion in Tubbercurry, However, 1.21 percent of the land was under grain crops, as opposed to 1.73 percent in Tubbercurry, while 1,86 percent consisted of root and green crops, compared with 1.15 percent in Tubbercurry. Thus, root and green crops were relatively more prevalent than grain crops in Scarriff. Further differences occur in the mix of grain crops and of root and green cropsi Oats and potatoes were of relatively less importance in Scarriff, though still comprising the bulk of the grain, root and green crops. In Scarriff, oats consti­ tuted 70 percent of the grain crop and potatoes accounted for 60 percent of the root and green crop acreage, compared with the corresponding figures of 93 percent and 9^ percent, res­ pectively, which were noted earlier in the Tubbercurry Sural District. Say (13 percent) occupies a greater proportion of the land than in Tubbercurry (9 percent). The amount under pas­ ture (47 percent) is also slightly larger while the propor­ tion of "other land" (37 percent) is correspondingly less than in the Tubbercurry Rural District (4-7 percent). The Scarriff Rural District contained about 30,000 cattle, less than 2,000 pigs and less than 10,000 sheep in i960. However, the number of horses was greater than in Tubbercurry. The uplands in the area have some sheep farming, but the raising of cattle is again of greater importance throughout the area. 82

Industrial activity (other than at the plant under study) is rather sparse in the area. In Scarriff itself, there is a creamery. Nearby, there are some sawmilling operations, while in Killaloe, there is a weaving enterprise in which the employees are mainly females. Based mainly in Killaloe, a fairly important and expanding tourist industry has been developing recently in association with the develop­ ment of Lough Derg as a resort area.

B. The New Plants

1, Tubbercurry During the year ended March 31, 1956, Basta. Limited received approval for a grant of c620,000 from An Foras Tionscal to establish a plant in Tubbercurry for the manu­ facture of locks, ^ cetera (5^). The grant was paid during the same year and the plant commenced operations. As part of its requirements, this plant needed tooling services, so a small workshop was subsequently set up to provide the required tooling services. As the latter operation continued to grow, it was decided to incorporate it as another company. Thus, The Tool and Gauge Company of Ireland, Limited came into being, and during 1959/60 received approval for a grant of 5^,600 from An Poras Tionscal (55). Grant payments to this company in 1959/60 amounted to ,^25,300 (55). During I96O/6I, the company 83 received.11,205 (56), while a further^f3,000 was paid them in 1961/62 (57). During 1963/64 the grant paid was-510,300 (59), another

Using the size classification proposed by Staley and Morse (115." p. 14), in which industrial firms having less than 10 employees are classed as very small, those having 10 and less than 100 classed as small and -those having 100 and less than 250 employees are classed as medium, it is to be noted that each of the three Tubbercurry plants is in the small category. Hence, in combination, they may be considered as three small plants. However, since the impact of all three is to be examined as if they were one establishment, the three plants together may be regarded as one medium-sized industrial undertaking.

2. Scarriff A grant of^314,000 was approved by An Foras Tionscal during 1959/60 for the establishment of a plant in Scarriff by Chipboard, Limited (55). Of this amount, <6191,000 was paid to the new firm during 1959/60, ^19,000 during 1960/61(56), i'10,500 during 1961/62 (57), i"3,500 during 1962/63 (58) and i'45,000 during 1963/64 (59), while the balance ofjf45,000 from the original grant approved was paid to the firm during 1964/65 (60). As its name implies. Chipboard, Limited is engaged in the manufacture of chipboard, which is used extensively by the building trade. A large volume of production is exported from Ireland, mainly from a port on the east coast. As the product is quite heavy relative to value, the transportation . 86 costs involved are rather large. The company has acquired its own fleet of lorries which haul the chipboard over the 120 or so miles to the port. Partly in response to this cost situation. Chipboard, Limited has recently commenced further processing of some of the chipboard into veneered and plastic faced chipboard for use in higher quality kitchen units ^ cetera. Towards this end. An Foras Tlonscal during 1965/66 approved an "adaptation grant" ofj^^3i500 to Chipboard, Limited (6I). Most of this grant was paid to the company during 1965/66. Scarcely any of the products manufactured by Chipboard, Limited are sold within the area. Hence, once again, the direct effects of the new plant would be expected to occur via factor demand. Inputs required by Chipboard, Limited include labor services, timber, glue, plastic et cetera. Some, but not much timber is acquired within the area; currently, the firm acquires timber from a wide geographical .area.. Practi­ cally all of the nonlabor inputs are purchased from: suppliers outside the area. Thus, the direct effects of Chipboard, Limited on the Scarriff area would occur almost entirely as a result of the hiring of labor services from within the area, VJhen this study was conducted in 1966, Chipboard, Limited had 19^ employees up through the rank of working foreman, including office personnel. Management personnel were excluded from this count. Employment at the plant was initially about 80 during i960. About 50 more employees were added in the 87 following year and employment at the plant has since grown rather steadily to its current level. Hence, it is seen that this plant also falls, according to the Staley and Morse classification, into the medium-sized category. 88

, V. THE PLANT EMPLOYEES

This chapter contains a descriptive analysis of the labor force of the industrial plants in the two areas. Certain personal and household characteristics of the plant employees are discussed in Sections A and B, while Section C focuses on characteristics of the present employment of these employees. In view of the special interest of this study in the employment of farm people at the new plants, personal and farm business characteristics of farm opera­ tors who obtained plant employment are examined in Section D.

/ A. Employee Characteristics

In July 1966, the Tubbercurry factories had I83 employ­ ees up through the rank of working foreman, while the Scarriff factory had 194 such employees. In addition, each factory had a group of management personnel. Interviews were obtained with 157 employees in Tubbercurry and with I51 employees in Scarriff. Twenty-five of those not interviewed in Scarriff were either timber-workers or lorry drivers who were not available for interview. Various personal characteristics of the employees interviewed are described in this section. 89

1, Sex As lists of all plant employees were supplied by the factory management personnel, it was possible to determine the sex of all plant employees in each area. Hence, in Table 3» which contains the distribution of plant employees by sex, data are presented regarding all the plant employees and in regard to those plant employees who were interviewed in connection with the present study. Forty-five of the Tubbercurry employees (about 25 percent) were females, while there were 10 females (slightly over 5 percent) employed at the Scarriff plant. Twenty-six percent of the employees inijerviewed in Tubbercurry were females, while 6 percent of those interviewed at the Scarriff plant were females. Thus, the proportion of males and females in the sample of plant employees interviewed was about the same as that obtained among all plant employees.

Table 3. Distribution of plant employees by sex

Tubbercurry Scarriff Number Percent Number Percent

Total employees Male 138 75.4 184 94.8 Female 45 24.6 10 5.2 Total 183 100,0 194 100.0 Employees interviewed Kale 116 73.9 142 94.0 Female 41 26.1 9 6.0 Total 157 100.0 151 100.0 90

2. MÊ Plant employees are classified by age in Table k. In general, the Tubbercurry employees were younger than the Scarriff employees, the mean age of the former group being 25.6, while that of the latter group was 32.8 years. The median age of Tubbercurry employees was 21 years, 9 years lower than the median age of Scarriff employees. Similarly the modal age was also lower in Tubbercurry than in Scarriff. These data regarding age were obtained during the interviews with plant employees,

2* Marital status Information obtained during the interviews regarding the marital status of the plant employees is contained in Table 5. Thirty-seven percent of the male employees aged 18 years and over in Tubbercurry were married, while 45 percent of the male employees aged 18 years and over in Scarriff were married. All but one of the female employees in Tubbercurry were unmarried, while none of the female employees in Scarriff was married. As there was a much higher proportion of females employed in Tubbercurry than in Scarriff, it is seen that 38 or 28 percent of the em­ ployees aged 18 years and over who were interviewed in Tubbercurry were married, while the corresponding number of married employees interviewed in Scarriff was 63 or 4-3 percent. It is thus seen that the labor force of the new 91

Table 4. Distribution of plant employees by age

Tubbercurry Scarriff Number Percent Number Percent

Under 15 1 0.7 15 and under 20 48 30.5 14 9.3 20 and under 25 52 33.1 40 26.5 25 and under 30 17 10.8 20 13.3 30 and under 35 11 7.0 15 9.9 35 and imder kO 8 5.1 18 11.9 40 and under 45 11 7.0 15 9.9 45 and under 50 3 1.9 10 6.6 50 and under 55 3 1.9 9 6.0 55 and under 60 1 0.7 6 4.0 60 and over 2 1.3 4 2.6 Total 157 100.0 151 100.0 Mean age 25.6 32.8 Median age 21 30 Modal age 19 20

industrial plants in both areas consisted largely of unmarried people, with about 4-0 percent of the male employees being married and practically all of the female employees unmarried. Table 5» Marital status of plant employees by sex

Tubbercurry Scarriff Male Female Male Female Marital Status Number cent Number ?iHt Number fiSt Number cent

Married 37 37.4 1 2.9 63 45.0 . 99m MMC3CI

Single 61 61.6 34 97.1 77 55,0 8 100.0

Widowed 1 1.0 -- , — ---- \0 Subtotal 99 100,0 35 100,0 140 100.0 8 100.0

Employees under 18 years 17 6 2 • 1

Total 116 41 142 9 93

4. Educational attainment The level of education attained by the plant employees who were interviewed was quite different in the two areas, as shown in Table 6. Over 63 percent of the Scarriff em­ ployees received no education beyond the primary level, as compared with 35 percent in Tubbercurry. Of those receiv­ ing post-primary education, the vast majority had attended vocational schools. Some had attended secondary schools, while a few employees had attended vocational schools after one or more years of secondary school attendance. In all, about 50 percent of the Tubbercurry employees had some voca­ tional school education, while less than 30 percent of the Scarriff employees had attended vocational schools. Differ­ ences in education attainment hy sex were slight, 'For, example 5I percent of the male employees in Tubbercurry had attended vocational school, while 46 percent of the female employees had done so. Examination of the number of years of post-primary education obtained by plant employees reveals that the most frequently occurring quantity of post-primary education among those obtaining such education was three years for the Tubber­ curry employees and 2 years for the Scarriff employees. The basic course of study in the vocational schools is one of two years duration, at-the end of which period of study a state examination for the Group Certificate is administered to pupils. 94

Table 6, Educational attainment of plant employees

TuTabercurry Scarriff 'Level of Education Number Percent Number Percent

Primary only 55 35.0 96 63.5 Primary + secondary 23 14.6 11 7.3 Primary + vocational 66 42.2 35 23.2 • Primary + secondary + vocational 12 7.6 6 4.0 Primary + secondary + university 2 1.3 Primary + secondary + other 1 0.6 —— Primary + vocational + other 1 0.7 Total 157 100.0 151 100.0

It is then possible for pupils who wish to study further for a trade to spend an additional year of study at a vocational school. This third year is largely a *practical year* and . is frequently combined with an apprenticeship program for the trade in which the pupils are interested. It would appear, from the data contained in Table 7t that most of the plant employees in the Scarriff area who had attended vocational school had done so for the basic two-year course. In the . Tubbercurry.area, on the other hand, the majority of those attending vocational school had done so for three years. 95

Table 7. Distribution of plant employees by number of years post-primary education

Years Post Tubbercurry Scarriff Primary Education Number Percent Number Percent

0 55 35.0 96 63.5 1 13 "•8.3 6 4.0 2 20 12.7 18 11.9 3 34 21.7 16 10.6 16 10.2 . 3 2.0 5 13 8.3 7 4.6 6 2 1.3 • 1 0.7 7 2 1.3 3 2.0 8 1 - 0.6 • • 1 0.7 9 1 0.6 Total 157 100.0 151 100.0 Mean number of years post-primary education 2.08 1.14

This difference would be associated with higher levels of skill requirement for certain posfîlBhs'"^in the Tubbercurry plants and with the apprenticeship program which was developed to partly satisfy these requirements, thus providing a greater opportunity to residents of the Tubbercurry area for the acquisition and subsequent use of such skills. 96

As shown in Table 7, 44 percent of the Tubbercurry employees received three or more years of post-primary education, while about 20 percent of the Scarriff employees received this amount of education. The mean number of years post-primary education received by plant employees was 2.08 in Tubbercurry and I.l4 in Scarriff. These educational dif­ ferences are largely due to the hiring policies of the new firms, arising from the requirements of the particular jobs offered. In Tubbercurry, there was a greater demand for skilled employees, who would have higher levels of training. Similarly, a large number of apprentices was recruited. These also would have vocational school training.

Farm association—residence Plant employees are classified in Table 8 according to whether they resided in farm, nonfarm rural or urban house­ holds. All employees residing in "Census Towns" (defined as clusters of 20 or more occupied houses) are classed as urban residents. The number of plant employees residing on farms was much larger in Tubbercurry, amounting to 60 percent as opposed to 40 percent in Scarriff. About one third of the Tubbercurry employees were urban residents, while nearly half of the Scarriff employees resided in towns. In both areas a small portion of plant employees were rural nonfarm residents. 97

Table 8. Distribution of plant employees by type of residence

Tubbercurry Scarriff Type of Residence Number Percent Number Percent

Farm 9^ 59.9 6o 39.8 Nonfarm Rural 11 7.0 20 13.2 Urban 52 33.1 71 47.0 Total 157. 100.0 151 100.0

6, Farm associations-work All employees were classified by their farm work associa­ tion. A farm operator,was defined as a person who did some farm work (apart from maintenance) on fifty or more days during the preceding year, who was paid from farm profits (3..e. did not receive a fixed wage) and who made the management decisions regarding what crops were grown and what livestock were kept on that farm. All other farm workers were classed as nonopera­ tor farm workers. These latter failed to meet one or more of the above criteria, but worked on a farm. In classifying people as nonoperator farm workers a lower limit of twenty.days on which some farm work was done was applied. This procedure was followed in order to exclude from the nonoperator farm worker category those people who might help at faim work during periods of peak labor demands and those who might just do some farm work during vacations from other employment. 98

The distribution of plant employees by farm work associa­ tion is shown in Table 9, which contains data regarding, the' farm work association of plant employees both immediately prior to their obtaining employment at the new industrial plants and when interviewed in connection with the present study. Because of the criteria used, it transpired that the number of farm operators actually employed at both plants was lower than expected on the basis of preliminary enquiries, Many of those originally thought to be farm operators were, in fact nonoperator farm workers. Failure to satisfy the third criterion, that of responsibility for management decisions on the farm, was the most frequent cause for reclassification of those who had been felt to be farm operators on the basis of preliminary information. • In Tubbercurry, 15 plant employees were farm operators at the time of obtaining industrial employment and were still farm operators when the present study was conducted, as com­ pared with 17 such farm operators in Scarriff, One farm operator in Scarriff had ceased to be a farm operator at some stage subsequent to emplosnnent at the new plant and was a nonoperator farm worker at the time of interview. In Scarriff, also, one person, who at the time of employment had no farm work association, subsequently became a farm operator, while, in both areas, one person who was originally a nonoperator farm worker became a farm operator subsequent to obtaining Table 9. Distribution of plant employees by farm work association

Tubbercurrv Scarriff

Farm work association Number Percent Number Percent (n = 157) (n = 151)

Farm operator at time of taking plant employment and is farm operator now 15 9.6 17 11.3

Farm operator at time of taking plant employment and is nonoperator farm worker now MM mmmmm 1 0.7

Nonoperator farm worker at time of taking plant employment and is farm eperator now 1 0.6 1 0.7

Nonoperator farm worker at time of taking plant employment and is nonoperator farm worker now 46 29.3 31 20.5

Nonoperator farm worker at time of taking plant employment and has no farm work association now 18 11.5 12 7.9 No farm work association on taking plant employment and is farm operator now - — — — — — 1 0.7 No farm work association on taking plant employment and is nonop. farm worker now 4 2.5 1 0.7 No farm work association on taking plant employment and has no farm work association now 73 46.5 87 57.6 100

employment at the new plant. Sixty five of the Tubtercurry employees (41.4 percent) were nonoperator farm workers when hired at the new plant. Eighteen of these (28 percent) subsequently ceased to have any farm work association. In Scarriff, 44 plant employees (29.1 percent) were originally nonoperator farm workers, 12 of whom (2? percent) later ceased to have any farm work association. This was the most frequently occurring movement among types of farm work association following employment at the new industrial plants. A few people who had no farm work association when hired at the new plants subsequently became nonoperator farm workers. In all, when the present study was conducted, l6 employ­ ees (10.2 percent) in Tubbercurry and 19 employees (12.6 per­ cent) in Scarriff were farm operators. Fifty employees (31.8 percent) in Tubbercurry and 33 employees (21.8 percent) in Scarriff were nonoperator farm workers, while, in both areas, the majority of plant employees, 9I or 58.0 percent in Tubbercurry and 99 or 65.6 percent in Scarriff had no farm work association when this study was conducted,

B. Household Characteristics

In the present section, certain attributes of the house­ holds of plant employees are described, along with the plant employees* status within their households. 101

Status Tflthin household As seen from Table 10, slightly over half of the Scarriff employees were heads of households, while in Tubbercurry about 30 percent of the plant employees were heads of households. This difference is largely due to the fact that, as noted earlier, married males formed a much larger proportion of the plant employees in Scarriff than in Tubbercurry.

Table 10. Status of plant employees within their households

Tubbercurry Scarriff Household status Number Percent Number Percent

Head of household 47 29.9 77 51.0 Other household member 110 70.1 74 49.0 Total 157 100.0 151 100.0

The relationship of the other plant employees to the heads of the households wherein they resided is shown in Table 11, The most frequently occurring relationship to the head of the household was that of son, son-in-law or stepson, accounting for over 60 percent of the other household members employed in Tubbercurry and for over 80 percent of those in Scarriff, In all, the two relationship groups, son, son-in- law or stepson and daughter, daughter-in-law or stepdaughter accounted for nearly 95 percent of the other household members 102

Table 11. Relationships of plant employees to heads of house­ holds in which they resided

Tubbercurry Scarriff Relationship to head Number Percent Number Percent

Wife 1 0,9 Son, son-in-law, stepson 67 61,0 61 82.4 Daughter, dau^ter-in law, step-daughter 38 34,5 6 8,1 Brother, brother-in- law, stepbrother . 1 0.9 3 4,1 Other relation 3 2.7 4 . . 5.4 Subtotal ' 110 100.0 74 • 100,0 Heads of households 47 77 Total 157 151

employed in Tubbercurry and for over 90 percent of those in Scarriff,

Thus, in Tubbercurry, about JO percent of plant employees were heads of households, the remainder being nearly. all sons or daughters of heads of households, while in Scarriff, about half of the plant employees were heads of households, most of the other half also being sons or daughters,

2, Multi-employee households Some households in both areas contained more than one 103

plant employee. The term multi-employee household is used to refer to such households. In some of these households,• the head was employed at the plant along with one or more other members, while in other cases the head was not em­ ployed at the plant but two or- more other members were. It was possible from the lists of employees to ascertain in respect of all employees whether or not they belonged to multi-employee households. Hence, data are presented in respect of all employees and in respect of those interviewed regarding the occurrence of multi - employee households. In Tubbercurry, as shown in Table 12, ^0 employees or 22 percent came from households with two members employed at the plant. Hence, the total number of households contain­ ing plant employees was 163. In Scarriff, 26 employees came from two-employee households. There also was one three-employee household and one four-employee household. Hence, the number of households containing Scarriff plant employees was 176. Similar information is presented in Table 13 regarding the employees who were interviewed in both areas. Thirty- six or 23 percent of the 157 employees interviewed in Tubber­ curry were members of multi-employee households, while in Scarriff, 25 employees or l6.5 percent of those interviewed were members of multi-employee households. Table 12. Distribution of all plant employees and of households containing these employees by number of employees per household

Tubbercurry Scarriff

Employees Households Employees Households Employees per household Number cent Number cent Number cent Number cent

One 143 78.1 143 87.7 161 83.0 161 91.4

Two 40 21.9 20 12.3 26 13.4 13 7.4

Three 3 1.5 1 0,6

Four 4 2.1 1 0.6

Total 183 100.0 163 100,0 194 .100.0 176 100.0 Table 13. Distribution of plant employees interviewed and their households by number of employees per household

Tubbercurry Scarriff

Employees HousehoIds Emolovees Households PciT" Employees per household Number cent Number cent Number cent Number cent

One . 121 77.1 121 85.8 126 83.5 126 89.4

Two 36 22.9 20 14.2 ; 19 12.6 13 9.2

Three -- — ---- 2 1.3 1 0.7

Four — ---- 4 • 2.6 1 0.7

Total 157 100.0 141 100.0 151 100.0. 141 100.0 106

3, Nimber of people In household Table 14 shows the distribution by household size of the plant employees • who x-rere interviewed. There is hardly any difference between the two groups of employees in this respect. For example, 36 percent of the Tubbercurry employees and 35 percent of the Scarriff employees were members of households containing 3 or fewer members. The proportion of plant em­ ployees residing in households containing 5, or 6 members was somewhat higher in Scarriff, while the proportion of em­ ployees, who were members of households containing 7 or more members was slightly higher in Tubbercurry than in Scarriff, The distribution by household size of the households which contain one or more plant employees is shown in Table 15. In both areas the median size of households which contained plant employees was 4 persons. In Tubbercurry, 38 percent of the households containing plant employees had three or fewer members, the corresponding fraction for Scarriff being 36 per­ cent. About 45 percent of the Tubbercurry households had 4, 5, or 6 members while 49 percent of the Scarriff households fell in this size-range. Households containing 7 or more members amounted to slightly more than 17 percent of the Tubber­ curry group and about 14 percent of the Scarriff group of households which contained plant members. 107

Table 14. Distribution of plant employees by number of people in the households of which they were members

Tubbercurry Scarriff Size of household (people) Number Percent Number Percent

1 9 5.7 11 7.3 2 18 • 11.5 16 10.6 3 30 19.1 26 17.2 4 33 21.0 26 17.2 5. 25 15.9 26 17.2 6 11 7.0 24 15.9 7 14 8.9 • 11 7.3 8 5 3.2 1 0.7

—< - 9 8 5.1 7 4.6 10 2 1.3 2 1.3 11 2 1.3 . 1 0.7 Total 157 100.0 151 100.0

if:» Family-classification " of households Plant employees were groups according to the family classic fif>.5.+-.^on of their households. This grouping is shown in Table ' J ' * * .16. .In Tubbercurry, 113 employees or 72. percent ©f the total interviewed were members of husband-wife family hoi^seholds where both spouses were present. A further 18.5 percent were members of broken-family households, where the head of the ' 108

Table 15. Distribution of households containing one or more plant employees by size of household

Tubbercurry Scarriff Size of household (people) Number Percent Number Percent

1 9 6,4 11 . 7.8 2 17 12.1 16 • 11.4 3 27 19.2 25 17.7 4 31 22.0 26 18.4 5 21 14.9 23 16.3 6 11 7.8 20 14.2 7 13 9.2 10 7.1 8 4 2.8 1 0.7 9 5 3.5 6 4.3 10 2 1.4 2 1.4 11 1 0.7 1 0.7 Total l4l 100.0 l4l 100.0

Table l6. Distribution of plant employees by family-classi­ fication of their households

Tubbercurry Scarriff Family Classification Numoer i'ercent Number Percent

Husband-wife family household—both spouses present 113 71.9 112 74.2 Broken-family house­ hold—one spouse pre­ sent, mother and child (ren) or father and child(ren) 29 18.5 16 10.6 Nonconjugal family house­ hold—brothers, brothers and sisters, etc. 5 3.2 9 5.9 Single Person household 10 6.4 l4 9.3 Total 157 100.0 151 100.0 109

of the household was either widowed or separated (legally or informally) from his/her spouse. Five plant employees were members of nonconjugal family households, • for example, brothers and sisters or aunts, uncles, nephews and nieces living in one household. A further 10 people were members of single person households. In Scarriff, a somewhat higher proportion of employees belonged to husband-wife family households. Considerably less Scarriff employees were members of broken-family households. The number of employees who resided in nonconjugal family households and in single person households was, however, larger in Scarriff than in Tubbercurry. To facilitate comparisons on a household basis. Table 1? shows the distribution by family classification of households in both areas which contain one or more plant employees. Exactly the same proportion of households containing plant employees (72.4 percent) were husband-wife family households in each area. • On a household basis, single-persons households as a proportion of households containing plant employees, numbered 6.4^ percent in Tubbercurry and 9.9 percent in Scarriff. Thus, about three quarters of the households containing plant employees in both areas were husband-wife family households, the remaining households having other family combinations or else being single person households. 110

Table 1?. Distribution by family-classification of households containing one ormmore plant employees

Tubbercurry Scarriff Family classification Number Percent Number Percent

Husband-wife family household—both spouses present 102 • 72.4 102 72.4 Broken-family household —one spouse present, mother and child(ren), or father and child(ren) 24 17.0 16 11.3 Nonconjugal family house­ hold—brothers, brothers and sisters, etc. 5 3.5 9 6.4 Single person households 10 7.1 14 9.9 Total 141 100.0 151 100.0

C. Employment Characteristics

This section contains a description of the plant employees jobs, how these jobs were obtained and- the length of time plant employees held their present jobs prior to the study being . conducted.

1, Present occupation The plant employees who were interviewed are classified by present occupation in Table 18. Some occupations are ex­ clusive to each plant. However there is a certain overlap in Table 18. Distribution of plant employees by present occupation

Tubbercurrv Scarriff Present occupation Number Percent Number Percent

Fitter, assembler or mechanic 3 1.9 5 3.3 Diecaster 5 3.2 — — Other skilled metal worker 7 4.5 2 1.3 Metal working machinist 3 1.9 -- Apprentice 22 14.0 3 2.0 Warehouser or packer 10 6.4 5 3.3 Other commercial worker 1 0.6 1 0.7 Other service worker 1 0.6 3 2.0 Other professional or technical worker 4 2.6 2 1.3 Foreman or supervisor 9 5.7 8 5.3 Clerk or typist 16 10.2 12 7.8 General laborer or other unskilled worker 54 . 34.4 68, 45.1 Carpenter or joiner 3 .2.0 Sawyer or other woodworking machinist ------13 8.6 Building tradesman -- -- 4 2.6 Veneerer or finisher ------6 4.0 Saw doctor 1 0.7 Skilled electrical worker ------3 2.0 Operator of moving machinery ---- 4 2.6 Operator of crane, stationary engine, etc. ---- 3 2.0 Truck driver ------4 2.6 Other transport and communications worker 1 0.7

Total 157 100.0 151 100.0 112 the occupational breakdown of plant employees in both areas particularly since a relatively large proportion of the plant employees fell in the unskilled labor category. Over 34 per­ cent of.the employees interviewed in Tubbercurry were classed as general laborer or other unskilled worker, while 68 or ^5 percent of those.interviewed in Scarriff were so classed. Twenty two or 14 percent of those interviewed in Tubber­ curry were apprentices, as compared with 3 employees or 2 per­ cent in Scarriff, As can be inferred from this, a rather large apprenticeship program has been introduced in Tubbercurry in an effort to increase the supply of skilled labor to the plant. Clerical personnel amounted to about 10 percent of those interviewed in Tubbercurry and about 8 percent in Scarriff.

2. Manner of recruitment The manner in which plant employees obtained their present employment is shown in Table 19. By far the majority of plant employees in both areas obtained their employment by just applying at the plant office. Nearly 70 percent of the Tubber­ curry employees and over 65 percent of the Scarriff employees obtained their present positions in this manner. The next most frequent response in both areas was that the employee heard of the availability of this job from a friend or relative. In many of these cases, a relative of the present employee had been working at the plant and had obtained employment for Table 19. Distribution of plant employees by manner of recruitment to present employment

Tubbercurrv Scarriff

Manner of recruitment Number Percent Number Percent

Newspaper advertisment 11 7.0 9 6.9

Just applied at the plant office 108 68.8 99 65.5

Heard of job from friend or relative 20 12.7 25 16.6

Through private employment agency 3 1.9 1 0.7

Contacted by employer 15 9.6 17 11.2

Total 157 100.0 151 100.0 114 for other members of his household or other relatives. Occasionally, when one employee left the plant*s employ, a close relative of his might come to work at the plant to "replace him". The third most frequent manner of recruitment in both areas involved the employer seeking out and contacting the potential employee. In Tubbercurry, 15 or nearly 10 percent of the plant employees were recruited in this manner, while, in Scarriff, 1? or 11 percent of the employees were so re­ cruited. Seven percent of the Tubbercurry employees and 6 percent of the Scarriff employees were recruited by newspaper advertisement, while, in both areas, recruitment through a.n employment agency or placing service was negligible.

Length of time in present position • Plant employees were classified according to the length • of time during which they had worked at the new plants. This classification is shown in Table 20, Because of its longer period of operation, the Tubbercurry plant had some employees who had worked there for over 8 years. Both plants had a fairly similar distribution of employees among the other cate­ gories of length of employee service. In Scarriff, 28 employees had worked at the plant for less than one year prior to the survey, the same number as in Tubbercurry, In Tubber­ curry, 85 employees or 54,2 percent had been employed for less than 3 years, as compared with 82 or 5^.3 percent in Scarriff. 115

Table 20. Distribution of plant employees by length of time in present position

Tubbercurry Scarriff Number of Months Number Percent Number Percent

Under 3 3 1.9 7 4.6 3 and under 6 4 2.5 9.9 6 and under 9 7 4.5 2 1.3 9 and under 12 14 8.9 4 2.6 12 and under 18 8 5.1 4 2.6 18 and under Zk 11 7.0 11 7.3 24 and under 30 16 10.2 12 7.9 30 and under 36 9 . 5.7 14 9.3 36 and under 48 16 . 10.2 21 ' 14.0 48 and under 60 20 12.7 17 11.3 60 and under 72 19 12.1 19 12.6 72 and under 84 7 4.5 11 .7.3 84 and under 96 5 3.2 13 . 8.6 96 and over 18 11.5 1 0.7

Total 157 100.0 151 100.0 Mean number of months 45.9 41.0

Largely because of increased length of plant operation in Tubbercurry, the mean number of months of employment was 45.9 in Tubbercurry and 4l.O in Scarriff. The major contrast between the two areas arose when the duration-of ..employment 116 was classified "by farm work association. Plant employees who were farm operators before accepting employment at the new plant and who remained farm operators following such employ­ ment had a mean duration of employment of 80.5 months in Tubber- curry and 36.6 months in Scarriff, This indicates that the farm operators were nearly all hired in the early stages of plant operation in Tubbercurry but that in Scarriff their hiring was more scattered throughout the period of operation of the plant.

D. Farm Operator Plant Employees

In this section, certain personal and farm business characteristics of those farm operators who obtained employ­ ment at the new plants and who did not subsequently change their farm work association are examined.

. Personal characteristics In both areas all of the farm operators who were employed at the new plants were males. Fourteen of the 15 farm opera­ tors employed in Tubbercurry were heads of households. The other farm operator was the son of the head of the household. in which he resided. Fourteen of the 1? farm operators employed at the Scarriff plant were heads of households. Two of the remaining 3 were sons of the heads of the households in which they resided, while the third was a nephew of the 117 head of his household. All but one of the 15 farm operators employed in Tubber- curry were members of one-employee households. Similarly, all but one of the 17 farm operators employed at the Soarriff plant were members of one-employee households. Eleven of the 15 farm operators employed in Tubbercurry were married, while 11 of the 17 farm operators employed at the Soarriff plant were married. . The mean age of the farm operators employed in Tubber­ curry was 4l years. The mean age of farm operators employed, at the Soarriff plant was 36.9 years. Seven of the 15 farm operators employed in Tubbercurry had received some education beyond the primary school level. Most of these people had attended vocational school. The mean number of years of post-primary education obtained by the farm operator plant employees in Tubbercurry was 1.4? years. In contrast, only 3 of the 17 farm operators employed at the Scarriff plant had received any post-primary educa­ tion. The mean number of years of post-primary education received by the Scarriff farm operator plant employees was 0.3 years.

2. Farm business characteristics Farm business characteristics of those farm operators who accepted plant emplosrment and who did not subsequently 118 change their farm work association are described hereunder. This description focuses on land utilization, livestock enterprises, labor use, machinery use and farm income. a. Land utilization Land utilization of farm opera­ tor plant employees in both areas is shorni in Table 21, Those farm operators employed in Tubbercurry operated a mean acreage of 30.067, while their Scarriff counterparts operated a mean of 34.117 acres. Total grain crops had a mean acreage of 1.827 for the Tubbercurry group and 0.627 for the Scarriff group. In each case, oats was predominant among the grain crops. Similarly, potatoes were pre-eminent among the root and green crops, of which the Tubbercurry operators had 0.620 acres and the Scarriff operators had 1.435 acres. Say occu­ pied about 6 acres on the Tubbercurry farms and about 9 acres on the Scarriff farms. However, in both cases, the bulk of the farm land was devoted to pasture, the amount being 21.767 acres for the Tubbercurry operators and 20-, 524 acres for the Scarriff operators. b. Livestock As might be expected from th,e high proportion of farm land devoted to pasture, cattle occupied a prominent place among the farm livestock enterprises. As shoifjn in Table 22, farm operator plant employees in Tubber­ curry had a mean of 17.5 cattle, compared with 19.5 by the Scarriff farm operator plant employees. Approximately one fourth of the cattle were milch cows in each case. 119

Farm operator plant employees in Scarriff had a mean of about 5 sheep, considerably more than had the Tubbercurry group. Similarly, the Scarriff group had more pigs than had their Tubbercurry counterparts. There were but slight differences in numbers of poultry kept. 0. Labor use Table 23 shows particulars regarding • labor use on these farms. Farms operated by the farm opera­ tor plant employees in Tubbercurry had slightly more family • members who did some work on those farms than had the cor­ responding farms in Scarriff. Operator time devoted to farm work was somewhat over 900 man-hours in' each case. However, the number of man-hours of total family labor used in farming was about 400 higher on the Tubbercurry farms. This is con­ sistent with the presence of more other family members to work on these farms. Farm operator plant employees employed more hired labor in Tubbercurry (33 days) than in Scarriff (l6.5 days). Thus, the total number of man-hours of family plus hired labor used on the Scarriff farms. d. Machinery The mean estimated selling value of farm machinery and equipment on farms operated by farm opera­ tor plant employees was «^57.3 Tubbercurry and 43.2 in Scarriff. Î4any of these operators reported that whatever machinery and equipment they had was now obsolete and had no current selling value. 120

je. Farm Income Data pertaining to the current farm income of plant employee farm operators are shown in Table 2^, Farm operator plant employees in. Scarriff reported mean sales of farm products amounting to «65^1» «6183 more than reported by the Tubbercurry plant employee farm operators. The value of farm products consumed in their farm households was roughly similar for both groups of farm, operators. Hence, the gross farm output of these farms was £621 in Scarriff and in. Tubbercurry. However, farm operator plant employees had higher non- labor farm expenses in Scarriff than in Tubbercurry, so the labor income on those Scarriff farms was ^311, compared with ;f231 on the Tubbercurry farms, a difference of ^80. The Tubbercurry plant employee farm operators had used somewhat more hired labor, so their labor expenses were correspondingly higher than those of their Scarriff counterparts. Hence, family farm income was iif295 on farms operated by plant employee farm operators in Scarriff, compared with ^190 on the corresponding Tubbercurry farms, a difference of slightly over100. 121

Table 21. I966 Land utilization pattern of farm operator plant employees

Characteristic (mean) Tubbercurry Scarriff (n = 15) (n = 17)

Total acres operated 30.067 34.117 Wheat .059 Oats .741 .573 Barley .029 .053 Total grain crops .829 .627 Potatoes .433 .924 Other root and green crops .187 .511 Total root and green crops .620 1.435 Hay 6.140 9.059 Pasture 21.767 20.524 Woods and plantations .013 .029 Other land .900 2.241

Table 22, I966 livestock enterprises of farm operator plant employees

Characteristic (mean) Tubbercurry Scarriff (n - 15) (n = 17) Cows 4.2 4.7 Heifers-in-calf 1.7 1.3 Other cattle{ 11.6 13.5 Total cattle 17.5 19.5 Ewes 0.8 2.2 Other sheep 0.7 2.9 Total sheep 1.5 . 5.1 Sows 0.0 0.4 Other pigs 1.3 2.8 Total pigs 1.3 3.2 Turkeys, geese and ducks 2.7 6.4 Ordinary fowl 21.3 15.9 Total poultry 24.0 22.3 122

Table 23. Labor utilization on farms of farm operator plant employees

Characteristic (mean) Tubbercurry Scarriff (n = 15) (n = 17)

Number of family members doing some farm work 2.4 2.2

Man hours operator labor ' per annum 930.0 922.6 Total man hours family labor per annum 2,288.7 . • 1,853.5 Number of days hired labor 33.1 16.5 Total man hours family plus hired labor per annum 2,553.7 1,985.7

Table 24. I966 Farm income data (jS) pn

Characteristic (mean) Tubbercurry Scarriff (n = 15) (n = 17)

Total sales of farm products . 358.3 541.1 Household consumption 86.0 80.1 Gross output 444.3 621.2 Non-labor expenses 213.5 310.4. V. Farm labor income 230.8 310.4 Hired labor expenses 41.0 15.8

Family farm income 189.8 294.9 123

VI. HYPOTHETICAL INDUSTRIALIZATION EFFECTS

The location of a new industrial plant in a predominantly rural community can be expected to have many social and econo-, mic effects. Some of these effects may be felt by households in the area. Other effects may be felt by business firms in the community—both farm business and non-farm business firms. The present study focused primarily on the economic impact of local industrialization on households and on farm businesses in two areas of Western Ireland. To a lesser extent, some of the effects on non-farm businesses were examined. The economic effects of a newly established industrial plant on households and business firms in an area depend on the product demand and factor demand characteristics of the new plant. In the two areas studied, it was expected that these effects would arise mainly from the factor demand characteris­ tics of the new plants. This expectation arose from the fact that the markets for chipboard, looks and tooling products were practically entirely outside the two areas involved. Hence, sales of these products within the two areas would have little if any effect on production. In addition, cost reduc­ tions to local business firms selling these products in the two areas (arising from lower transportation charges or direct purchase from the factory) would be small, because sales 124 of those products within the areas would be relatively insig­ nificant. Furthermore, hardly any close complementarity or substitution relationships in production existed between these products and the products of other local firms. The types of factors (inputs) demanded by a new indus­ trial firm depend on the type of product manufactured while the quantities which are demanded are closely related to the level of demand for the product manufactured. The new firms needed building facilities, machinery, assembly line equip­ ment, office equipment and supplies, electricity, water and other utilities, transportation services and labor. In addition, the Tubbercurry firms required metal and metal pro­ ducts, while the Scarriff plant required timber, glue-and some other factors. Demand for buildings, machines, office and assembly line equipment would be determined mainly by plant size and would be concentrated in the initial stages of the firms* operations. The demand for other inputs would be closely related to the level of production over time.

A. Direct and Indirect Effects

The effects of industrialization.may be direct or indirect. Direct effects of industrialization are defined as those changes in household and business characteristics which are associated with the employment of particular factors of pro­ duction at a newly established plant. The magnitude of these 125. direct effects of the factor demand of a new firm on the local community depends on the ability of the community to supply these inputs to the new firm at prices competitive with sources of supply outside the community. Since there were no other manufacturing firms in the two areas defined, the bulk of the non-labor inputs required by the new firms in these areas were likely to be obtained from wholesale firms outside these areas or by direct pur­ chase from manufacturers located in other areas. Since the two areas were characterized by net emigration of population, the new firms would be expected to obtain a large proportion of the labor needed from within the two areas. Hence, the major direct effects of industrialization to be expected in these two areas would be those direct effects associated with the employment of labor in the new plants. These direct effects would be those changes in household and business characteristics associated with the employment of a household member at one of the new plants. The direct effects of industrialization on local farm businesses are of . special interest in the present study. An example of a direct effect on a farm business would be any reorganization of farm­ ing activity as a result of a farm operator having less time to spend at farm work following acceptance of factory employ­ ment. Indirect effects of industrialization can also occur. Indirect effects of industrialization may be defined as those 126 changes which industrialization induces in the external environment in which households arid businesses function. These effects may alter the demand situation facing house­ holds and firms for the goods and services which they have to offer. On the other hand, these effects may also alter the supply situation- of goods and services which households and business wish to acquire. Examples of the first type of indirect'effect would be­ any additional increased employment (affecting demand for labor sources from households) and income (affecting demand for products supplied by business firms) generated in the community via a multiplier following the direct effects. The second type of indirect effect may be illustrated by any reorganization of resources on farms using hired labor in the community arising from a rise in the level of farm wages caused by local industrial development,

B. Selectivity Aspects of Industrialization Effects

Productive factors hired or used by a new manufacturing plant are not likely to possess the same characteristics as those factors which are not hired or used by the new plant. To the extent that such differences occur, there is, there­ fore, a selectivity aspect involved in the incidence of the . direct effects of industrialization on a community. Such selectivity can arise from the hiring policies of the new 127 industrial firm or may arise from certain characteristics of some factors which result in those particular factors not being offered to the new firm, for employment. More specifically, one may expect that people who are employed at a newly established plant will differ in some respects from other people within the area who are not so employed. The nature of the selectivity involved depends largely on (a) the factors motivating people to offer their labor services to the new firm and (b) the nature of the newly created demands for labor services. The importance of selec­ tivity considerations may arise as follows. It may be that an offer of labor services to the new plant would be prompted by a desire,to improve personal or family position through increased income, higher occupational status or better work­ ing conditions. If these selectivity aspects are such that people who obtain emplozment at a new plant initially have lower incomes than those who do not obtain such employment, then the direct effects of industrialization would, because of these selectivity factors, tend to reduce income inequal- ' ity in the area of impact. In particular, it is expected that newly created nonfarm jobs would attract some farm people into urban employment. Some of these might be farm operators, the remainder being other members of farm families. It is to be expected that farm people who take nonfarm jobs are not likely to be repre­ sentative of all farm people in the area. On a priori 128-129

grounds, it is possible to postulate certain farm and family circumstances which would favor the obtaining of nonfarm employment by members of farm families. One of the characteristics contributing to selectivity may be family farm income. If family farm income is relative­ ly low on certain farms, and if there appear to be few opportunities available for increasing farm income, then operators and other family members from these farms may seek nonfarm employment as a means of supplementing farm income. When the desire for greater family income is the major motivation component, it follows that farm people who offer their labor services to a newly established plant anti­ cipate a net increase in their incomes. This implies that the marginal return to their labor is smaller in their farm businesses than in nonfarm work. The larger this differen­ tial, other things being equal, the greater will be the près- . sure to find nonfarm jobs. Thus, people who are experiencing a low marginal return to their labor are expected to offer their labor services for industrial employment more frequently than those who are experiencing a high marginal return. Under given conditions regarding prices of farm products and costs of farm inputs, the marginal return to the labor of farm operators and other members of farm families is closely associated with the effective quantities of land and capital which are combined with this labor. Within certain limits. 130

the more land and capital that are combined with labor, the greater the marginal return to labor may be expected to be. Hence, offers of labor services for nonfarm employment may be expected to come most often from families on farms which have the smaller effective inputs of land and capital. The fre­ quency of such offers may be expected to decrease as the effective inputs of land and capital increase. If farm price conditions are favorable, people working on well-organized farms (in terms of the usual economic effi­ ciency criteria) will earn returns to their labor which com­ pare favorably to the wages offered in nonfarm employment. However, if farm prices are unfavorable, labor returns, even on well-organized farms, will lie below those available in nonfarm employment. Under such circumstances, some operators and other family members from farms with relatively large inputs of land and capital may offer their labor services for nonfarm employment. However, the frequency of such offers is likely to be much lower than among families on farms with smaller inputs of land and capital. Hence, the generation of new nonfarm employment opportunities in an area is likely to attract a larger proportion of farm people with low incomes and small amounts of land and capital than of those-j/fith high incomes and large amounts of land and capital. In general, the labor demands of a newly established plant are likely to be specific in many cases. For some jobs, the new firm will desire to hire workers having certain 131 characteristics, which some people will be better able to meet than others. If the firm is able to find people having the desired characteristics, those not possessing such characteristics will not be hired, even if they offer their services for employment. Hence, the hiring policies of the new firm partly determine the type of selectivity which characterizes industrialization. Selectivity may be associated with age. Hiring policy of the new plant may favor the recruitment of younger workers, while older people may also be more vocationally immobile. The new firm may favor male employees over female employees. The firm may prefer to hire workers with previous nonfarm work experience as opposed to those without such experience. Similarly, people with such prior nonfarm work experience may more readily offer their labor services to the new firm. Subjective feelings regarding the desirability of certain characteristics of alternative employment opportunities may also influence the degree to which farm people offer their, services to the new plant. To the extent that there are selectivity aspects involved, both arising from the hiring policies of the new firms and from other family or personal characteristics, the people who obtain emplosrment at the new plant are likely to differ with respect to some attributes from those who do not obtain such employment. 132

C, Employment and Wage Effects

The demand for labor by the new industrial plants would theoretically shift the aggregate demand schedule for labor in both areas to the right as depicted in Figure 5. It should be understood that this increase in demand for labor services would be relative to the demand for labor services which would have existed in those areas in the absence of the new manu­ facturing plants, not relative to the demand for labor services which existed in those areas at the time when the new indus- trail plants commenced operations. For a given increase in demand for labor services, the effects on employment and wage rates in an area depend on the aggregate supply schedule for labor services in the area. The shape of this schedule "was not known in either area. It was theoretically possible that this schedule was perfectly in­ elastic in both areas as shown by the line QQ in Figure 5, With such a supply schedule, an increase in the demand for labor sources from DD to DiDi would result in an increase in the wage rate from Wq to WI, with the level of employment remaining unchanged. It was decided to reject this possibility for both areas, since both areas had been characterized by declining employmait and by net emigration during the period prior to the establishment of the new industrial plants. It was also decided that a supply schedule for labor sources which sloped upwards-to the left was unrealistic for both areas. Q Qj Number of workers Figure 5, -Effect of increased demand for labor services on employment and wage rates 134

since the areas had relatively low levels of income -per capita. It was felt, on the other hand, that it was reasonable to expect that the supply schedule for labor services in areas which had been experiencing declines in employment and net emigration would be quite elastic over a limited range of employment, as depicted by the horizontal segment

WqH of the kinked line IHqS in Figure 5. It was expected that unemployed and underemployed people were present in both areas. Some, at least, of these people would be expected to accept employment, if available to them, at the wage rate existing in those areas prior to the introduction of the new industrial plants. Others of them, also considered under- employed as conventionally defined, may have value systems in terms of work-leisure preference such that, at the pre­ vailing wage rate, they would not offer additonal labor . services for emplosrment. However, in any particular area, a perfectly elastic supply schedule for labor services can exist only over a limited range of employment. At some level of employment, the supply schedule for labor services will turn upwards to the right, as a higher wage rate would be required to attract additional residents of the areas into the labor force or to induce workers from outside the areas to accept employ­ ment at the new plants. In Figure 5, such a situation is depicted by the upward sloping segment HS of the line WqS which is the supply curve for labor services intersecting with D^Di the new demand curve for labor services, giving an emplosrment level of at a wage rate of Wg* compared with the initial employment level of Q at a wage rate of WQ. The aggregate labor market in an area is more likely to consist of a number of separate markets for different types of labor services than to be a single labor market. It will suffice for purposes of the present discussion to view the labor markets in the two areas of'interest as consisting of a market for unskilled labor services and a market for skilled labor services. Training of workers and the introduction of an apprenticeship program at one of the Tubbercurry plants indicated that the supply schedule for certain types of labor services demanded at that plant was less than perfectly elas­ tic in the area. Training of workers at the plant would shift the supply schedule for skilled labor services to the right as shown in Figure 6A-, which represents a market for skilled labor services. Depending on the amount of increase in the supply schedule relative to the increase in the demand schedule, the wage rate for skilled labor would increase, decrease, or remain unchanged as depicted in Figure 6A, it was expected that the wage rate for skilled labor in the Tubbercurry area would not decline, since skilled labor would be likely to migrate from the area if the skilled wage rate declined. However, 136

6A. Skilled labor market

CD S O

Qq Qj Number of workers

SB. Unskilled labor market %

0 Q| Qz Number of workers Figure 6, Effect of increased demand for labor services on labor and wage rates in skilled and unskilled labor markets 137 the increase in the supply schedule may have been sufficient to keep the skilled tmge rate unchanged in the area. The demand schedule for unskilled labor services would shift to the right, as depicted in Figure 6B, either as a result of the increased demand for actual employment of unskilled laborers at the plant or the demand.for unskilled laborers for future training. The supply schedule for un­ skilled labor services was expected to be perfectly elastic over a limited range of employment for the reasons alluded to earlier. Again .depending on the amount of increase in the demand schedule relative to the supply schedule the wage rate for unskilled labor would remain constant or increase. In Figure 6B, an increase in the demand schedule from DD to

D^DI would result in an increase in employment from Qq to at a constant wage rate Wq, If, however, the demand schedule for unskilled labor services.increased to D2D2, then the level of employment would be at Q2, while the wage rate would have risen to Arising from the foregoing analysis, it was expected • that employment in both areas would increase as a result of the demand for labor services by the new industrial plants. However the probable effects on wage rates are not as evident. Any upgrading of the levels of skill of the labor force in these areas would tend to raise average wage rates, while wage rates for various types of labor services would either increase or remain constant. Since the new factories in both 138

areas were a major source of employment in the towns wherein situated, the most probable effect was the increases in demand for labor services by the new plants would lead to increases in average wage rates in both areas. Hypotheses can also be developed regarding the geographi­ cal incidence of the employment effects of a new industrial plant. In any particular occupation and in any specific grade of skill within that occupation, the employees of the new plant may be expected to receive a wage rate which is unrelated to the distance travelled to and from work by those employees. Such commuting involves transportation costs and loss of lei­ sure time, both of which are roughly proportional to distance travelled. Because of these costs of commuting, the propor­ tion of population and the actual number of workers commuting to work at the new industrial plants were expected to be in­ versely related to distance from the plants, due to the decreasing net differential between wages received and total cost of commuting. Indirect wage adjustments in both areas would therefore be expected, to diminish with increasing dis­ tance from the new plants. Increases in population and incomes per capita usually arise from increases in employment and wage rates. These in­ creases would then be expected to lead to an increase in the demand for goods and services sold by other firms in these areas. This, in turn, might lead to an increase in demand 139 for labor services "by those other "business firms. This indirect emplosrment effect would probably be quite small relative to the direct employment effect in both areas studied, since it is reasonable to expect that in areas experiencing declining employment and net emigration some business firms have unused capacity. However, any indirect employment effects which would occur in those areas would generate additional upward pressure on wage rates in both areas.

D, Population Effects

Although increases in employment are usually accompanied by increases in population, an increase in employment in an area can occur without an increase in an area's population. Employment of persons residing within the area who were for­ merly unemployed, employment of persons residing within the area who were formerly employed outside the area or employment of persons who commute from outside the area would give rise to an increase in emploient within the area but not to an increase in the population of the area. It was likely, however, since the new industrial plants would have a relatively large employment in both areas, that population as well as employment would rise in both areas. Here again, it must be borne in mind that an increase is to be understood as an increase in population relative to what l4o population would have "been in the absence of the new plants, not relative to what population was prior to the establish­ ment of the new plants. Persons who remained in these areas as a result of obtaining employment following the establish­ ment of the new industrial plants who would otherwise have emigrated from these areas would increase these areas* popu­ lation. Similarly, any migration of workers into the areas would increase population. Since some of these workers would be heads of households, population would be expected to in­ crease by some multiple of the number of employees in these two categories. It was also expected that such increases in population would be greater in and around Scarriff and Tubbercurry than in other parts of the two areas, since, as hypothesized earlier, increases in employment at the .new plants would be greater in an around Scarriff and Tubbercurry than in other parts of the two areas, since, as hypothesized earlier, increases in employment at the new plants would be greater in and around Scarriff and Tubbercurry than in other parts of the areas. In addition, persons and families who mig­ rated to the two areas as a result of employment at the two plants would be likely to reside in and around Scarriff and Tubbercurry in proximity to their new places of employment. It is, therefore, hypothesized that population increased in the two areas as a result of the new industrial activity I4l and that this increase in population diminished accordingly as distance from the new manufacturing plants increased,

E. Income Effects

Even if wage rates in both areas remained constant, total and per capita income would be expected to increase. Any increase in the number of employed workers from within the areas would raise total income, assuming no decrease in • '» hours worked by each employee. Employment at the prevailing wage rate of previously unemployed workers residing within the areas would increase income per capita as well as total income. Underemployed persons in the areas might be expected to accept employment at the new plants if they expected an increase in income as a result. For example, operators of smaller farms and small local businesses might expect to increase their incomes by accepting emplosrment at the new plants while continuing to operate their farms and businesses,. Lastly, any upgrading of labor associated with training of workers at the new plants, or migration to the areas of more highly skilled employees would increase total income and income -per capita in the areas even though wage rates remained constant. Any increase in wage rates in the two areas would give rise to additional increases in total income and income per capita, unless a corresponding decrease occurred in the 142

number of hours worked. However, it was expected that hotirs worked per employee would remain constant or increase, since the new industrial plants would increase the aggregate demand for labor services in the two areas. Since wage rate adjust­ ments would be expected to decrease with distance from the industrial plants, any increases in income per capita in th,e areas due to increases in wage rates wotp.d also be expected to decrease with distance from Scarriff and Tubbercurry. Increases in total income and income per capita within the two areas would be expected to occur. These increases would also be expected to be greatest in and around Scarriff and Tubber curry than in other parts of the two areas, since employment and population were expected to increase more in the parts of the areas closest to Scarriff and Tubbercurry.

P. Household Expenditure Effects

Aggregate demand for goods and services sold by business firms in the two areas would be expected to increase as a result of increased consumer expenditures arising from the increases in population and income. It is well to remember once more that this increase in demand must be considered relative to the level of demand in these areas in the absence of the new plants, not to the level of demand in the period just prior to the commencement of industrial activity. An increase in population and/or income per capita would increase. 14-3

the demand schedule facing business firms selling various types of consumer goods and services. However, it was also expected that some employees who lived in the outlying parts of the two areas would shift their shopping patterns in favor of Scarriff and Tubbercurry. In addition, since the increase in population would be greatest in and around these towns, the incidence of the expenditure effects could also be expected to be greatest in and around Scarriff and Tubbercurry,

; • ;

G, Farm Business Effects .

1. Direct Effects Direct effects of industrialization on farm businesses are those changes in farming activity which result on farms from which the farm operator or another member of the farm family accepted employment at the new industrial plant. In the present study, major attention is focused on the direct effects on fazm businesses which arise as a result of farm operators accepting industrial. employment. Industrial employment of a farm operator may affect his farm business by increasing the relative scarcity of operator labor and also by stimulating farm investment. If a desire for increased income induces a farm operator to take a non- farm job, it is reasonable to infer from this that the marginal return to his labor is greater in the nonfarm job 14^ than is his farm business. Hence, the opportunity cost of nonfarm labor may increase with nonfarm employment. Depend­ ing on the elasticity of supply of operator labor with respect to income, this increased opportunity cost may induce adjustments in farm inputs, in product mix, in farm output and in farm income. On the other hand, an increase in the income of a farm family associated with nonfarm employment may give rise to an increase in family savings and lead to a reduction in the opportunity cost of investing in the farm business. Such a reduction in the opportunity cost of farm investment may induce farm capital formation and increased use of more productive reproducible farm inputs. This income effect may, to a certain extent, counteract any adjustment pressures in the farm business, which arise because of a reduction in avail­ ability of operator labor. While bearing this possibility in mind, some of the direct effects of industrialization on farm business are examined hereunder in more detail. a. Labor use The employment of a farm operator at an industrial plant may or may not reduce the labor input in his farm business, depending on various possibly substitution effects. One possibility may be that prior to industrial employ­ ment the farm operator was engaged in farm duties for only a small proportion of his total available time.. This might be 1^5

expected to occur if the effective quantities of land and capital on his farm were extremely small, so that the marginal return to his labor in his farm business would be so low that he would devote a high proportion of his time to leisure. Under such circumstances, availability of industrial employ­ ment at a considerably higher rate of return to his labor might result in a large substitution of income-generating activity for leisure. In accepting industrial employment, he may merely utilize his available time more fully without de­ creasing the amount of time devoted to farm work. In general, however, industrial employment involves a large and relatively constant input of time on the part of industrial employees. In general, also, the amount of time devoted by farm operators to strictly leisure activities is less than the amount of time usually required as an input in industrial employment. It may well be that an operator has been devoting a large amount of time to farm work, but that his labor has not been very productive, due to the low levels of other inputs available to him. Industrial employment of such an operator would be expected to induce a substitution of industrial work for leisure and a substitution of indus­ trial work for farm work. His time devoted to farm work would decline, but such decline would be less than the time devoted to industrial employment, because of an increase in total time worked. 146

In a third, situation, industrial employment of a farm operator may result in a decline in his time spent at farm work roughly equal to the time devoted to his industrial emplosrment. Such a situation would arise when the operator*s total work time was already large. Industrial employment would then involve a substitution of one work activity (indus­ trial work) for another (farm work). It was felt that most farm operators in both areas fell in the second or third cate­ gory described. Hence, it was expected that some reduction in time devoted to farm work would occur in the case of most farm operators accepting employment at the new plants. The direct effects of industrial employment of a farm operator on his farm business are strongly influenced by the labor situation on his farm. Even when the time spent at farm work by the farm operator declines as a result of his industrial emplo3rment, it need not follow that a reduction in total labor used on his farm will occur, as other farm labor (either family or hired) may be available to substitute for that lost to industrial employment. The extent to which family labor may be substituted for operator labor is influenced by family size and composition, which determine the availability of potential substitute labor on a farm. The extent to which this potential substitute labor is utilized to substitute for operator labor depends on the rate at which these people can transform some of their 14? present activities into the equivalent of operator labor and also on their desire to do so. Considerable variability was expected in these character­ istics among farm families. This would give rise to wide variation among farms in the amount of labor substitution for a given loss of operator labor. However, it was expected that some increase in amount of time devoted to farm work by other family members was likely to occur on most farms the operators of which had accepted industrial employment. b. Farm investment In general, industrial employment of a farm operator may be expected to increase the total income of a farm family. This may give rise to an increase in family savings, which, in turn, would tend to reduce the opportunity cost of investment in the farm business. The influence of this effect would be present even.on farms where family labor sub­ stituted completely for any operator labor lost through indus­ trial employment. However, the increased opportunity cost of operator labor to the farm business may induce efforts to economize on the use of labor. This, coupled with a decreased opportunity cost of farm investment funds, may result in an increase in the use of labor-saving machinery and methods. This would be most likely to occur when family labor cannot be substituted readily for operator labor, because of its low elasticity of supply on some farms. Such an adjustment might take the form of acquisition of machinery and equipment or its hiring. 148

Apart from investment induced by labor-saving, a decrease in the opportunity cost of farm investment funds may give rise to increased investment in new and improved reproducible farm inputs. Increases may occur in expenditures on such inputs as better seeds and fertilizers, more or improved live­ stock et cetera. Investment may take place to increase the effective input of land on a farm, either by purchasing or renting additional land or by improving the productivity of existing land on the farm through drainage or other reclama­ tion processes. Cropping pattern Industrial employment of a farm operator may give rise to adjustments in land utilization. However, as noted earlier, the effect of greater scarcity of operator labor may be partly off-set by the investment effects arising from increased family income. An increase in the scarcity of operator labor may be expected to induce a substitution of labor-extensive crops for labor-intensive crops. In particular, it may be expected that in the areas studied a reduction would occur in the acreage under potatoes and other root crops along with a reduc­ tion in acreage under grain crops on farms, the operators of which accepted industrial employment. This would be accom­ panied by a corresponding increase in acreage under hay and pasture, except to the extent that a reduction in total acreage farmed was involved. 149

There may be a reduction in total acreage farmed, especially if crops, the acreage -under which is "being reduced, were grown on land rented on a conacre system. On the other hand, as already noted, the investment effect may induce an increase in acreage farmed. Hence, the most proTaable net effect on total acreage farmed depends on the relative strength of these two effects. Pressure for adjustments in cropping patterns may be expected to be greatest on farms where a substantial increase occurred in the opportunity cost of operator labor, where the supply of other farm labor is highly inelastic and where the reduction in the opportunity cost of farm investment funds was slight. Such adjustment pressure would be least (or possibly nonexistent) on farms characterized by the negation of the foregoing attributes, d. Livestock mttem Similar effects may be expected in the case of livestock enterprises on farms the operator of which has accepted industrial emplosrment. An increase in the scarcity of operator labor would induce a reduction in labor-intensive livestock enterprises and a possible increase in labor extensive livestock enterprises, though not neces­ sarily requiring the latter. In particular, in th.e study areas, it was expected that industrial employment of farm operators would induce a decline in numbers of pigs and dairy cows kept and an increase in the 150 number of other (dry) cattle. However, the reduction in number of dairy cows might be counteracted on some farms by the investment effect, especially if the supply of other farm labor on these farms were fairly elastic. It was expected that a shift from labor-intensive to labor-extensive enterprises would occur both in terms of cropping and livestock patterns since the most frequently adopted labor-extensive livestock enterprize in those areas (rearing of beef cattle) is highly complementary with the most frequently adopted labor extensive crop (pasture) in the study areas. e. Farm output and farm income , Obviously, the impact which industrial employment of a farm .operator will have on the output of his farm depends on the magnitude of the substi­ tution effects (both factor and product) and on the magnitude and kind of net investment effects on the farm business. Cir­ cumstances under which a decrease in farm output would be most likely to occur may be described as follows; low income elasticity of supply of operator and family labor, lack of opportunity to effect labor economies in crop and/or live­ stock production and a low propensity to invest in the farm business. These circumstances are not as likely to be characteris­ tic of farms where•operator have accepted industrial employ­ ment as frequently as they are characteristic of other farm's. 151

The operator of a farm where such circumstances prevail would have considerably less incentive to seek nonfarm employment, other things being equal, than would operators of farms not so circumstanced. Selectivity aspects, therefore, are expected to be of importance in influencing the incidence of industrial employment among farm operators in such a manner that their industrial employment would not be expected to reduce farm output on most of the farms involved. Maintenance of farm output at its level prior to the acceptance of industrial employment might be accomplished in one or more of several ways. The farm operator may work harder while at farm work, he may rise earlier or work later into evening-time or he may allocate his time more effectively. The operator*s wife or other family members may compensate for the loss in operator labor. Greater recourse may be had to labor-saving technology; while the investment effect arising from increased total family income would also tend to boost farm output. Arising from the foregoing, it would also be expected that industrial employment in both areas involved but slight, if any, reductions in farm income. Where farm output declined as a result of industrial emplo]rment, it would be expected that farm income would decline also. However, since the decreases . in output were expected to be slight, any decreases in farm income were also expected to be slight. It would, therefore. 152 appear that most of the additional income obtained by farm families as a result of industrial employment of farm opera­ tors would represent a net'increase to the total family income of such farm families in both areas.

'2. Indirect effects Indirect effects on farm businesses may arise as a result of local industrialization. These may involve changes in the supply situation for farm inputs or the demand situation for farm products. An indirect effect of the first type might arise if the increased demand for labor services by the new industrial plant led to and increase in the local level of wage rates, including wages paid to hired farm labor. Such an increase might be expected to induce adjustments in resources, output and income on farms which use moderate to substantial amounts of hired labor. However, in the two study areas, the quantity of hired labor used on most farms is negligible; hence this effect was not expected to be of high magnitude. The second type of indirect effect might be expected to occur following an increase in an area*s population or income •per capita. If a new industrial plant gives rise to a direct population increase, this, in turn, would be expected to shift the demand schedule for farm products within that area. An indirect effect of increased income. on consumption might also occur following employment of workers at a new plant. This ^ might also lead to an increased demand for some farm products. 153

Howevèr, the income elasticity of demand for most farm products would appear to be relatively low. Hence, increases in an area*8 income per capita would not be likely to generate much of an increased demand for farm products. In addition, it is also possible that any increased demand for farm products might be met by farm producers outside the area involved. This "leakage" would reduce the indirect effect on farm businesses in the area itself,' In either case, the incidence of these indirect effects would be quite diffuse and their magnitude difficult to quantify. In the present study, no rigorous attempt was made to estimate the magnitude of these indirect effects.

2» Selectivity aspects The concept of selectivity has been discussed in detail earlier in the present chapter. The decision of a farm operator to seek employment at a newly established industrial plant may be presumed to result after careful consideration on his part. It is to be expected that such a decision would be influenced to a large extent by family and farm characteristics. Whether or not he might actually obtain such employment, given his decision to seek it, may, in turn, be influenced by the hiring policy of the new firm. For these reasons, therefore, it was expected that, in both areas, it should be possible to discern certain differences in personal and farm characteristics between farm operators who obtained employment at the new 15^

plant and those who did not obtain such employment. The farm differences would be expected to be manifested in such characteristics as farm income, farm size, value of farm machinery, quantities of livestock ^ cetera. The per­ sonal differences would be expected to be associated with age, education, previous nonfarm work experience ^ cetera.

H. Summary of %rpotheses

The hypotheses in the present study regarding the impact of the establishment of new industrial plants at Scarriff and Tubbercurry on the surrounding areas are summarized hereunder. Survey data collected in the course of the present study will be used to evaluate these hypotheses. 1. The new plants directly increased employment in the two areas. This increase consisted of people who were newly drawn in to the labor force, people from outside these areas who moved into the areas and people who would have left the areas in the absence of obtaining employment at the new plants. . The emploarment effect diminished as distance from Scarriff and Tubbercurry increased, 2. Population in both areas increased, due to immigration of some workers and their families and the non-emigration from the areas of some workers and their families who would other­ wise have left the areas. The population effect diminished as distance from Scarriff and Tubbercurry increased. 3. Incomes in both areas increased. The increase in total income and in income per household diminished as distance from Scarriff and Tubbercurry increased. 155-159 •f 4. Increased incomes of employee households resulted in increased expenditures on goods and services. There was also a shift in the incidence of purchases of goods and services from the outlying parts of the two areas in favor of purchases in the towns of Scarriff and Tubbercurry. 5. Acceptance of industrial employment by farm operators resulted in resource adjustments and product mix adjustments on their farms. 6. The most frequently occurring resource ad­ justment on such farms was labor substitution, 7. Decreases in total farm output were not neces­ sitated on most farms the operators of which accepted industrial employment. 8. Farm and personal characteristics differentiated the farm operators who obtained industrial employment from those who did not obtain such emplosrment. i6o

VII. METHODOLOGICAL CONSIDEEATIONS

The methodological considerations involved in the identi- fication and measiirement of industrializa.tion effects in Western Ireland are discussed in this chapter. Section A contains a general discussion regarding problems involved in measurement of the effects. The selection and delineation of the study are&s is discussed in Section B, The sources of data used in the study are detailed in Section C, Section D describes the manner in which the direct effects of indus­ trialization were estimated, while Section -E "contains' a dis­ cussion of the methods used in the examination of the selec­ tivity factors involved,

A. Problems of Measurement

Difficult problems arise in attempting to identify and measure the effects of industrialization. One of these is the problem of accurately measuring the changes in the variables studied. Measurement of change implies the avail­ ability of data pertaining to at least two points in time. Changes in primary data can be measured most accurately if the desired information is collected at each relevant point in time, as such a procedure tends to minimize memory bias. Ideally, measurement of changes Induced by industriali­ zation would require a benchmark study in an area prior to the introduction of the new industrial plant the impact of I6l which it is desired to study. This "benchmark study would be followed at a later date by one or more studies undertaken after the new plant had been in operation. Accurate measurement of change in the relevant variables, however, is not the most difficult problem encountered. After a new industrial plant has been established in an area, other forces which may generate changes in the variables being studied continue to operate. Hence, the measured changes in these variables may reflect the result of industrialization or of other forces. More likely, they will reflect a com­ bination of effects emanating from the industrialization and from other forces which may generate change. Thus, there is the problem of determining how much, if any, of the observed changes in the relevant variables can be attributed to the effects of industrialization and how much to the effects of other forces. One approach to the solution of this latter problem would involve undertaking a controlled'experiment type of study. In such a study, in addition to the area wherein the new industrial plant had been located, one or more control areas would be selected on the basis of overall similarity to the area of interest. The only significant difference among these areas during the study period would be that the area of interest would have experienced industrialization, while the other(s) would not. 162

The variables of interest would be measured during the base period and during or at the end of the study period. Changes occurring in these variables in the area of interest and in the control area(s) would then be calculated and the difference between these changes would be attributed to the effect of industrialization. Some variables which might be examined in such a study- would be total area employment, sectoral employment, total Income, income per capita, manufacturing output, manufacturing sales, retail sales, agricultural output, local taxation base, income tax payments, population, age distribution of popula­ tion, net migration into or out of the area, educational expansion ^ cetera. A study of the foregoing nature would be suited to the identification of the total effects of industrialization, _i. e., the combined direct, and indirect effects, which have been discussed in the previous chapter. It would not be possible to separate these effects, nor to estimate the nature and magnitude of the selectivity aspects involved. An alternative approach involves a survey type study. Such a study provides the best approach for observing the direct effects of industrialization and the influence of the selectivity factors. Ideally, in order to measure the selectivity factors, it would be desirable to have prior to their acceptance of plant employment, data regarding the personal, household 163 and farm business characteristics of those people who ob­ tained plant employment. Such data could be compared with data pertaining to the same time period regarding the same characteristics of those people who did not obtain plant employment. Prom this comparison, the nature and magnitude of the selectivity factors could be estimated. The original data regarding the personal, household and farm business characteristics of those people who accepted plant employment could subsequently be compared with data regarding the same characteristics of these people during or at the end of the study period. Thus, combined direct and indirect effects of industrialization might be elucidated. Groups of people could be identified who, in the base period had attributes similar to those of the people who obtained plant employment, except that these groups did not obtain plant employment. Changes occurring during the study period in the personal, household and farm business characteristics of these groups could be measured. Differences between the changes observed in the characteristics of the plant employee group and the changes observed in the characteristics of group possessing initially similar attributes would be due to the direct effects of industrialization. Since the plants in both areas had been in operation for some few years prior to the present study being conceived, it was not possible to conduct a benchmark study. Because 164

of the limitations on the availability of aggregate data pertaining to the areas of interest and because of the specific interest of the present study in the direct indus­ trialization effects and in the selectivity factors, it was decided to conduct a survey type study in the two areas. Towards this end, it was decided to interview all plant employees in both areas. In addition, a sample of heads of urban households which contained no plant employees and a sample of farm operators who were not employed at the plant were interviewed in each area. The direct effects of industrialization were identified by direct questioning of plant employee respondents regarding changes arising as a result of their obtaining, employment at the new plants. The magnitude of the selectivity factors was estimated indirectly by comparing characteristics of certain groups of plant employees with those of corresponding groups of other people from the area who did not obtain plant employment, after allowing for the direct effects reported by the plant employees. This approach has two limitations. The first involves the ability of respondents to recall the direction and magni­ tude of changes in the relevant variables. The second in­ volves their ability to identify portions of these changes as arising as a result of their obtaining plant employment. These limitations notwithstanding, it was felt that this 165 approach provided the best available analytic framework for analyzing the problem at hand and that it would provide interesting and useful results, •

B, Selection and Delineation of Areas

The criteria used in selecting the study areas have been discussed earlier. Likewise, the manner in which the bound­ aries to those areas were determined has also been discussed. At this point, however, it is appropriate to note that the area delineated around Tubbercurry contained the residences of 153 or 97.5 percent of the 157 employees interviewed. Two of the 4 who resided outside the area were residents of the town of Sligo, One resided near Ballysodare and one near Collooney, The area delineated around Scarriff contained the resi­ dences of 137 or 90.7 percent of the 151 plant employees who were interviewed. Thirteen of the 14 people who resided outside the area were residents of County Tipperary, hence being excluded, by definition, form the area, since they resided outside the Undeveloped Areas, Nearly all of these 13 plant employees resided in and around Ballina, County Tipperary, which, as noted earlier is connected to Killaloe by a bridge across the Hiver Shannon, The other employee who resided outside the area resided about 4 or 5 miles west of Tulla, County Clare, . l66

C, Sources of Data

The field work in connection with the present study was conducted in the two areas during the summer of 1966. This section describes the manner in which the field work was organized and conducted and the types of data collected. Plant employees A complete listing of all employees was provided by the plant management personnel in each area. Facilities were kindly made available by the plant management personnel to enable the plant employees to be interviewed at the plants. Interviews were arranged with all plant employees up throu^ the rank of working foreman. Clerical and secretarial per­ sonnel were included, but the management personnel were not included in the group to be interviewed. There were I83 plant employees in Tubbercurry. One hundred and fifty-seven complete interviews were obtained.

Pour of the employees were ill and, thus, not at work; 3 more were on holidays while the interviews were being con­ ducted, Nineteen plant employees refused to cooperate in the study. The Scarriff plant had 19^ employees when the survey was conducted. One hundred and fifty-one complete interviews were obtained. Three plant employees were absent from work due to illness; seven were on holidays, while there were eight refusals. In addition.there were 15 timber workers - 16? and 10 lorry drivers who were not available for interview. The latter have a "brief. turn-about period at the plant. Data presented earlier regarding the sex distribution of all plant•employees and of those plant employees inter­ viewed was about the same as the proportion of males and females among the population of plant employees in each area. Some differences may exist in Scarriff between the timber workers and lorry drivers on the one hand and the remainder of the plant employees on the other. However, a few of these workers were interviewed. Data regarding age, education, residence, income et cetera for these few employees did not differ appreciably from corresponding data pertaining to other plant employees. However, there were only a few cases involved. Hence, some caution may be advisable in general­ izing from the results of the interviews with the other plant employees, because of the nonavailability of most of the timber workers and lorry drivers for interview. The questionnaries used in interviewing plant employees are contained in Appendix B. The first questionnaire was administered to all plant employees. Information was obtained regarding personal characteristics (age, sex, education et cetera) of the employee and the other members of his household, the employee*s residential and occupational history since 1956, job attitude, length of time in plant employment, pre­ sent earnings, previous earnings, estimated alternative local 168-169

earnings In the absence of the plant cetera. Information was also obtained regarding the magnitude of any increases in household income reported as a result of obtaining plant• employment, on the expenditure of these increased incomes and on shifts in shopping patterns induced as a result of obtaining plant employment. In addition, the farm work association of each plant employee was determined during the course of the interview. An additional questionnaire was administered to each plant employee who was a farm operator. This farm questionnaire was designed to elicit information regarding land utilization, numbers of livestock, labor and machinery use and farm income. In addition, information was collected from those farm opera­ tors regarding the changes in their farm businesses which they made as a direct result of obtaining plant employment. The content of these questionnaires will be referred to in more detail in the next section during the discussion of the methods used in estimating the direct effects of industriali­ zation. 2, Farm operator sample In order to determine the nature and magnitude of the selectivity factors affecting farm operator employment at the plants, a sample of farm operators who were not employed at the plants was drawn in each area. No list of farm operators was available, so the samples had to be drawn by 170 indirect means which are outlined hereunder. Irish agricultural statistics are collected in relation to "agricultural holdings". An "agricultural holding" is viewed as all land used wholly or partly for agricultural or livestock production, that is operated, directed or managed by one person (the holder), alone or with the assis­ tance of others, without regard to title,, size or location, and may "be in one or more pieces if they are in the same neighborhood and are known and operated as a single holding or property. A lower limit of one quarter of an acre is adopted in the application of this criterion; - The enumeration districts are the District Electoral Divisions (DSD*s). In the 1965 agricultural enumeration, where a holding lay partly in one DED and partly in one or more other DED's, data pertaining to each part were enumerated separately in the DED in which that part of the holding was located. Hence, the number of holdings reported in each DED consisted of all holdings lying wholly or partly in that DED. Such holdings, lying partly in two or more DED*s are referred to as "divided holdings". Adjustments in numbers of holdings to take account of the number of "divided hold­ ings" are not published at the DED level. Such adjustments are made at the level of Rural Districts (sub-county aggre­ gations of DED's) and at higher levels of aggregation. However, in respect of each holding, one specific point 171

called the headquarters (usually where the farmjiard is located) has been defined. Ifhen parts of a holding lie in two or more DED*s, it is possible to identify the DSD in which the headquarters is situated. It was decided, for the purposes of the present study, to confine attention to farms of five or more acres in extent, A sample of about 100 operators of such farms was desired in each area. An initial sampling fraction to pro­ vide this number of holdings (unadjusted for "divided holdings") was calculated. This sampling fraction was then increased by the ratio of the total number of holdings (including "divided holdings") to the number of whole holdings in the Rural District which comprised the bulk of each area. A further adjustment was made to allow for noninterviews and for the possibility that some holdings as defined were no longer being operated as separate farms. These t%fo adjust­ ments resulted in a one-in-fourteen sampling fraction in the Scarriff area and a one-in-thirty sampling fraction in the • Tubbercurry area. The Tubbercurry area had a larger number of holdings, than had the Scarriff area, partly because the area was larger and partly because the holdings in the Tubbercurry area tended to be smaller than those in the Scarriff area. In order to obtain representation in the sample from each DED, it was decided to stratify holdings by DED and to 172 draw holdings at random within each DSD, using the same sampling fraction for all BED*s in each area, A "headquar­ ters rule" was devised for use in the case of "divided holdings". In the case of each "divided holding", such a holding was included in the sample if its headquarters lay in the DED for which that holding was drawn; such a holding was excluded if its headquarters lay in another DED. Thus every holding had an equal and independent chance of being drawn in the sample. The number of agricultural holdings returned in the agricultural enumeration was expected to exceed the number of farm operators, for a variety of reasons. First of all, land let to other persons is not included as part of the holding of him to whom it has been let. Rather, it is included in the holding to which it had formerly belonged. Since whole holdings are sometimes let, the "holder" of such a holding would not be a farm operator and that holding would be operated by the renter either as a separate farm or, more likely, as part of and in conjunction with other land which he already was operating. Secondly, other holdings which have ceased to be operated as farms may still be included as separate holdings for enumeration purposes. Examples of such holdings would be holdings which have been sold and are now being operated by other farmers as part of their farms, holdings sold to or 173 acquired by the Irish Land Commission for redistribution to relieve land congestion, but which have not yet been real­ located, holdings sold to the Foresty Division of the Department of Lands for afforestation purposes,, but vhich have not yet been planted and holdings whose owners may be elderly or unable to work and which are being operated by locally resident relatives of the owners in conjunction with their own farms. The procedure used in deriving a sample of farm opera­ tors from the sample of holdings was as follows. All holdings in the sample which had been acquired.by the Irish Land Commission or by the Department of Lands were identified. These had ceased to be operated as separate farms and were eliminated. Holdings in the sample which had been sold or let were identified. IfJhere such a holding was being operated as a separate farm by the new owner or renter, the new ovmer or renter was interviewed and data collected pertaining to that farm. Where such a holding was being operated as part of another farm, it was eliminated. Similarly, in cases where the prospective interviewee had died since the lists of holdings had been revised the holding was included in the sample if it was currently .being operated as a separate farm. If., not, it was eliminated. Any farm operator plant employees who were drawn in the samples were eliminated therefrom, so that the samples would be representative of farm operators 174 in both areas who had not obtained employment at the new plant. For example, use of a one-in-fourteen sampling fraction in the Scarriff area and the application of the "headquarters rule" resulted in a sample of 120 holdings. Nineteen of these holdings had ceased to be operated as separate farms, leaving 101 farm operators identified in the sample. One farm operator in the sample had been interviewed at the Scarriff plant, leaving 100 eligible farm operators. Seventy- nine complete interviews were obtained; there were 2 refusals and 19 farm operators were unobtainable for interview by rea­ son of illness, absence on vacation, not being at home on repeated calls ^ cetera. Conventional stratified sampling techniques were used in analyzing the data obtained from the farm operator sample in the Scarriff area regarding personal, household and farm busi­ ness characteristics. Even when using a one-in-thirty sampling fraction in the Tubbercurry area, l64 holdings resulted in the sample. As the study progressed, time and other resources limited the collection of the survey data. Subsequently, interview­ ing was confined to 22 of the 30 DSD*s in the Tubbercurry area. These had a total of 128 holdings listed in the sample. Twenty-one holdings had ceased to be operated as separate farms since the listings of holdings had last been revised. 175

Three farm operators in the sample were plant employees, who had been interviewed in the plant. Thus, there were 10^ eligible farm operators. Complete interviews were obtained in respect of 80 of those, while the remaining 24 were unob­ tainable for similar reasons to those cited earlier regarding the Scarriff rural sample. Data obtained in these interviews were analyzed using cluster sampling techniques, the DED*s being treated as •clusters, 2- Urban household sample A stratified random sample of urban households was drawn in each area, the towns in each area being treated as strata. A one-in-five sample was drawn in the Scarriff area and a one-in-six sample was drawn in the Tubbercurry area. Urban households which contained plant employees were eliminated from the samples. Urban households in which farm operators resided were also eliminated, as such farm operators had a chance to enter the farm operator sample. Thus the urban household sample represents nonfarm urban households containing no plant employees. Interviews were obtained with heads of the remaining households in the .samples. Use was made of selected portions of the first questionnaire which had been administered to all plant employees. Seventy-seven complete interviews with heads of urban households were- obtained in the Scarriff area and 72 complete interviews were obtained in the Tubbercurry area. Data 176 obtained in these interviews were analyzed using conventional stratified sampling techniques.

D. Estimation of Direct Effects

1, Employment Several facets of the employment'opportunities generated by the establishment of the new plants in Tubbercurry and in Scarriff were of interest. The extent to which the new plants drew some of their employees into the nonfarm labor force for the first time was determined from the employment history of the plant employees as reported when they were interviewed. The extent of employee mobility into the areas from jobs located elsewhere was determined from an examina­ tion of the location of the previous employments of those plant employees who had been previously engaged in nonfarm employment. The major interest of the present study regarding employ­ ment lay in measuring the employment effects of the new plants. The true employment effect of a plant on an area at any given point in time is the difference between the actual level of employment in the area at that point in time and the level at which employment in the area would have been at that point in time had not the plant been in the area. Since, at any given point in time, a particular plant either is or is not in a particular area, it is not possible for 177 any point in time to measure directly both employment in the presence of and in the absence of the plant. Hence, one of the two measurements must be made indirectly. The choice of which of the two measurements must be made indirectly depends on whether the plant is or is not in the area at the time-point in which the researcher is interested. For example, it may be desired to obtain informiation regarding the employment effect which Plant A would have in a particular area if it were in that area at a specific time. The actual level of employment in the absence of Plant A would be directly measurable, while the level of employment in the area if Plant A were there at that time would have to be indirect measured. In the present study, the level of employment in the pre­ sence of the new plants in both areas was directly measurable. However, the level of employment which would have existed in the summer of I966 in those areas in the absence of the plants was not directly measurable. Indirect measurement of the direct employment effect of ' the new plants in both areas was carried out as follows. Each of the plant employees interviewed was asked to estimate how much per week he would have been able to earn in the study area at the time of Interview, had not the plant been located in the area. He wa's then asked to indicate whether or not he would have remained at or come to work in the area for the alternative earnings which he had indicated he woald have 178

"been able to obtain in the area at the time of interview if the plant had not been in the area. The direct employment effect of the new plant on that area was then computed as the number of plant employees who would have gone to work outside the area rather than work in the area for the alter­ native earnings which they had indicated they would have been able to obtain in the absence of the plant. Each employee who had indicated that hé would'not have: remained at (or come to ) work in the two areas in the absence of the new plants was asked to indicate the place to which he would have gone. This information was used to estimate the proportion of the plant employees who would have left Ireland in the absence of the new plants in the study area. 2. Population The magnitude of population migration into each area as a result of plant employees moving residence into the area in association with obtaining emplosnnent at the new plants was measured. It was assumed that, if the head of a house­ hold had moved into one of the areas in association with his obtaining of plant employment, the members of his household had migrated with him. It also was assumed that migration to the areas by plant employees who were nonheads of households involved only those plant employees. In estimating the direct population effect of the new plants on the two areas, those employees who had indicated 179 that they would have gone in search of employment to places outside the areas were classified on the basis of whether or not they were currently residing within the areas. Migra­ tion of heads of households currently residing within the areas who would have left the areas in the absence of the plants was assumed to involve the migration of the other members of their households, though possibly after some time lag. Migration of nonheads of households from the area was assumed to involve just themselves. The direct population effect on the two areas was estimated as the number of people who would have been involved in .migration of households and of single people from the areas in the absence of the new plants. 2* Income Each employee was asked to indicate whether or not there had been an increase in his household income as a result of his plant employment, after allowing for any expenses invol­ ved in his present job. Those employees who indicated that there had been such increases were asked to indicate the magnitude of the increments. Each employee who had indicated that he would have gone to work outside the areas in the absence of the new plants was asked to indicate how much he felt he would have been . earning in the alternative location had he gone there. A comparison of the present plant earnings of those employees who would have gone to work outside the areas in the absence 180 of the plants with the earnings which they. felt they would have been receiving in these alternative locations provided information of value in assessing the importance of any non- income considerations which prompted those employees to stay at work in the study areas rather than go to the alternative locations for the earnings which they believed they would have been able to receive in those alternative locations, 4. Expenditure All plant employees who had reported an increase in house­ hold income as. a result of plant employment were asked to allocate the actual or proposed expenditure of the reported increment in income among various expenditure categories. Some employees indicated the expenditure categories to which some of the increased income had been devoted. Others ranked expenditure categories by the amount of the added income devoted to them. Still others provided actual or percentage allocations of the added income among the expenditure cate­ gories. Thus, it was possible .to analyze the expenditure effects at three levels, viz. mentions of categories, rankings of categories and allocations among categories. Plant employees reporting increased income were asked to indicate the town in which most of the income had been spent. Plant employees were also asked to indicate whether, as a result of obtaining plant employment, they or other"members 181 of their households had increased their shopping in the towns wherein the plants were situated. If so, they were asked to indicate whether or not they had decreased their shopping in other towns. The goods and services involved in such shopping shifts were then identified. Farm business The nature and magnitude of the direct effects on farm business in the two areas as a result of farm operators ob­ taining plant employment were identified by direct questioning of the farm operators involved. Each operator was asked whether or not there had been a change in a number of farm characteristics as a direct result of his obtaining plant employment. Each operator reporting a direct change in land utilization or in livestock numbers was asked to estimate the amount of the change which had occurred as a direct result of his obtaining plant employment.

E. Selectivity Factors

In order to elucidate the nature and importance of any selectivity factors which influenced the obtaining of plant employment by certain people a number of comparisons were made between characteristics of groups of people in each area who obtained employment and corresponding groups of people who did not obtain employment at the new plants. Four group­ ings of people were considered for this purpose, farm operators 182 nonheads of farm households who were in the 1^ through 64 year working age group, heads of urban households and, finally, nonheads of urban households who were in the working age group. Comparisons based on age and educational attain­ ment were made in respect of each of these groups. Compari­ sons based on household size were also made for farm operators and for heads of urban households. In addition, a large number of comparisons of farm business characteristics were made in respect of farm operators who had obtained employment at the new plants and other farm operators in the two areas who were not employed at the plants. In making these comparisons based on farm business character­ istics, the direct effects of operator emplosrment on these characteristics were taken into account in order to evaluate the selectivity factors in terms of original differences bet­ ween the farm business characteristics of the two groups of farm operators, those who subsequently obtained plant employ­ ment and those who did not obtain such employment. 183

VIII. EMPLOYMENT EFFECTS

This chapter presents an analysis of the direct employ­ ment effects of industrialization on the Tubbercurry and Scarriff areas. The magnitude of these effects is examined in Section A. The spatial incidence of the effects is examined in Section B, while Section C contains a discussion of the places to which those employees who would have left the two areas in the absence of the new plants would have gone in search of emplosnnent,

A. Employment Effects

The direct employment effects of the new industrial plants are examined in this section. Specific attention is focused on new entrants to the labor force and their previous activities, the degree of transfer of labor to the new plants from agricultural occupations, the amount of entry of new employees to the areas in association with their plant employ­ ment and the numbers of plant employees who would have left the two areas in sea,rch of employment had they not obtained employment at the new plants. In addition, the prevalence of prior work in England among plant employees is also examined. 184

A» entrants to the nonfarm labor force Table 25 shows the number of plant employees who entered the nonfarm labor force for the first time in each, area in taking their present jobs at the new industrial plants. In Tubbercurry, 91 plant employees or 58 percent of the total number entered the nonfarm labor force for the first time in taking jobs at the plant. This was a considerably higher proportion of plant employees than in Scarriff, where 48 employees or about 32 percent of the plant employees entered the nonfarm labor force for the first time to take their present jobs. It is, therefore, seen that in Tubbercurry only 42 percent of plant employees had prior experience of nonfarm jobs, as opposed to 68 percent in Scarriff.

Table 25. Number of plant employees who entered nonfarm labor force for first time in taking their present jobs

Tubbercurry Scarriff Number Percent Number Percent

Entered nonfarm labor force for first time 91 58.0 . 48 31.8 Had been in nonfarm labor force prior to present job 66 42.0 103 68.2 Total 157 100.0 151 100.0 185

The immediately previous activity of the new entrants to the nonfarm labor force is shown in Table 26, The immediately previous activity of l6 of the new entrants in Tubbercurry was designated as farm operator or agricultural contractor. In contrast, only 8 of the new entrants in Scarriff were farm operators immediately prior to obtaining their present jobs. Thus, the other farm operators employed at the Scarriff plant did not enter the nonfarm labor force for the first time to take jobs at the new plant. In Scarriff, considerably more people whose immediately previous activity was that of unpaid relative assisting on a farm entered the nonfarm labor force for the first time than in Tubbercurry, Nearly 30 percent of the new entrants in Scarriff belonged to this category, as opposed to 3.3 percent in Tubbercurry. Similarly, 12.5 per­ cent of the new entrants in Scarriff had been hired agricul­ tural laborers immediately previously, while only 1.1 percent of the new entrants in Tubbercurry had been so engaged. In all, 20 people or 22 percent of the new entrants to the nonfarm labor force in Tubbercurry and 28 people or 58 percent of the new entrants in Scarriff had been engaged in agricultural occupations prior to their entry into the non- farm labor force. This, then, represents the degree to which people who were engaged wholly in agricultural occupa­ tions were attracted, either wholly or in part, into the non- farm labor force for the first time to to work at the new plants. Table 26. Immediately previous activity of plant employees who entered the nonfarm labor force for the forst time to accept plant employment

Tubbercurrv Scarriff Immediately previous activity Number Percent Number Percent

Farm operator or agricultural contractor 16 17.6 8 16.7

Unpaid relative assisting on farm 3 3.3 14 29.1

Agricultural laborer 1 1.1 6 12.5

Total agricultural occupations 20 22.0 28 58.3

At school full-time 64 70.3 19 39.6

Engaged in home duties 5 5.5

Incapacitated 1 1.1

Not engaged in income-producing activity 1 1.1 1 2.1

Total nonagricultural activities 71 78.0 20 41.7

Subtotal 91 100.0 48 100.0

Previously in nonfarm labor force 66 103

Total 157 151 18?

Subtracting out these people, it is now seen that, in Tubbercurry, 71 people or ^5.2 percent of the employees entered the overall labor force for the first time in taking their plant jobs, while 20 people or 13.2 percent of the plant employees in Scarriff did so. Further reference to Table 26 indicates the previous activity of these people. Practically all these new entrants to the labor force had been at shcool just prior to employment. The proportions involved were 90 percent in Tubbercurry and 95 percent in Scarriff. In Tubbercurry, 5 of the new entrants to the overall labor force (7 percent) had been engaged in home duties, while one person (1.5 percent) had been unable to work because of health reasons and another person (1.5 percent) had been unemployed immediately previously. Similarly, in Scarriff, one new entrant (2.1 percent) to the total labor force had been unemployed immediately previously. In summary, then, in both areas, there was a substantial number of new entrants to the nonfarm labor force as a result of new employment opportunities at the new plants, the number being greater in Tubbercurry than in Scarriff. Some of these new entrants to the nonfarm labor force had been gainfully employed in agricultural occupations, slightly over 20 per­ cent in Tubbercurry and nearly 60 percent in Scarriff. Nearly all of the remaining new entrants had been at school full- time prior to obtaining employment at the new plants. 188

2. Employee mobility into areas Plant employees are classified in Table 2? on the "basis of their nonfarm work association with the two areas of impact . (AOI) defined in this study. In Tubbercurry, 25 of the 66 plant employees who had previously worked at nonfarm jobs had always worked at such jobs in the AOI. In addition 5 plant employees had formerly worked outside the AOI and began to work in the AOI for the first time since 195^ at some jobs other than their present plant jobs. From these jobs, they later accepted employment at the new plant. There was also one plant employee who had worked in the AOI, then worked outside the AOI for some time, returning to work in the AOI at some stage since 1956, but not at his present plant job. These three groups of workers, 31 in all or 4? percent of those who had previous nonfarm jobs, had been working at other nonfarm jobs in the Tubbercurry AOI immediately prior to obtaining jobs at the new plant. In Scarriff, 57 plant employees or 45,3 percent of the 103 who had previous nonfarm work experience had been working at nonfarm jobs within the AOI immediately prior to obtaining jobs at the new plant. This group comprised 49 people whose previous nonfarm jobs had always been in the AOI, 6 whose jobs had always been outside the AOI until they began to work in the AOI subsequent to 1956 at a nonfarm job other than at the new plant and 2 people who had worked originally in the AOI, then worked outside the AOI, but returned Table 27. Distribution of plant employees by nonfarm work association with area of impact (AOI)

Tubbercurry Scarriff Nonfarm work association Number Percent Number Percent (n = 66) (n = 157) (n=103) (n=l5l)

Works in AGI at nonfarm job now and has worked at prior nonfarm job(s), always in AGI 25 37.9 15.9 49 47.6 32.5 Works in AGI at nonfarm job now, worked outside AGI previously and began to work In AGI for first time since 1956, but not at present job 5 7.6 3,2 5.8 4.0 H» 00 Works in AGI at nonfarm job now, worked VO outside AGI previously and began to work in AGI since 1956, not at present job, but had worked in AGI at an earlier stage 1 1.5 0.6 1.9 1.3 Works in AGI at nonfarm job now, worked outside AGI previously and began to work in AGI for first time at present job 25 37.9 ; 15.9 29 28.2 19.2 Works in AGI at nonfarm job how. Worked outside AGI previously and began to work in AGI since 1956 at present job, but had worked in AGI at an earlier stage 10 15.1 6.4 17 16.5 11.2 Subtotal 66 100.0 , 42.0 103 100.0 68.2 Entered nonfarm labor force for first time to take present job 91 58.0 48 31.8 Total 157 100.0 151 100.0 190 sometime after 1956 to work at some other nonfarm job. Employment at the new plants of these 31 Tubbercurry employees and 57 Scarriff employees who had been working immediately previously at other nonfarm jobs within the two areas represents a shift of workers from other jobs within the two areas to employment at the new plants. If their former employers within the two areas hired other people to fill the jobs which these people vacated, such employment would be an indirect effect of industrialization. Information regarding the extent of replacement of workers who changed jobs in accepting employment at the new plants was not collected in the present study, which focused primarily on the direct effects. It may well be that some of these vacancies were not filled if the places of former employment were operating at less than full capacity. On the other hand, some additional people may have been drawn into the labor force for the first time to fill some of these posts, while further vacancies may have been filled by attracting some other people into the two areas. It is also possible that some of these jobs were fil­ led by people who were working within the two areas at other jobs, which, in turn, would then be vacated. Hence, the in­ direct effect of industrialization on employment in both areas could spread throughout each area*s employment pattern in a chain of employment adjustments, . However, 35 of the Tubbercurry employees or 53 percent of those who had previous nonfarm work experience had been 191 working at jobs outside the AOI immediately prior to accepting their present plant employment. Twenty-five of these employees began working in the AOI for the first time at their present jobs, while the other 10 had worked in the AOI at an earlier stage, had then gone to work outside the AOI, but had returned to work in the AOI at their present plant jobs. Similarly ^6 of the Scarriff employees or 44.7 percent of those who had previous nonfarm work experience had been employed outside the AOI just prior to obtaining jobs at the new plant. Twenty nine-of these began working in the AOI for the first time at their plant jobs, while the other 1? had worked in the AOI at some stage previously, but had subsequent­ ly gone to work outside the AOI and recommenced working in the AOI at the new industrial plant. These two latter groups, amounting to 22.3 percent of all the Tubbercurry employees interviewed and 30.4 percent of the Scarriff employees interviewed, represent those people who were working outside the AOI*s but were attracted into employ­ ment within the two AOI*s following establishment of the new industrial plants. Some had worked earlier in the AOI * s, but had left. Others hailed originally from the AOI*s, but had left in search of their initial emplosrment elsewhere, never having been employed earlier in the AOI*s. Yet others had no previous association with the AOI*s until acceptance of their present plant employment. l92

Finally, 4 of the 91 new entrants to the nonfarm labor force in the Tubbercurry area came from outside the area, while 2 of the 46 new entrants in Scarriff came from outside the area to work at the new plant. These two groups of employees had had no previous association with the study areas.

Employment level in absence of plants While the analysis conducted in the preceding subsections, in terms of the new entrants to the labor force and the employees attracted into the areas from outside sources of employment, provides information regarding the direct employ­ ment effects of the new industrial plants, the true magnitude of these direct effects is that obtained from a comparison of the existential levels of emplosrment in the two areas with what the levels of employment would have been in those areas in the absence of the new plants. This is a task fraught with many difficulties of measure­ ment, One possibility would involve an estimation of what current emplosrment in the absence of the new plants would be by reference to employment changes occuring during the period of interest in other initially similar areas which îiad not experienced industrialization. However, such a- procedure was not possible in the present study. 193

The procedure adopted involved asking each employee for his estimate of how much he felt he could earn currently in the local area if the new plant were not situated there. He was then asked whether or not he would have either remained in the area or come into the area to work for that wage. This procedure suffers from the limitation that no effective means exist whereby to assess the precision of the employees* esti­ mates of their local income generating ability in the'absence of the new plants. This limitation notwithstanding, it is believed that the procedure yields data which are of use in estimating the direct effects of industrialization. As shown in Table 28, 11^ or 72.6 percent of the employees in Tubbercurry said that they would not have remained in (or entered) the AOI to work for the alternative local wage which they felt they could earn in the AOI in the absence of the plant. Similarly, 103 people or 69.1 percent of those who answered in Scarriff. said that they would not now be working in that AOI if the new plant were not there. This proportion, about 70 percent, which was quite simi­ lar in both areas, provides an estimate of the direct effect of industrialization on employment in these two areas. Apply­ ing the observed proportions to the total number of.plant employees in the two areas, the direct effects on employment may be estimated as an increase of 133 in employment in the Tubbercurry area and an increase of 134 in the Scarriff area. 194

It is accordingly concluded that the hypothesis regarding a direct increase in employment in the two areas as a result of industrialization has been supported.

Table 28. Distribution of plant employees by whether or not they would have remained to work in or entered to work in the area of impact for estimated alter­ native local wages

Tubbercurry Scarriff Number Percent Number Percent

Would have remained (or entered) 43 27.9 46 30.9 Would not have remained (or entered) 114 . 72.6 103 69.1 Subtotal 157 100.0 •. 149 100.0

No information ——— 2 Total • 157 151

4. Prior employment in England In Western Ireland, there has developed over a period of many years a strong pattern of emigration from local areas to England in search of employment. This emigration pattern has been a source of much concern, both at the local and national levels. It was felt by many people that the establishment of industrial plants in Western Ireland with the aid of grants paid under the Undeveloped Areas Act might, through employment 195 employment effects, (a) reduce the number of people leaving Western Ireland to work in England and (b) induce a return to the West of Ireland of some former residents who had gone to England in search of employment and who might wish, for family or other reasons, to return to Western Ireland, pro­ vided some acceptable employment were available to them. In order to shed some light on the extent to which the latter aim may have been achieved, plant employees are class­ ed in Table 29 on the basis of whether or not they had worked in England prior to obtaining employment at the new industrial plants. In Tubbercurry, 2? people or 40.9 percent of the employees who had previous nonfarm work experience had worked in England at some stage previously. Eighteen of these had been working in England immediately prior to obtaining their present jobs; the other 9 had worked in England at some earlier stage. In Scarriff, 22 people or 21.3 percent of the 103 employees who had previous nonfarm work experience had worked in England, 13 of them immediately prior to obtaining employment at the new plant. Those plant employees with previous work experience in England are classified in Table 30 according to whether they had worked in the AOI at any stage. Fifteen of the 2? Tubbercurry employees who had worked in England began working for the first time in the AOI at their present jobs, 6 or 22 percent were working at other jobs in the AOI just prior to 196

Table 29. Distribution of plant employees by whether or not they had worked in England prior to obtaining plant employment

Tubberourry Scarrlff Number Percent Number Percent (n=66) (n=103)

Worked in England imme­ diately prior to obtain­ ing present job 18 27.3 13 12.6 Worked in England at an earlier stage, but not immediately prior to present job 9 13.6 9 8.7 Subtotal (worked in England at some stage prior to present job) 27 40.9 22 21.3 Never worked in England 39 59.1 81 78.7 Subtotal 66 100.0 103 100.0 Entered nonfarm labor force for first time for present job 91 48 Total 157 151

obtaining their plant jobs, while 6 employees who had worked in England had worked in the AOI at an earlier stage in their careers and had come back to work in the AGI at the present jobs. In addition, 2 of the 15 who began working in the AOI for the first time at the plants had hailed from the AOI, but had left the area to work elsewhere without ever having been 197

Table 30. Distribution of plant employees who had worked in England by previous work experience in the areas of impact prior to their present jobs

Tubbercurry Scarriff Number Percent Number Percent

Worked for first time in AOI at present job 15 55.6 6 27.3 Began working in AOI at present job, but had worked in AOI at an earlier stage (not imme­ diately prior to present job 6 22.2 11 50.0 Was working in AOI imme­ diately prior to present 6 22.2 5 22.7 job

Subtotal 27 100,0 22 100.0 Never worked in England 39 81 Not in nonfarm labor force previously 91 48 Total 157 151

employed in the AOI, It is, therefore, seen that the new plant directly attracted back 8 employees who had been working in England, to work in the Tubbercurry area. Similarly, 13 employees were directly attracted back to work in the Scarriff area by the new plant, 11 of whom had worked in the AOI at some earlier stage.. Five of the Scarriff employees who had worked in England were working at other 198 occupations in the AOI immediately prior to obtaining employ­ ment at the new plant. This evidence indicates that the new plants did attract back some employees who had left those areas in search of employment in England, but that the major employment effects of the new plants operated through increasing employment in the two areas by providing employment opportunities for people who would probably have otherwise left the two areas rather than by attracting back former residents of the areas to work in the new plants,

B, Spatial Incidence of Employment Effects

The spatial incidence of the direct effects of indus­ trialization in both areas is examined in this section. Initial attention is focused on the distribution of plant employment among District Electoral Divisions (DED*s) in both areas. Next, the location of residence of the new entrants to the nonfarm labor force is examined. Then, the incidence of the direct employment effects among DED*s is discussed. Finally, the plant employees are analyzed in terms of distance from the new plants, as are the direct employment effects.

Plant employment Plant employees in Tubbercurry are classified in Table 31 according to the DED of their residence. Pour of the 157 199

Table 31. Distribution by DED of Tubbercurry plant employees, new entrants to the nonfarm labor force and plant employees who would not have remained to work in the area.- in the absence of the new plant

Total . New Employees who DED employees entrants would have left the area

Kilshalvey 5 2 3 Ballymote 3 1 3 4 3 4 E. 6 5 3 Achonry W. 6 3 6 1 1 1 Banada 16 13 6 Breencoragh 1 1

Bra.nchfield 1 - — 1 3 2 3 Temple 4 4 4 Owenmore 1 - 1 6 3 5 Cloonoghill 3 1 2 Glendarragh 4 3 2 Kilturra 2 1 1 Leitrim • 10 10 9 Streamstown 3 3 1 . Tubbercurry 65 28 50 Cloonmore 2 - 2 Doocastle .3 2 2 Kilbeagh 2 1 1 Sonnagh 2 1 . 2

Subtotal 153 88 110

Reside outside area 4 3 4

Total 157 91 114 200 employees reside outside the AOI, Sixty-five or 42.5 percent of the 153 plant employees who reside within the AOI are residents of the Tubbercurry DED. The DED*s of Banada and. Leitrim, both of which adjoin the Tubbercurry DED contain 16 and. 10 plant employees respectively. Thus, residents of these three DSD*s comprise 91 or nearly 60 percent of the employees who resided within the AOI, The distribution of the residences of plant employees among DED»s in both areas is depicted in Fugure 7, while the DED distribution of the Scarriff employees is shown in Table 32. As will be noted, 58 or 42.3 percent of the 137 employees residing within the Scarriff AOI were residents of the Scarriff DED, the next highest number being from the adjoin­ ing DED of . Relatively high numbers of employees resided in the DED*s of Drumaan, Kilseily and Killaloe. These DED's contain the towns of Whitegate, Broadford and Killaloe respectively. These data indicate that plant employment in the Tubbercurry area was more concentrated in and around the town where the plant was situated than was the case in the Scarriff area. Further evidence to support this viewpoint is presented in Table 33 which shows the distribution of plant employees by distance from the new plants. In the Tubbercurry AOI, nearly 60 percent of the employees resided within 4 miles of the new plant, as compared to about 45 percent of the Scarriff employees. 201

Table 32. Distribution by DED of Scarriff plant employees, new entrants to the nonfarm labor force and plant employees who would not have remained to work in the area in the absence of the new plant

Total New Employees who DED employees entrants would have left the area

Kilseily 11 1 8 Carrowbaun 1 1 Killaloe 9 1 ' 8 Ogonnelloe 14 8 2 Ayle 2 2 1 Boherglass 5 3 2 Cahermurphy ^1 - 1 Cloonusker 3 2,1 Corlea 1 - 1 7 1 3 Cappaghbaun 4 3 2 Drummaan 13 2 11 Iniscaltra N. 2 - 2 Mountshannon 3 2 2 Scarriff 58 .19 38 Glandree 1 - Killaneena 1 . - 1 Loughea 1 1

Subtotal 137 45 92

Reside outside area 14 3 11

Total 151 48 103 VfOOUHi 1)1 ï 1:' / %?*A%gr / -.4 •.•. -••.• .: \^,iiLV .I'M/wA; fieio \ _ ...•.. : ^.:-'..j ^.usm/,/ 4 ,j\ \ %,^^|.X.../13 W f C''3J i>nvnmnn fOUtti... ^••>D&!->f"""l V &%'é

; fiitic. Is&V"""""''-^ 6.// "«««».- i2 '' V '* "footff^ev V.;l "IIMACWCE .Ai//ac^l«4U/* , f 'vO.YAfCOe, msRcuR'sT y A%f . .../v . : 14%;) 65 ••W----S-i :( i.-"ï ••/./ 2 y. "•SS.y ''."Hii^Lvr . l ^C/Wtfr ws; to •••''•••• //i'/fo, o \- ro

3 *!>. V • SOHt/ACH 'rtBWC// ; 2

' . • • The Scarriff area The Tubberourry area

Figure ?. Distribution of the residences of plant employees among District Electoral Divisions 203

Table 33. Distribution of plant employees by distance of residence from plant

Tubbercurry Scarriff Distance (miles) Number Percent Number Percent

Under .4 91 58.3 67 44.7 4 and under 8 38 24.4 29 19.3 8 and under 12 14 9.0 44 29.4 12 and under l6 8 5.1 6 4.0. l6 and under 20 2 1.3 2 1.3 Subtotal 156 100.0 150 100.0 No information 1 1 Total 157 151

Mean distance from plant 4.31 miles 5.20 miles

Similarly more of the Tubbercurry employees than of the Scarriff employees resided between 4 and 8 miles from the plant. However, nearly 30 percent of the Scarriff employees resided between 8 and 12 miles from the plant, as compared to 9 percent of the Tubbercurry employees. The three other towns in the Scarriff AOI" mentioned earlier all fall in this range. Many of the plant employees who resided in these towns were former residents of these towns who had returned to these towns when employment became available at the new plant. For example, about half of-the plant employees who resided in %

'1 /"' J 'Tl Awmt"%A...../31 ..: 'WfÂôV 2 iCioo/iAcoot^ " " il ' ^ S -... \ :' / (ma tj riiCTî^^iM/' "cobt.«£4SV^l-v^*^'"'""' . ^ \c-* - : ji ({gcsât** &.A«4Ur-\iW»tmMCHV «.•! 5<.^ K/i/tAOTeie£ **•* • "% • • ^j/Bggseai' t lX) iJ' 1,7 1 ':. . .. ;" " • 13 A /' WMI04 Ik. S '••^•'V tsViuor i 'X. 1 N |7'nii(0i\ •.!•••. ,/ ''':•••! crnmV-'"^ o fr

V SOHHACn ;.1 n«fcuc/«u/fKimAGH ;• a%2, •) I w The Tubberourry area The Soarrlff• area

Figure 8. Distribution of the residences of new entrants, to the nonfarra labor force among District Electoral Divisions 205

KlHaloe and in Whitegate had returned from outside the area and had recommenced residence in their old home towns. In both areas, well over 90 percent of the employees resided within 12 miles of the new plants. The mean distance of residence from the plant was 4.31 miles for the Tubbercurry employees and 5.20 miles for the Scarriff employees. ,

2, New entrants to nonfarm labor force — " The distribution among DED*s of the new entrants to the nonfarm labor force in the two areas is shown in Tables 31 and 32. Similarly, this distribution is depicted in Figure 8. In the Tubbercurry AOI, the DED*s of Tubbercurry, Ogonnelloe and Lei trim contain 51 or 58 percent of the 88 new entrants to the nonfarm labor force who were residents of the AOI, while no other DED contained more than 5 such new entrants. The pro­ portion of the new entrants who were residents of those 3 DED*s (58 percent) is practically the same as the proportion of plant employees who resided in the same DED*s (60 percent), indicating.that the new entrants were spatially distributed relative to the new plant in approximately the same manner as - were the other plant employees. In the Scarriff AOI, 19 of the 45 new entrants to the nonfarm labor force who were residents of the AOI were resi­ dents of the Scarriff DED. This number amounted to 42.2 percent of the new entrants, and may be compared with the fact noted earlier that 42.3 percent of the Scarriff employees 206

resided in the Scarriff DED, Hence, it may be concluded that the geographical distribution of new entrants to the nonfarm labor force was similar to the distribution of all plant employees in both areas, the incidence being greatest in the DED*s in which the new plants were situated.

Employees who would have left to work elsewhere Tables 31 and 32 and Figure 9 show the distribution by DED of those employees who would not have remained to work in the AOI*s in the absence of the new plants. In the case of Tubbercurry plant, 4 of the 114 such employees resided outside of the AOI. Fifty or 45.5 percent of the 110 who resided within the AOI were residents of the Tubbercurry DED. This is slightly higher than the 42.5 percent of employees who resided in the Tubbercurry DED, The DSD*s of Tubbercurry, Banada and Leitrim accounted for 65 or 59.1 percent of the employees who would have left to seek work elsewhere, compared with the 60 percent of plant employees who resided within these DED s. These employees who would have gone to work elsewhere are •classified in Table 34 by distance of residence from the new plants. Nearly 60 percent of the Tubbercurry group resided within 4 miles of the plant, while about 45 percent of the Scarriff employees did so. In the Tubbercurry area the employment effect declined steadily as distance from Tubber­ curry increased. However, in Scarriff, 35 people or one third of those who would have left the AOI to seek work elsewhere in /:z% 11 > i,„ ;£££«£

;s^%k W {Cfp J

SONHACn

The Scarriff area The Tubberourry area

Pl^re 9. • Distribution of direct employment effect of the new plants among District Electoral Divisions 208

Table 34» Distribution of plant employees who would have left both areas in the absence, of the new plants by distance oi present residence from plant

Distance from plant Tubbercurry Scarriff (miles) Number Percent Number Percent

Under 6 66 57.9 46 44.7 4 and under 8 26 22.8 15 14.5 8 and under 12 10 8.8 35 34.0 12 and under 16 7 6.1 4 3.9 . l6 and under 20 2 1.8 1 1.0 20 and over 3 2.6 2 1.9 Total 114 100.0 103 100.0

the absence of the plant resided between 8 and 12 miles from the Scarriff plant. This number includes those former resi­ dents of Killaloe and Whitegate who had returned to those towns following the opening up of new emplosrment opportunities in the area. It also includes other residents of those towns who indicated that they would have left the area in the absence of the new plant because of the absence of suitable alternative employment opportunities in those towns. In a sense, there­ fore, those towns have been serving as dormitory towns for many of the Scarriff plant employees. 209

C, Alternative Employment Locations

All plant employees who had indicated that, in the absence of the new plants, they would have left the study areas in search of employment were asked to indicate where they would have gone in search of such employment. As shown in Table 35, over two thirds of the Tubbercurry employees who would not have remained to work in the AO! would have sought employment in England. This is a substantially higher proportion than the 45 percent of those from the Scarriff area who would have sought employment in England. Both areas are approximately the same distance from England, Yet, historically, there has been a substantially more pronounced pattern of emigration to England from the northwestern counties, such as Sligo, in which the Tubbercurry plant is situated, than from areas like East Clare,-in which Scarriff is situated. Exactly why these differential emigration patterns have developed historically is not clear. Part of the explanation may lie in the fact that the city of Limerick, containing over 50,000 people, is about 25 miles distant from Scarriff, in an adjoining county. No such city occurs in any of the counties adjoining County Sligo. As a result of this, it is seen that 15 percent of the Scarriff group would have sought employment in an adjoining county, while only 3.5 percent of the Tubber­ curry group would have done so. However, there are also other factors of importance in explaining the differential emigration Table 35. Places to which employees who would have left the two areas would have gone

Tubbercurrv Scarrlff Place Number Percent Number Percent

Same county (excluding Shannon) 5 4.4 3 3.1 Adjoining county 4 3.5 15 15.3

Other western county 2 1.8 ---- Dublin • 10 8.8 20 20.4 Rest of Ireland 3 2.6 Great Britain 77 67.5 44 44.9 United States of America 8 7.0 6 6.1

Shannon ' -- 9 9.2 Other (including further study or religious life) 5 4.4 1 1.0 Subtotal 114 100.0 98 100.0 No information regarding where employee would have gone 5

2 Would not have left the area 43 46

Total 157 151 211

have left would have gone to Dublin, while only 8.8 percent of the Tubbercurry group would have done so, even though both areas are about 120 miles from Dublin, About 10 per­ cent of the Scarriff employees would have gone to work at the Shannon Airport Industrial Estate. The proportion who would have come to the United States for employment was approximately the same in both areas. In summary, about three quarters of the Tubbercurry employees who would not have been at work in the AGI in the absence of the new plant would have sought employment outside Ireland, while about half of the corresponding Scarriff group would also have left Ireland in search of employment. 212

IX. POPULATION EFFECTS

In this chapter the residence association of plant employees with the two areas of impact is examined in Section A. The magnitude of migration into the areas following indus­ trialization is measured in Section B and finally, in Section C, the population effects of the new industrial plants on the two areas are estimated in terms of the levels of population which would currently exist in both areas in the absence of the new plants.

A. Residence Association with Areas of Impact

Plant employees are classified in Table 36 according to their residence association with the two areas. About three quarters of the Tubbercurry employees and two thirds of the Scarriff employees have resided within the two areas continu­ ously since 1956. Seven employees moved into the Tubbercurry AOI since 1956, but these moves were not associated with the taking of their present jobs. Similarly, 5 plant employees moved into the Scarriff AOI since 1956, but not in associa­ tion with obtaining employment at the new plant. Thus, 123 people or 78 percent of the Tubbercurry employees were local residents at the time they obtained plant employment and 10? or 71 percent of the Scarriff employees were residents of that AOI when they obtained plant employment. 213

Table 36. Distribution of plant employees by residence association with the areas of impact

Tubbercurry Scarriff Residence Association Number. Percent Number Percent

Lives in AOI and has done so since 195^ II6 73.9 102 67.5 Lives in AOI but has moved into AOI for first time since 1956, not associated with present job 4- 2.5 1.3 Lives in AOI, has moved. into AOI since 1956, not associated with present job, but formerly resided in AOI 3 1,9 2.0 Lives in AOI, but moved into AOI for first time since 1956, associated with près- 18 11.5 11 7.3 ent job Lives in AOI, has moved into AOI since 1956, associated with present job, but former­ ly resided in AOI. 12 7.7 19 12.6 Lives outside AOI, but lived in AOI at some stage since 1956 8.0 Lives outside AOI and has done so since 1956 4 2.5 12 8.0 Total 157 100.0 151 100.0 214

In Tubbercurry, 18 plant employees moved residence into the AOI for the first time in association with obtaining plant employment, while 12 other employees moved residence into the AOI in association with obtaining plant employment, but had resided in the AOI during some former period. Eleven of the Scarriff employees moved residence into that AOI for the first time associated with obtaining jobs at the new plant, while 19 former residents of the AOI moved residence back to the AOI in association with obtaining employment at the new plant. Thus, in each AOI, 30 plant employees moved residence into the AOI in association with their new plant employment. Four Tubbercurry employees currently reside outside the AOI, while 14 Scarriff employees reside outside the AOI. As discussed earlier, 9 of the latter reside in Ballina, County Tipperary, which is connected to Killaloe by a bridge across the Shannon, while 4 more reside elsewhere in Tipperary, being also excluded, by definition, from the AOI.

B. Migration into Areas of Impact

As noted in the previous section, 30 employees moved residence into each AOI in association with their plant employ­ ment. The population impact of these residence changes is examined in this section. Twenty of the 30 employees who moved residence into the Tubbercurry AOI were heads of 215 households, while 25 of the 30 who moved into the Scarriff AOI were heads of households. Since a migration of heads of households into both areas occurred, the increase in population which resulted was greater than the number of employees who migrated into the AOI*s. As shown in Table 37. the migration of heads of households into the Tubbercurry AOI resulted in an increase of 63 persons in the population of the area, that of the 10 nonheads resulting in an increase of a further 10, thus giving an increase of 73 persons as a result of migration into the Tubbercurry AGI in association with the obtaining of plant employment by these 30 employees.

Table 37. Distribution,of people who migrated into areas of impact in association with heads of households obtaining plant employment by size of household together with number of migrating employees who were nonheads of households

Size of household Tubbercurry Scarriff (persons) Households People Households People

1 7 7 4 4 2 1 2 1 2 2 6 7 21 i 5 20 6 24 2 10 2 10 i 3 18 3 18 7 8 1 8 9 1 Subtotal 20 63 25 96 Nonheads of households 10 • 5 Total 73 101 216

Similarly in Scarriff, migration of 25 heads of house­ holds into the AOI gave rise to an increase of 96 persons, while there were 5 nonheads of households who migrated to the AOI giving an increase of 101 persons in the AOI as a result of migration of these 30 plant employees to the AOI in asso­ ciation with obtaining employment at the new plant. The geographical incidence of this increase was also examined. As hypothesized, a-large proportion of these increases occurred in an around Tubbercurry and Scarriff. In fact, 5^ persons or 74 percent of the 73 people involved in the migra­ tion into the Tubbercurry. AOI were residing in the Tubbercurry DED when interviewed, while none of the other 32 DED * s in the Tubbercurry AOI had received more than an increase of 6. In the Scarriff AOI,' 49 persons or 48,5 percent of the increase of 101 people were residing in Killaloe DSD and 12 or 11,9 percent in Drummaan DED, These 3 DED*s contain the towns of Scarriff, Killaloe and Whitegate, respectively. The remaining 16 people were residents of 4 other DSD's (one household per DED), It is thus seen that a greater proportion of the migration into the AOI associated with plant employment was concentrated in and close to the town where the plant was located in the Tubbercurry AOI than in the Scarriff AOI, where some of the migrants to the AOI settled in other towns within the area. Practically all of the migration into the towns of Killaloe and Whitegate was associated with the return to these 217 toims of former residents who had left these towns at an earlier stage but returned to their old home towns when employ­ ment became available at the Scarriff plant,

C, Population in the Absence of the New Plants

As noted in the previous chapter, a large proportion of the employees of both plants said that they would not have remained to work in the AOI for the alternative earnings which they felt they could have obtained locally, if the new plants had not been established. These employees are classified in Table 38 on the basis of whether or not they are heads of households or other house­ hold members residing within the two areas. One hundred and ten such employees currently reside within the Tubbercurry AOI and 92 within the Scarriff AOI. One third of the former and one half of the latter are heads of households. It was assumed that when a head of household would move residence from the AOI, the other members of his household would also move, though there might be some lags present in this connec­ tion. Table 39- shows the direct population reduction which would occur if these households migrated from the two areas, along with the reduction involved as a result of the migration of plant employees who were nonheads of households. Migration of 37 household heads from the Tubbercurry area would have 218

Table 38. Distribution of plant employees who would not have remained in the areas of impact for the alternative local earnings expected in the absence of the new plants by status within their households

Tubbercurry Scarriff Household Status Number Percent Number Percent

Head of household residing in AOI 37 33.6 46 50.0 Other household member residing in AOI 73 66.4 46 50.0 Subtotal 110 100.0 92 100.0 Reside outside AOI 4 • 11 Total 114 103

Table 39. Distribution of households and people who would not be residents of the areas of impact if indus;- trialization had not occurred classified by household size

Tubbercurry Scarriff Household size Households People Households People

1 7 7 7 7 2 8 16 3 6 3 5 15 8 24 4 7 28 8 32 5 5 25 8 40 6 3 18 5 30 7 1 7 3 21 8 9 1 9 2 18 10 2 20 Subtotal 37 125 46 198 Nonheads of households 73 46 Total 198 244 219 resulted in a population reduction of 125 persons, while that of plant employees who were nonheads of households would have reduced population "by a further 73 persons, giving a total population reduction of 198 people. In the Scarriff AOI, a population loss of 198 persons would have resulted from migration.of the 46 heads of house­ holds and a further loss of 46 from migration of plant employees who are nonheads of households. Thus the Scarriff area would have experienced a population loss of 244 people. Assuming that the population effect of plant employment was similar in the case of the plant employees who were not interviewed, one may estimate the direct population effects of industrialization in the two areas as an increase of 231 in the population of the Tubbercurry AOI and an increase of 318 in the population of the Scarriff AOI. These increases have been measured relative to the level at which it was estimated that the population of these two areas would be in 1966 in the absence of the new industrial plants. It must be borne in mind that these estimates represent, the direct effect of plant employment on population levels in these two areas. The total population effect may be expected to be greater for a number of reasons. First of all, the study dealt only with employees up through the rank of working foreman. As most of the plant management personnel had come from outside the two areas, it may be expected that . 220 they and their families would not have been currently residing in the areas had not the plants been established. Secondly, indirect employment effects may be expected to have occurred. These may, in turn, be expected to have given rise to indirect population effects. For example, some proprietors of small businesses in the two areas might have been able to stay in business after the plants had been located in these areas, whereas otherwise they might have been forced out of business as a result of the lower population which would have other­ wise been in- the areas. These people might have then been obliged to leave the areas in search of employment. . The direct population effect of the new industrialization was estimated to be greater in the Scarriff area than in the Tubbercurry area during the period under study. This reflects the fact that relatively more heads of households obtained employment in the Scarriff plant than in Tubbercurry. It is, thus, estimated that instead of its actual level of 16,793, the 1966 population of the Tubbercurry AOI would have been not more than 16,562 in the absence of the industrialization. Similarly, it is estimated that in the absence of the Scarriff industrial plant, the 1966 population of the Scarriff AOI would have been not more than 7,2^4, instead of the actual 1966 population of 7,572. 221

•D. Spatial Incidence of Population Effects

In order to examine the spatial incidence within the two areas of the direct population effects of industrialization, the direct population effect generated by the plant employment of those employees who were interviewed was distributed among DED' s in the two areas as shown in Tables 40 and 4l and as depicted in Figure 10, In Tables 40 and 4l, this direct popu­ lation effect is shown as a proportion of the actual 1966 population of each DED, In the Tubbercufry area, the direct population effect of the plant employment of the interviewees amounted to 1,18 per­ cent of the 1966 population of the area. However, if one con­ siders the DED*s in the Rural District of Tubbercurry, this effect amounted to 1.97 percent of the population of the Sural District. Both in terms of absolute numbers and as a propor- ' tion of the 1966 population, the direct population effect on the Tubbercurry DED was higher than on any other DED within the area, being 98 persons or 5.^1 percent of the I966 popu­ lation. Thus, half of the population effect of the Tubbercurry industrial development was concentrated in the Tubbercurry DED, The DED* s of Lei trim and Achonry West had the next highest numbers of people involved,-15 and 12 respectively. In the Scarriff area, the direct population-effect result­ ing from the plant employment of those employees who were interviewed amounted to 3.22 percent of the I966 population.of 222

Table 40. Distribution of direct population effect of industrialization among DED's in the Tubbercurry area .

Actual 1966 Population effect of industry jjgjj population Estimated Percent of 1966 number population

Cùilmore .765 - Kilfree 492 — — —— — Kilshalvey 469 3 0.69 Ballymote 1,403 3 0.21 Carrickbanagher 577 2 0.35 Achonry E. 640 3 0.47 Achonry W. 927 12 1.29 Aclare 416 1 0.24 Banada 869 6 0.69 Breencoragh 221 - —— —— Kilmactaigue 270 - Annagh 259 - —— — — Branchfield 102 4 3.92 Carrownaskeagh 159 - Cartron 250 - —— — — Coolaney 342 8 2.34

Loughill 86 -• Temple . 256 • 7 2.73 Owemnore 231 1 0.43 Cloonacool .272 6 2.21 Cloonoghill 359 6 1.67 Glendarragh 247 5 2.02 Kilturra 260 1 0.38 Leitrim 466 15 , 3.28 Streamstown 381 1 0.26 Tubbercurry 1,812 98 5.41 Cloonmore 692 4 0.58 Doocastle 678 7 1.03 Kilbeagh 1,120 • 1 0.09 Sonnagh . 1,184 4 0.34

Tungesh 588 • "•

Total 16,793 198 1.18 223

Table 41. Distribution, of direct population effect of industrialization among DED's in the Scarriff area

Actual 1966 Population effect of industry DED population Estimated Percent of 1966 number population.

Fahymore 261 - ——

Killokennedy 164 • — — Kilseily 442 15 3.39 Lackareagh 105 - —— Caherhurley 147 - —— Carrowbaun 55 1 1.81 Killaloe 1,027 40 3.89 Ogonnelloe 399 10 2.51 Ayle 230 2 0.87 Boherglass 200 6 3.00 Cahermurphy 92 1 1.09 Cloonusker 235 2 0.85 Coolreagh 246 - — —— — Corlea .145 10 6.90 Derrynagittagh 155 - — — Feakle 385 12 3.12 Cappaghbaun 158 . 12 7.59 Drummaan 503 23 4.57 Iniscaltra N. 151 2 1.32

Iniscaltra S. 45 - — —— Mbuntshannon, 259 8 3.09 Scarriff 1,110 99 8.92 Ballinahinch 343 - — —— Glandree 190 - • —— —— Killaneena 354 1 0.28 Loughea 171 -

Total 7,572 244 3.22 10.../ LOVGHil l'|. to^snV' ââtjk 2 1' 'XipO//ACOOl • •• TfU>i rv m.) \ 6 : f.t'jte

\A i/ „ - ar.\ A*. o'ioxtaiot 10 il :" 6 k^-'i v\ f .3*^ ;V**'' .;•'««Cwwr ^^'"v ^ y\ •••^•••- kn •••.. ***-• X KUliLOi (\) % V •' J V^- ..xoocAsnrl tr-xume'^f fjiA/tutt!0»e-....>^ I Y • SOHUAOH ;. fllSaOH ; J^,

The Soarà?lff area The Tuhberourry area

Figure 10,. . Distribution of direct population effect of the new plants among District Electoral. Divisions. 225 the area. Within the DED*s contained in the Scarriff Rural

District, it amounted to 4.11 percent. Once again, both in absolute numbers and as a proportion of the I966 population thé direct population effect on the Scarriff DSD was higher • than on any other DED within the area, being 99 persons or 8.92 percent of the I966 population, . The population effect on the Scarriff DED was slightly over percent of the population effect on the whole area. About one sixth of the effect was on the Killaloe DED and about 10 percent on the Drummaan DED, This evidence, particularly that in the Tubberc.urry area, supports the hypotheses that the population effect of indus­ trialization would be strongest in and close to the towns wherein the new plants were situated. However, in the Scarriff area, concentrations of the population effect in DED*s containing other towns were greater than in the Tubbercurry area. It is also of interest to examine the direct population effect of plant emplosnnent on the towns within the two areas. In the Tubbercurry area, the population effect on towns was 92 persons or 46.5 percent of the total, while in the Scarriff area it was 125 persons or 51.2 percent of the total. Table 42 shows the population effect on each, town of, the employment of those persons who were interviewed at the . plants. The bulk of the urban population effect in each area 226 Table 42. Distribution of direct population effect of industrialization among towns

Population Effect of Industry Actual 1966 Estimated Percent of Population Number 1966 Population

Tubbercurry Area 1 Ballymote 921 3 0.33 Charlestown- Bellaghy 680 5 0.73 Coôlaney 117 7 5.98 Tubbercurry 937 77 8.22 Scarriff Area

Broadford 158 5 3.16 Killaloe 816 21 2.57 Peakle 121 4 3.31 Whitegate 169 8 4.73 Mountshannon. 149 8 5.37 Scarriff 673 79 11.74

was on the two towns wherein the new plants were situated. It is estimated that in the absence of the new plants the popu­ lation of Tubbercurry would have been at least 8.22 percent less than its 1966 level of 937, while that of Scarriff would have been at least 11.74 percent less than its I966 population of 673 persons. The population effects, reported in Table 42 refer only to those employees who were interviewed. Hence, the 227 full magnitude of the direct effect attributable to all employees would be greater. Furthermore, the direct popu­ lation effect due to the management personnel of the new plants would have been concentrated in Scarriff and Tubbercurry. In addition, it is reasonable to expect that important indirect population effects had also occurred to a greater extent in the towns of Scarriff and Tubbercurry than elsewhere in the two areas. 228

X. INCOME EFFECTS

The direct income effects of plant employment are examined in this chapter, which contains four sections. Sec­ tion A contains a descriptive analysis of the present earnings of plant employees. The alternative local earnings expected by plant employees in the absence of the new plants are dis­ cussed in Section B, while Section C contains an analysis of the alternative earnings expected elsewhere by plant employees who would have sought work outside the two areas had not the new plants been located in those areas. A comparison between these earnings expected elsewhere and the present plant earn­ ings of the employees who would have left the two areas pro­ vides information regarding the importance of any nonincome considerations prompting these employees to remain in the two areas. Finally, in Section D, the amount and spatial inci­ dence of net increments to household income arising directly from industrial employment are examined,

A, Present Earnings of Plant Employees

The distribution of plant employees by their present weekly plant earnings is shown in Table 43. Certain differences are immediately apparent. The distribution of weekly earn­ ings of the Tubbercurry plant employees exhibits a considerably larger variability than does the distribution of weekly Table 43. Distribution of plant employees by weekly plant earnings

Tubbercurry Scarriff Weekly earnings (,£) Number Percent Number Percent

Under 4 25 15.9 1 0.7 4 and under 8 54 34.6 11 7.3 8 and under 12 29 18.5 95 63.4 12 and under 16 16 10.2 20 13.3 16 and under 20 9 5.7 16 10.7 20 and under 24 17 10.8 5 3.3 24 and under 28 4 2.5 2 1.3

28 and under 32 3 1.9 ------

Subtotal 157 100.0 150 100.0

No information -- 2

Total 157 151

Mean weekly earnings {£) 10.0 11.3 Median weekly earnings 06) 7.9 10.5 Modal weekly earnings {£) 5 and under 6 10 and under 11 230 earnings of the Scarriff employees. Nearly two thirds of the Scarriff employees receive wages in the ^8 to^12 cate­ gory, while the greatest proportion of Tubberciirry employees in any wage category is slightly over one third in the to ,£8 category. This greater variability of wages among the Tubbercurry employees is largely explained by the lower occupational homogeneity of the Tubbercurry employees and by sex differen­ tials in wages. For example, about l6 percent of the Tubber­ curry employees had weekly earnings of less than ^4, as compared with less than 1 percent of the employees in Scarriff. This reflects the larger number of apprentices hired in Tubber­ curry. Similarly, over 15 percent of the Tubbercurry employees received weekly wages of over «^20, compared Tilth 4.6 percent of the Scarriff employees, reflecting the larger number of skilled plant employees who were working in Tubbercurry. The presence of 35 percent.of the Tubbercurry employees in the to category, as opposed to 7 percent in Scarriff is largely explained by the larger number of female plant em­ ployees in Tubbercurry. The mean weekly wage of plant employees interviewed was /11.3 in Scarriff and £10.0 in Tubbercurry. The median. weekly wage was /10,5 In Scarriff and 7.9 in Tubbercurry, The modal weekly wage was between ^10 and «^11 in Scarriff and between jf5 and ^6 in Tubbercurry, Thus, mean, median, and 231

modal weekly wages were higher in the case of the Scarriff employees than those of the Tubbercurry employees. •Mean weekly earnings of the Tubbercurry employees classi­ fied by farm work association and by sex are shown in Table 44". For convenience in the tabular presentation, in Table 44 and in all subsequent tables in which the farm work association of plant employees in either area is depicted, symbols are used to denote the various farm work association categories. The symbol PO stands for "farm operator"; FW stands for "nonopera- tor farm worker" ; NFWA stands for "no farm work association", Plant employees are classified on the basis of their farm work association at the time of obtaining plant employment and at the present time. Various combinations of the three symbols will be used to denote the nine possible combinations of farm work association. Thus, for example, FO-FO means "farm opera­ tor at the time of obtaining plant employment and is farm operator now", FW-NFWA means "nonoperator farm worker at the time of obtaining plant employment and has no farm work association now". Other combinations are formed in like manner. Because of the possibility of disclosure of financial data pertaining to individual plant employees, such data are —not presented separately in Table 44 or in subsequent similar tables for farm work association groups which contain only one or a few employees. However, data pertaining to. such employees are included in the totals shown for the two areas. Table 44. Mean weekly plant earnings (4.) of Tubbercurry plant employees classified by farm work association and by sex

Sex Farm work association* Male Female Total

FO - FO 11.9 (n = 15) 11.9 (n = 15)

FW - FW 7.4 (n = 30) 5.2 (n = 16) 6.6 (n = 46)

FW - NFWA 12.3 (n « 14) 5.4 (n = 4) 10.7 (n = 18)

NFWA - NFWA 13.2 (n = 53) 5.9 (n = 20) 11.2 (n « 73)

Total 11.6 (n = 116) 5.6 (n = 41) 10.0 (n = 157)

®An explanation of the farm work association symbols appears on p. 231 233

In all categories of farm work association, plant wages of female employees in Tubbercurry were substantially lower than those of male employees. The mean weekly wage of male employees was ^11,6 while that of female employees was less than half of that received by male employees. There was extremely little variability in the wages of female employees according to farm work association. The mean weekly wage of the 15 male farm operators who did not change their farm work association was 11.9, as compared with a mean weekly wage of jfl3.2 for the 53 male employees who had no farm work association at any stage. . Mean wages of farm operators were higher than those of male nonoperator farm workers who did not change their nonfarm work status following plant employment, while mean wages of nonoperator farm workers who severed their farm work associa­ tion were slightly higher than those of the farm operators. However, all these groups had mean weekly wages which were lower than those of the group who had no farm work associa­ tion. Similar data in respect of the Scarriff employees is presented in Table 45. The mean weekly wage of the 1? male farm operators who did not change their farm work association either at the time of their plant emplosrment or subsequently. As in Tubbercurry, wages of nonoperator farm workers who retained their farm work status were lower than those of Table 45. Mean weekly plant earnings (^) of Scarriff plant employees classified by farm work association and by sex

Sex Farm work association^ Male Female Total

FO - FO 10.9 (n = 17) -- 10.9 (n = 17)

FW - FW 9.7 (n = 28) 7.3 (n = 3) 9.5 (n = 31)

F17 - NFWA 10.7 (n = 11) b 10.4 (n = 12)

NFWA - NFWA 12.4 (n = 81) 7.6 (n = 5) 12.1 (n = 86)

Total 11.5 (n = 141) 7.5 (n = 9) 11.3 (n = 150)

^An explanation of the farm work association symbols appears on p. 231

^This cell contains only one employee 235 the farm operators, "but wages of nonoperator farm workers who severed their farm work association were about the same as those of the farm operators. However, the wages of all three groups were below those of the employees who had no farm work association. As in the case of the Tubbercurry employees, mean weekly wages of female plant employees Ç47.5) were below those of male plant employees (^11,5). Once again, there was hardly any variation in mean wages of female plant employees accord­ ing to farm work association. In comparing the mean weekly wages of plant employees in the two areas, it is seen that the mean wage of farm operators in Tubbercurry («611.9) was 1 higher than that of the farm operators in the Scarriff plant. Similarly, mean wages of male employees in Tubbercurry who had no farm work association («afl3.2) were about ^1 higher than the wages of the Scarriff employees who had no farm work association (<£12.4). Thus, the differential between the wages of farm operators employed at the plants and the wages of male plant employees who had no farm work association was approximately the same in both areas. Mean wages paid to female employees in Tubbercurry were, substantially below the mean wages paid to female employees in the Scarriff plant. This difference is mainly due to the fact that female employees in Scarriff were almost all engaged in clerical or secretarial positions, while most of 236 those in Tubbercurry were production workers, Wages paid to female employees in clerical and secretarial positions are usually larger in Ireland than wages paid to female plant pro­ duction workers." Wages paid to female clerical and secre­ tarial workers in Tubbercurry were similar to those paid to the female clerical and secretarial employees in Scarriff.

B, Alternative Local Earnings

Each of the plant employees was asked to estimate the alternative weekly earnings which he could currently obtain locally if the new plant were not in the area. Plant employees are distributed in Table 46 according to their estimates of alternative local weekly earnings in the absence of the new plants. In both areas, practically the same proportion of employees (48.4 percent in Tubbercurry and 47.7 percent in Scarriff) felt that in the absence of the plants they would not be able to earn anything locally. Among those who felt they could obtain positive earnings locally, the Tubbercurry employees tended to give lower esti­ mates of the alternative earnings which they could obtain than did the Scarriff employees. The mean, alternative local earn­ ings estimated by the Scarriff employees was ««f4.0, while that of the Tubbercurry employees was afZ.S, about «f1 less. Simi­ larly, the median alternative local earnings expected by the Scarriff employees was /3«25, while-that expected by the Table 46. Distribution of plant employees by estimated alternative local weekly earnings in the absence of the plant \

Tubbercurry Scarriff Estimated alternative local weekly earnings

Zero 76 48.4 71 47.7 Under 4 28 17.8 7 4.7 4 and under 8 37 23.6 33 22.1 8 and under 12 11 7.0 31 20.8 12 and over 5 3.2 7 4.7 to V) -Nj Subtotal . 157 100.0 149 100.0 A) No information 2 V) 00

Total 157 151

Mean alternative earnings (£) 2.90 4.00 Median alternative earnings (£) 2.20 3.25 Modal alternative earnings (f) 0.00 0.00 239

Tubbercurry employees was 2.20, Mean alternative local earnings are shown in Table 4-7 for the Tubbercurry plant employees, classified by farm association and by sex. The 15 farm operators who did not change their farm work association expected mean alternative local weekly earnings of about 1 more than that expected by the 53 male plant employees who had no farm work associa­ tion at any stage. Alternative earnings expected by the farm operators were higher than those expected by male plant employees who were nonoperator farm workers at the time they obtained plant employment. The mean alternative weekly earnings expected by male plant employees (d^3.0) was higher than that expected by female plant employees («^2.5), though the female plant em­ ployees exhibited more variability according to farm associa­ tion in their expectations than appeared in their present earnings. • Corresponding data pertaining to the Scarriff employees are presented in Table 48, Farm operators expected higher mean alternative weekly earnings («^5.6) than did the male employees who had no farm work association (ôf3.9). As in the case of Tubbercurry, the mean alternative local weekly earn­ ings expected by farm operators were higher than were expec­ ted by plant employees who were nonoperator farm workers when they obtained plant employment. Table 47. Mean alternative local weekly earnings (JE) expected in the absence of the new plant by Tubbercurry plant employees classified by farm work association and by sex

Sex Farm work association* Male Female Total

FO - FO 3.8 (n = 15) MM 3.8 (n = 15)

FW - FW 2.6 (n = 30) 3.0 (n = 16) 2.7 (n = 46)

FW - NFWA 3.6 (n = 14) 3.9 (n = 4) 3.7 (n = 18)

NFWA - NFWA 2.9 (n = 53) 1.8 (n = 20) 2.6 (n = 73)

Total 3.0 (n = 116) 2.5 (n = 41) 2.9 (n = 117)

®An explanation of the farm work association symbols appears on p. 231 Table 48. Mean alternative local weekly earnings CO expected in the absence of the new plant by Scarriff plant employees classified by farm work association and by sex

Sex Farm work association Male Female Total

FO -FO 5.6 (n = 17) #* M* 5.6 (n = 17)

FW - FW 4.5 (n = 28) 4.7 (n = 3) 4.4 (n = 31)

FW - NFWA 1.6 (n = 11) b 1.5 (n = 12)

NFWA - NFWA 3.9 (n = 80) 2.1

Total 4.1 (n = 140) 2.7 (n = 9) . 4.0 (n = 149)

®An explanation of the farm work association symbols appears on p. 231

This8 cell contains only one employee 242

Female plant employees in Scarriff expected lower alter­ native earnings than did male plant employees, though they also exhibited more variability by farm work association in their expectations than occurred in their present earnings. In comparing the two areas in this respect, it is inter­ esting to note that the mean alternative earnings expected by male plant employees who had no farm worJc association at any time in Scarriff was«£l higher than that of the corresponding employees in Tubbercurry. Similarly, farm operators in Scarriff expected higher alternative local earnings than did their Tubbercurry counterparts. This is in contrast with the current situation of those two groups, who, as noted earlier, are currently receiving higher wages in Tubbercurry than in Scarriff. It is possible, therefore, to infer that industrialization has had relatively greater effect on income earning opportunities in the Tubber­ curry area than in the Scarriff area in terms of differences between male plant employees * actual present wages and their expectations of alternative local earnings in the absence of the new plants. In the case of female plant employees, there was little difference between the expected local alternative earnings in the two areas. Female employees in Tubbercurry had a mean expectation of^2,5, while those in Scarriff had a mean expectation of .6 2.7. 2^3

Finally, it is of interest to note that 10 of the Tubbercurry employees (6.3 percent) felt that they could earn more locally in the absence of the plant than what they were currently receiving. Most of these were apprentices who were currently accepting lower wages during their apprenticeship than what they could have earned had they not become apprentices. A further 11 employees felt that in the absence of the plant they could earn the same as they were currently receiving, but the vast majority, I36 (or 86,6 percent) felt that"they could earn less in the local area than they were currently earning at the new plant. Five of the Scarriff employees felt that they would be earning more in the AOI in the absence of the plant than the amount which they were currently receiving. One of these was an apprentice. The other 4 employees said that in the absence of the plant they would have been working at higher paying jobs in the area. However, these alternative jobs would have involved working harder or else working out of doors under unfavorable climatic conditions. Hence, these employees, because of the nature of the employment which they were offered at the plant, accepted lower wages in the plant than the wages which they would be receiving in the jobs which they would have had to accept, had not the plant been in Scarriff. Seven of the Scarriff employees felt that they could earn the same wages in the area in the absence of the plant. However, 92 percent 24^

of those interviewed felt that in the absence of the plant, their alternative earnings in the Scarriff area would have been less than the amount currently being earned at the plant,

C. Alternative Earnings Elsewhere

All plant employees who indicated that they would not have remained at work or come to work in the two areas were asked to estimate the weekly earnings which they felt they would have been obtaining currently in the places to which they would have gone for employment. Table 4-9 shows the dis­ tribution of these employees by their estimated alternative earnings elsewhere. Seventy-one percent of the Tubbercurry employees who would have gone to work elsewhere felt that they would have earned «iél2 or more per week in their new locations, while 77 percent of those Scarriff employees who would have gone to work elsewhere felt they would have been earning ^12 or more per week. However, more Tubbercurry employees felt they could have earnedcf20 or over elsewhere, 46 percent as against 38 percent of the Scarriff employees who would have gone else­ where. Thus, more of the Scarriff employees who would have gone elsewhere had earnings expectations between 2 and <£20. This fact is largely explained by skill differences among the two groups of employees and the fact that more of the employees Table 49o Distribution of plant employees who would have left the areas by expected alternative earnings elsewhere

Tubbercurrv Scarriff Weekly earnings (£) expected elsewhere Number Percent Number Percent

Under 4 6 5.8 2 2.1

4 and under 8 9 8.7 5 5.2

8 and under 12 15 14.4 15 15.6

12 and under 16 15 14.4 25 26.0

16 and under 20 11 10.6 12 12.5

20 and under 24 18 17.3 16 16.7

24 and under 28 18 17.3 . 11 11.5 \ 28 and over 12 11,5 10 10.4

Subtotal 104 100.0- V, 96 100.0

No information 10 7

Other employees 43 48

Total 157 151 246 who would have left the Tubbercurry area would have gone to England, where they would have obtained higher wages than in Ireland. The mean alternative earnings expected elsewhere by plant employees who would have gone to work elsewhere are shown for the two areas in Tables 50 and 51» classified by farm work association and by sex. The mean weekly earnings expected elsewhere by Tubbercurry employees («£18,2) was about/I higher than the mean expected by Scarriff employees C£17,3). Both male and female plant employees who would have left the Tubbercurry area had higher earnings expectations . elsewhere than had the Scarriff employees, the differences • being about^2 for male employees and about for female employees, The most striking difference between the two areas is the fact that farm operators who would have left the Tubbercurry area had a mean weekly earnings expectation of «628,4, the highest for any farm association group in Tubbercurry, while farm operators who would have left the Scarriff area had a mean weekly earnings expectation of^13,2, the lowest for any farm work association group in that area. Two possible expla­ nations of this difference may be noted. Firstly, farm operators employed at the new plants had differing educational levels in the two areas. The mean number of years of post­ primary education received by farm operator plant employees Table 50, Mean alternative weekly earnings (,C) expected elsewhere by Tubbercurry plant employees who would have gone to work elsewhere classified by farm work association and by sex

Sex Farm work association^ Male Female Total

• FO -FO 28.4 (n « 8) — 28.4 (n SS 8)

FW - FW 18.4 (n = 19) 8.3 (n « 8) 15.4 (n 27)

FW - NFWA 15.7 (n = 5) b 14.7 (n S3 6)

NFWA - NFWA 20.1 (n = 46) 10.5 (n = 13) 18.0 (n 59)

Total 20.4 (n = 82) 9.7 (n = 22) 18.2 (n 104)

®An explanation of the farm work association symbols appears on p. 231

This cell contains only one employee Table 51. Mean alternative weekly earnings ÇE) expected elsewhere by Scarriff plant employees who would have gone to work elsewhere classified by farm work association and by sex

Sex Farm work association^ Male Female Total

FO - FO 13.2 ( n = 5) 1 M 13.2 (n = 5)

FW - FW 20.4 (n = 14) 9.0 (n = 2) 18.9 (n = 16)

FW - NFWA 17.2 (n = 10) b 17.2 (h = 11)

NFWA - NFWA 18.5 (n = 59) 8.7 (n = 5) 17.7 (n = 64)

Total 18.3 (n = 91) 8.8 (n = 8) 17.3 (n = 99)

^An explanation of. the farm work association symbols appears on p, 231

b This cell contains only one employee 24-9 in Tubloercurry was 1.4? years, while that of their Scarriff coimterparts was 0.30 years. Secondly, three fourths of the Tubbercurry farm operator plant employees who would have left the area would have gone to England, whereas none of those who would have left the Scarriff area indicated that he would have gone farther afield than to an adjoining county. It is now possible to construct a measure of the non- income considerations which entered into the decision of those people, who would have sought employment elsewhere in the absence of the new plants, to accept employment at those plants rather than to seek employment elsewhere. Such a mea­ sure may be constructed by comparing, for this group of people, their expected earnings elsewhere with their actual current earnings at the new plants. It matters not that these earnings expectations might not have been realized elsewhere. In fact, whether or not the expectations are realistic is irrelevant in the present con­ text. The important consideration is that each of these indi­ viduals may be presumed to have compared this expectation with his current earnings at local industrial emplosrment an, on the basis of such a comparison, decided to remain at work in the local plant. The difference between that expectation and his current plant earnings, may, then be used as a measure of the importance of whatever nonincome considerations entered into his decision to work at the local industrial plant. 250

Tables 52 and 53 show, for the two areas, the mean dif­ ference between expected weekly earnings elsewhere a:nd pre­ sent earnings at the new plant for plant employees who would have left these areas in the absence of the new plants, classified by farm work association and by sez. As noted in Table 52, the 104 Tubberciirry plant employees who indicated that they would have gone to work elsewhere in the absence of the new plants at Tubbercoirry were currently receiving a mean of7.1 less per week than the alternative earnings which they felt they would have been obtaining had they gone elsewhere. The corresponding figure for the 103 Scarriff employees who would have gone to work elsewhere was ^6, as shown in Table 53. It may, thus be argued that other considerations besides the income available from plant employ­ ment and the alternative income available elsewhere entered into the decision-making process employed by those individuals in deciding to accept employment at the new plants. A mean difference of was reported by farm operators in Tubbercurry, This may be compared with a mean difference of 06IO.3 reported by the male nonoperator farm worker group who did not change their farm work association. However, those male nonoperator farm workers in Tubbercurry who ceased to have a farm work association reported no difference. Male plant employees who had no farm work association reported a difference of^7.8 per week. Table 52. Mean difference between present weekly earnings and alternative weekly earnings (of) expected elsewhere by Tubbercurry plant employees who would have gone to work elsewhere classified by farm work association and by sex

Sex Farm work association Male Female Total

FO - FO 16.4 (n = 8) M M 16.4 II

FW - FW 10.3 (n = 19) 3.0 (n = 8) 8.2 (n = 27)

FW - NFWA -0.2 (n = 5) c 0.6 (n = 6)

NFWA - NFWA 7.1 (n = 46) 4.5 (n = 13) 6.6 (n = 59) 0 0 Total (n = 82) 3.9 (n = 22) 7.1 (n = 104)

^Difference is expressed as (alternative earnings - present earnings)

^An explanation of the farm work association symbols appeals on po 231

^This cell contains only one employee Table 53. Mean difference between present weekly earnings and alternative weekly earnings Cj6) expected elsewhere by Scarriff plant employees who would have gone to work elsewhere classified by farm work association and by sex

Sex Farm work association Male Female Total

FO - FO 3.0 (n = 5) -- 3.0 (n = 5)

FW - FW 10.7 (n = 14) 1.8 (n = 2) 9.5 (n = 16)

FW - NFWA 6.4 (n = 10) : c 6.4 (n = 11)

NFWA - NFWA 4.2 (n = 59) 1.1 (n = 5) 4.0 (n = 64)

Total .6.6 (n = 91) 1.3 (n = 7) 6.0 (n = 98)

^Difference is expressed as (alternative earnings - present earnings) b : An explanation of the farm work association symbols appears on p. 231

c' This cell contains only one employee 253

It is to be expected that farm income considerations would be of importance to farm operators. Family farm income of those operators with plant employment in the Tubbercurry area was ^3.8 per week, so if allowance is made for this item, the difference occurring in the case of the Tubbercurry farm opera­ tor plant employees becomes12,6, about 2 higher than that reported by the male nonoperator farm -workers. Both groups reported a greater difference than did those employees who had no farm work association, indicating that those employees who had farming associations were prepared to make a greater income sacrifice in order to work in the Tubbercurry plant than were the employees who did not have any farming associa­ tion. In Scarriff, however, the farm operators employed at the plant reported a mean difference of ^1^3» the smallest for any farm work association group. It will be recollected that these people had relatively low expectations regarding the alternative incomes which they would have been receiving else­ where had they left the Scarriff AOI. When one bears in mind that the mean family farm income for this group was 5.9 per week, it is seen that farm operator plant employees in Scarriff did not feel that they could have obtained as high an income elsewhere as their present combined incomes from farming and plant employment. It was noted earlier that farm operator plant employees in Scarriff had relatively low expectations 254 regarding their income earning ability elsewhere. As was noted in the case of Tubhercurry, the male Scarriff plant employees who were nonoperator farm workers and who did not subsequently change their farm work association reported a mean difference of^flO.? per week, while those male employ­ ees with no farm work association reported a mean difference of«f4.2 per week. Thus, in both areas, nonoperator farm workers reported a greater mean difference between their pre­ sent plant earnings and the amount they felt they could earn had they gone to work elsewhere. Farm operator plant employees in Tubbercurry reported an even greater difference (after allow­ ing for farm income) between present earnings and expected alternative earnings elsewhere.

D. Household Income Effects

All plant employees were asked whether their plant employ­ ment had given rise to an increase in their net household in­ come, that is, after allowing for any costs which might have been involved in their present employment. As shown in Table 54, 81 percent of the Tubbercurry employees and 74 percent of the Scarriff employees reported a net increase in household income as a result of obtaining employment at the new plants. Practically all of those reporting no increase had returned from abroad, for family or other reasons, to work in the plant. Others had been employed at different jobs prior to obtaining Table 54. Distribution of plant employees by whether or not an increase in household income occurred as a result of their obtaining plant employment

Tubbercurrv Scarriff Number Percent Number •Percent

Increase reported 127 81.4 109 74.1

No increase reported 29 18.6 38 25.9

Subtotal 156 100,0 147 100.0

No information 1 4

Total 157 151 256 employment at the new plants. In each area, all "but one of the farm operators who were employed at the plant reported an increase in household income. The reported increments in household income ranged from less than <^50 per year to more than

Tubbercurrv . Scarriff Amount of increase in income (£) Number Percent Number Percent

1 - 49 6 5.2 6 5.7 50 - 99 15 12.9 13 12.4 100 - 149 15 12.9 14 13.3 150 - 199 17 14.6 11 10.5 200 - 249 22 19.0 16 15.2 250 - 299 13 11.2 12 11.4 300 - 349 9 7.8 12 11.4 350 - 399 5 4,3 5 4.8 400 - 449 7 6.0 7 6.7 450 - 499 1 0,9 5 4.8 500 - 549 3 2,6 4 3.8 550 and over 3 2,6 — ----

, Subtotal 116 100.0 105 100.0 No information on amount of increase 11 4 Did not report an increase 29 38 No information on whether or not an increase occurred 1 4

Total 157 151 Table 56. Mean net increment to household annual income (f) reported by plant employees classified by farm work association

Farm work association^ Tubbercurry Scarriff

FO - FO 353 (n = 14) 285 (n S 15)

FW - FW 213 (n = 34) 233 (n ss 25)

FW - NFWA 228 (n = 14) 203 (n &: 9)

NFWA - NFWA 198 (n = 51) 233 (n ss 52)

Total 225 (n = 116) 237 (n a 105)

*This table refers only to those employees reporting positive Increments to household income

An explanation of the farm work association symbols appears on p. 231 259 from plant employment, Malé employees in Scarriff reported a mean increment of while males in Tubbercurry reported a mean increment of cjf237 per year. On the other hand, female employees in Tubber- curry reported a mean increment ofcS^200, while females in

Scarriff reported a mean increment ofjfl50 per year. The aggregate of the positive increments to annual house­ hold income reported by the plant employees interviewed in Tubbercurry was 0^*28^950. The corresponding aggregate of the increments reported by the plant employees interviewed in Scarriff was26,675. The distribution of these aggregate increments to annual household income of plant employees, classified by distance of residence from the plants, is shown in Table 57. Fifty-six percent of the aggregate increment to household income in the Tubbercurry area accrued to households within 4 miles of the plant, compared with 47 percent of the aggregate increment in the Scarriff area accuring to households within 4 miles of that plant. In the Tubbercurry area, the aggregate increment to house­ hold incomes declined steadily as distance from the plant in­ creased. In Scarriff, on the other hand, the proportion of the aggregate increment to household income accruing to house­ holds located between 8 and 12 miles distant from the plant (23.3 percent) was only slightly less than the proportion accruing to households which, were between 6 and 8 miles distant Table 57. Distribution of aggregate increased annual household income (f) by distance of employees' • residence from plant*

Tubbercurrv Scarriff Distance from plant (miles) Amount Percent Amount Percent

Under 4 16,325 56.4 12,575 47.1

4 and under 8 6,675 23.0 6,875 25.8

8 and under 12 2,975 10.3 6,225 23.3

12 and under 16 1,875 6.5 875 3.3

16 and under 20 . 375 1.3 125 0.5

20 arid over 725 2.5 ---

Total 28,950 100.0 26,675 100,0

*This table refers only to plant employees who reported positive increments to household income 261

from the plant. This is a consequence of the relatively high proportion of Scarriff plant employees who resided between 8 and 12 miles distant from the plant. About 90 percent of the aggregate increment to house­ hold incomes in the Tubbercurry area accrued to households located within a 12-mile radius of Tubbercurry, In Scarriff, over 95 percent of the aggregate increment accrued to house­ holds located within 12 miles from the plant. 262

XI. EXPSNDITUHE EFFECTS

The expenditure effects arising from the increased income of households in both areas as a result of plant employment / are analyzed in the present chapter, which contains two sec­ tions. In Section A, the allocation of the increased in­ come among various expenditure categories is discussed, while Section B contains an evaluation of the spatial incidence of these expenditure effects and an examination of spatial shifts in shopping patterns induced by industrialization.

A, Expenditure Effects

All employees who had reported an increase in net house­ hold income as a result of industrial employment were asked to allocate the actual or planned use of this increase among a number of expenditure categories (including savings). Within the context of the present discussion, the term "savings" is to be understood as comprising money which was being accumu­ lated and hoarded by plant employees, probably in bank accounts or post office savings accounts, and in respect of which no decision had been made regarding its future use. Some employ­ ees (13 in Tubbercurry and 6 in Scarriff) were unable, as shoïm in Table 58, to give any information regarding the use to which the increment in their household income had been or was about to be put. 263

Table 58. Distribution of plant employees by type of informa­ tion given regarding expenditure of increase in household income

Tubbercurry Scarriff Type of information Number Percent Number Percent

Percentage 61 53.5 59 57.3 Pounds sterling 12 10.5 8 7.8 Bank 30 26.3 27 26.2 Tick (check) 11 9.7 9 8.7 Subtotal 114 100.0 103 100.0 . Ho information on expenditure . 13 6 Did not report an increase in income 29 38 ' No information on whether an increase in income occurred 1 . Total 157 151

About 65 percent of the employees who gave information regarding expenditures provided either percentage or actual allocations among the expenditure categories. About 26 per­ cent of the employees in each area made a ranking of the ex­ penditure categories, while 11 Tubbercurry and 9 Scarriff employees indicated with a tick (check-) that" they had "devoted some of the increased income to certain of the categories. It is thus possible to analyze the expenditure effects at 264 three levels, viz. nimbers mentioning each category, numbers giving various rankings to each category and, finally, amounts expended on each category,

1, Expenditure categories mentioned Table 59 contains a distribution of the various expendi­ ture categories by the number of employees who mentioned each. In both areas, the two most frequently mentioned expenditure categories were savings and general living expenses, the former being more -prevalent in Tubbercurry, where nearly half of those reporting devoted some of the increased income to savings, as opposed to one third of the Scarriff employees who reported on expenditures. About a quarter of those reporting in each area said that some of the increased household income had been used to pur­ chase household equipment. Thirty percent of the Tubbercurry group and 25 percent of the Scarriff group had used some of the increase to purchase a car. Nearly 38 percent of the Tubbercurry employees reported some expenditure on clothing, while 28 percent of the Scarriff employees did so. This ref­ lects the higher proportion of female employees in Tubber­ curry, The other major difference between the two areas, that involving expenditure on entertainment (29 percent in Tubber­ curry and 13 percent in Scarriff) largely arose because of the greater number of younger, unmarried employees in Tubbercurry, Table 59. Distribution of expenditure categories by number and percent of plant employees mentioning each category

Tubbercurrv Scarriff Expenditure category Number Percent Number Percent (n = 114) (n = 103)

Purchase household equipment 29 25,4 28 27.2 Purchase car 35 30.7 26 25.2 Purchase clothing 43 37.7 29 28.2 Educational expenses 11 9.6 10 9.7 Savings 54 47.4 35 34.0 Pay bills or repay loans 1 0.9 4 3.9 General living expenses 48 42.1 37 35.9 Entertainment 33 28.9 13 12.6 Purchase farm equipment or livestock .17 15.0 20 19.4 Purchase or improve land 2 1.8 5 4.9

Purchase or improve house ------4 3.9

Invested in own nonfarm business 2 1.8 ------Given or sent to relatives 1 , 0.9 1 1.0 Other 2 1.8 2 1.9 266

About 10 percent in each area used some of the increase for educational expenses. The number using thé added income to repay debts was quite small in each area, being k- in Scarriff and 1 in Tubbercurry. Farm investment uses were reported by a somewhat higher proportion of the Scarriff em­ ployees. Farm investment uses were not reported exclusively by farm operators; some nonoperator farm workers reported that some of their added income was used for farm investment on their home farms. Four Scarriff employees reported an invest­ ment in housing, while none of those reporting in Tubbercurry did so. 2. Banking of expenditure categories The number of employees who provided rankings of the expenditure categories (or actual or percentage expenditures from which rankings could be derived) was 103 Tubbercurry and 94 in Scarriff. The expenditure categories are distri­ buted in Table 60 by the number of plant employees who gave first (or joint first) rank to each category. Thus the total number of rankings shown for each area in Table 6l exceeds the number of employees providing such rankings to the degree that some employees provided joint rankings. Thirty-seven percent of the Tubbercurry employees and 27 percent of the Scarriff employees reporting attached first (or joint first) rank to general living expenses. This cate­ gory, in both areas, was ranked first (or joint first) by a Table 60, Distribution of expenditure categories by number of plant employees attaching first (or joint first) ranking to each category

Tubbercurrv Scarriff Expenditure category Number Percent Number Percent (n = 103) (n = 94)

Purchase household equipment 10 9.7 12 12.8 Purchase car 15 14.6 11 11.7 Purchase clothing 7 6.8 6 . 6.4 Educational expenses • 5 4.8 3 3.2 Savings 21 20.4 13 13.8

Pay bills or repay loans ------4 4.3 General living expenses .. 38 36.9 25 26.6 Entertainment • 14 13.6 5 5.3 Purchase farm equipment or livestock 8 7.8 16 17.0 Purchase or improve land J; . 1 1,0 3 3.2 « Purchase or improve house —#» 4 4.3

Invested in own nonfarm business y • 1 1.0 --

Given or sent to relatives -- 1 1.1 268a substantially greater proportion of employees than was any other expenditure category. Farm investment expenditures received the second largest number of first (or joint first) rankings in Scarriff, followed by savings and household equip­ ment. In Tubbercurry, on the other hand, savings received- the second largest number of first (or joint first) rankings, followed by car purchase and entertainment expenses. •Each of the four Scarriff employees who indicated thât they spent some of their increased household income in buy­ ing or improving their houses attached a first (or joint first) ranking to this expenditure. . Similarly, 3 Scarriff employees attached a first (or joint first) raiiking to the purchase or improvement of farm land, while only one Tubber­ curry employee did so. It would, thus, appear that more of the Scarriff employees devoted major portions of increased household income to investment activities than did the Tubber­ curry employees, for whom savings and immediate consumption expenditures played a greater role. The definition of savings as used in the present chapter will be recalled at this point. Use of the words savings and investment in the present chapter . is not to be construed in terms of macroeconomic savings-invest­ ment equilibria. 2» Expenditure on each category

Seventy three employees in Tubbercurry and 6? employees in Scarriff provided either a percentage or actual allocation 268 b of their increased household income among the expenditure categories. Since the increments in household income were known in the case of all the employees who gave a percen­ tage allocation among expenditure categories, it was possible to compute actual allocations thereform. Tables 61 and 62 show the mean expenditures per annum from the increased household income reported by plant em­ ployees in both areas, classified by. farm work association. Since some farm work association groups of plant employees had only one person reporting on the allocation of increased income among expenditure categories, data in respect of such groups are not presented in Tables 6l and 62, However, the information supplied by those employees was included in com­ puting mean expenditure on each expenditure category for all employees reporting. In both areas, mean expenditure on general living ex­ penses was higher than on any other expenditure category. In Tubbercurry, the next three categories in order of impor­ tance were savings, car expenses and entertainment, while the corresponding categories in Scarriff were farm equipment or livestock, savings and car expenses. Plant employees who had no farm work association, either before or subsequent to plant employment, devoted more of their increased household income to general living expenses than to any other expenditure category. This was so in 269

Table 61.. Mean annual expenditure Oé) on various expenditure categories from increased household income of Tubbercurry plant employees classified by farm work association

Farm work association^ Expenditure category FO-FO Fff-FW Ftf-NFWA NFWA-NFWA Total

Household equipment 82.6 6.0 13.5 . 17.1

Car 53.8 31.8 25.4 32.7 . 33.3

Clothing 9.4 18.2 19.5 29.5 22.5

Educational expenses --— ---- 8.1 1.2 1.7

Savings 33.5 49.0 51.6 33.4 41.3

Pay bills or repay loan ----

General living expenses 60.0 53.2 62.2 57.0 56.0

Entertainment — — — — 13.7 43.4 45.1 • 30.9

Farm equipment or livestock 77.0 ,11.3 ---- ——— 11.6

Land purchase or improvement 56.9 -—- —— 6.3

Housing —- ———— ———— • ——

Invested in nonfarm business—— ii,8 . 3.1

Given or sent to relatives —------—- ——

Other uses —— 2.1 —- 0.1 0.6

^An explanation of the farm work .association symbols appears on p. 231 270

Table 62. Mean annual expenditure (f) on various expenditure categories from increased household income of Scarriff plant employees classified by farm work association

Farm work association^ Expenditure category FO-FO ÎW-FW Ftf-NFWA NFWA-NFWA Total

Household equipment 3:6 ---- 19.6 10.6

Car 35.4 . — 15.7 17.9

Clothing —— 17.7 -—— — 23.4 16.9

Educational expenses — —" — 3.2 3.4

Savings —— 35.3 5.0 25.2 22.3

Pay bills or repay loan • — 55.0 23.5 15.7

General living expenses 30.4 66.4 95.0 .91.9 74.6

Entertainment 27.2 15.1 14.8

F^rm equipment or livestock 106.5 8.3 50.0 — — —— 23.0

Land purchase or improvement 114.3 12.2 —-—— 15.2

Housing 30.3 21.9 ———— 3.8 14.0

Invested in nonfarm business ——- —— —— ——

Given or sent to relatives 12.5 ———— ———— 3.4

Other uses 15.0 3.8. ——— 4.3 4.8

%n explanation of the farm work association syinbpls appears on p. 231 271 both areas. However, among the Tutbercurry group, the second expenditure category in order of importance was entertainment expenditure, while in Scarriff, entertainment expenditures were ranked seventh by this group of emploj^es. The Scarriff group tended to devote approximately equal amounts to savings, getting out of debt and to expenditure on clothing, which were next in order of importance to general living expenses. Farm operators in both areas allocated none of their increased income to entertainment expenditures. Allocations to investment uses such as purchases of farm equipment and livestock and acquisition or improvement of land outweighed the amount used for general living expenses. Farm operators in the Tubbercurry area made substantial purchases of house­ hold equipment from the added income while those in the Scarriff area devoted as much to improvement of their housing facilities as they did to general living expenses. These data regarding expenditures support the hypothesis that increased household incomes arising directly from indus- . trialization gave rise to increased expenditures on goods and services on the part of households experiencing such increased incomes. Such expenditures were on consumer goods, entertain­ ment and other services and on farm investment goods, thus providing increased demand for these goods and services which would give rise to indirect effects on businesses providing these services. 272

B, Spatial Incidence of Expenditure Effects

All plant employees who reported an increase in house­ hold income as a result of plant employment (except those employees who reported that all of the.increased income had been saved) were asked to indicate the town in which the increased income was mainly spent, • Some employees in each • area reported that the extra income had been spent in roughly equal proportions in more than one town, but the bulk of the employees mentioned just one town. The towns mentioned in this regard by the Tubbercurry employees are shown in Table 63. Tht total number of res­ ponses was 122. The town of Tubbercurry was mentioned 76 times, thus receiving 62 percent of all mentions, Ballymote and Charlestown were each mentioned 8 times. Towns- outside the Tubbercurry AOI were mentioned on 28 occasions as being the places wherein plant employees spent most of their in­ creased household income. Chief among these tomis was Sligo, the county seat, which had a I966 population of 13,424 people and is situated about 25 miles distant from Tubbercurry. Nearly all of the employees residing in the Tubbercurry DED and the adjoining BED*s mentioned the town of Tubbercurry, Those mentioning Ballymote and Charlestown were all residents of these towns or of the adjoining DED*s. Plant employees who mentioned Sligo resided in many of the DED*s though more of them resided to the north of Tubbercurry than to 273 the south of Tubbercurry. It is of interest to note that 6 residents of the Tubbercurry DED mentioned the town of Sligo. Five of these were either nonheads of households or else resided in one person households. Similar information regarding the Scarriff employees is shown, in Table 64. The town of Scarriff was mentioned 4-6 times, receiving nearly half of all mentions. All other towns in the Scarriff AOI were mentioned infrequently except Killaloe which was mentioned 9 times. Over 30 percent of ,the towns mentioned were outsid'e the Scarriff AOI, The most frequently mentioned town outside the AOI was Limerick (mentioned 19 times) which had a I966 population of 55,912 and is situated about 25 miles distant from Scarriff. In comparing the spatial incidence of the direct expen­ diture effects in the two areas, it is evident that the pro­ portion of plant employees who spent the major part of their increased household income in.the town wherein the new plant was situated was greater among the Tubbercurry employees than among the Scarriff employees. The town of Tubbercurry re­ ceived over 62 percent of the mentions among the Tubbercurry employees, while the town of Scarriff received 48 percent of the mentions among the Scarriff employees. Apparently, therefore, the expenditure effects of industrialization were more concentrated in the town of Tubbercurry than in the town of Scarriff, 274

Table 63. Distribution of towns by nimber of times mentioned by Tubbercurry plant employees as the main spend­ ing location of increased household income

Percent Times of Town Mentioned Mentions (n =122)

Within the AOI Tubbercurry 76 62.3 Ballymote .8 6,6 Charlestown 8 6,6 Aclare 1 0.8 Coolaney 1 0.8

Outside the AOI - Swinford 2 1.6 Ballina (Mayo) 2 1.6 Sligo 21 17.2 Other towns 3 2.5

Table 64. Distribution of towns by number of times mentioned by Scarriff plant employees as the• main spending. location of increased household income

Percent Times of Town Mentioned Mentions (n = 95)

Within the AOI Scarriff 46 48.4 Mount shannon 2 2.1 Peakle 4 4.2 Whitegate 2 2.1 Broadford 2 2.1 Killaloe 9 9.5 Bodyke 1 1.1 275

Table 64 (Continued)

Percent Times of ToTm Mentioned Mentions (n = 95)

Outside the AOI 2 2.1 Limerick 19 20.0 Ballina (Tipperary) 2 2.1 Other towns 6 6.3

This difference was to be expected on the basis of the greater number of Scarriff employees who resided in DSD*s containing other towns within the areas. For example, most of the plant employees who resided in Killaloe spent most of their increased income in Killaloe. It is also apparent that there were substantial leakages of the increased household income from both areas through expenditures made outside the areas. About 20 percent of the employees who had received increased household income in each area reported that this increased income was mainly spent in a large town situated about 25 miles distant from the town in which the plant was located. Further evidence to support the proposition that a rela­ tively greater expenditure effect was manifested on .the town of Tubbercurry than on the town of Scarriff is provided by the fact that 109 of the Tubbercurry employees (70 percent) 276

reported an increase in shopping in Tubbercurry town as a result of their plant emplosrment, while 89 of the Scarriff employees (less than 60 percent) reported an increase in shopping in Scarriff town.as a result of their plant em­ ployment, • , Of the employees who reported an increase in shopping in Tubbercurry, about half indicated that they had reduced shopping in other towns. Nearly two thirds of the corres­ ponding Scarriff employees reduced their shopping in other towns. Of course, many of these employees were people who had moved into the AOI's in association with their plant emplo3rment. Hence, the towns in which these people decreased their shopping were distributed over a wide geographical area. However, as shown in Tables 65 and 66, other towns within the two AOI's experienced a decrease in shopping by plant employees who increased their shopping in Tubbercurry and in Scarriff. In the Tubbercurry area, the towns of Ballymote and Charlestown exhibited the greatest decrease in shopping as a result of the Tubbercurry industrialization while in the Scarriff area, the town of Killaloe experienced a cor­ responding decrease in shopping as a result of the Scarriff industrialization. There was, thus, a shift in the location of shopping by families of plant employees as a result of obtaining indus­ trial employment in Tubbercurry and in Scarriff, In both 277

Table ,65. Distribution of towns in the Tubbercurry AOI by number of plant employees who decreased shopping in each town and increased shopping in Tubbercurry as a result of obtaining plant employment

Employees Town Number . Percent (n = 56)

Ballymote 12 21.4 Curry 3 5.4 Charlestown 9 16.1 Coolaney 1 1.8

Table 66, Distribution of towns in the Scarriff AOI by number of plant employees who decreased shopping in each town and increased shopping in Scarriff as a result of obtaining plant employment

Employees Town Number Percent (n = 57)

Mountshannon 2 3.5 Feakle 3 5,3 Whitegate 2 3.5 Broadford .3 5.3 Killaloe 10 17.5 278 cases the shift involved a decrease in shopping "by plant employees in other towns in the AOI and an increase in shopping in the town wherein the plant was situated. In both areas, practially all plant employees who reported shopping shifts from other towns to the plant tovjn were resi­ dents of the DSD*s containing these other towns or of the DED's adjoining these DED's, However, the shift in shopping location involved some goods and services to a greater extent than others, as shown in Table 6?. Groceries and clothing were involved much more frequently in the shift in both areas than were other goods and services. About 70 percent of the employees who increased shopping in Tubbercurry and Scarriff and decreased shopping in other towns indicated that groceries and clothing were involved in the shift. All other goods and services were involved in less than half of the shifts in each area. All goods and services other than groceries and clothing were involved more frequently in shopping shifts in Tubber­ curry than in Scarriff, In fact, newspapers and magazines were featured in 45 percent of the Tubbercurry shifts, but in less than 20 percent of the Scarriff shifts. In both areas, the items involved least frequently in shifts of shop­ ping location were furniture and household appliances. It is, thus, apparent that the indirect effects on local business firms arising from changes in the demand for goods Table 67. Distribution of goods and services by number of times mentioned as being involved in the shift in shopping patterns by plant employees who in­ creased shopping in Tubbercurry and Scarriff and decreased shopping in other towns as a result of obtaining plant employment

Employees mentioning each item Tubbercurry Scarriff Item Number Percent Number Percent (n = 56) (n = 57)

Groceries 39 69.6 40 70,2 Clothing 37 66.1 41 71.9 Hardware 16 28,6 7 1 12.3 Drugs and Cosmetics 14 25.0 12 21.1 Doctor or dental services 14 25.0 10 17.5 Entertainment 22 39.3 11 19.3 Petrol, oil, car repair 18 32.1 13 22.8 Newspapers and magazines 25 44,6 10 17.5 Furniture and household appliances 10 17.9 5 8.8 280 and services differ considerably among business firms accord­ ing to the goods and services in the provision of which they are engaged. Greater effects may be expected to be felt by grocery stores and clothiers, than, say, by suppliers of furniture following industrialization in an area. 281

XII. PAEM BUSINESS EFFECTS

The direct effects on their farm businesses following the plant employment of farm operators are discussed in this chapter. The discussion is confined to the effects observed on the farms of farm operators who did not change their farm work association subsequent to obtaining plant emplosrment. Farm operators in this category numbered in the Tubbercurry area and I7 in the Scarriff area. The manner in which the nature and magnitude of these direct effects were determined has been discussed previously. Suffice it to remark, at this stage, that in respect of each farm business characteristic examined, the farm operators were asked to report any changes in that characteristic which had occurred as a direct result of their obtaining employment at the new plants. For convenience of presentation, this chapter is organized as follows. The direct effects of plant employment on labor and machinery utilization are examined in Section A, The direct effects on land utilization and livestock enterprises are discussed in Sections B and C, which also contain a quantitative evaluation of the magnitude of these effects. Finally, Section D contains an evaluation of the direct effects on the total farm output of those farms. 282

A. Labor and Machinery

The effects of farm operator plant employment on the farm labor and machinery use on their farms is shown in Tables 68 and 69. All farm operators employed in Tubbercurry reported a decrease in the amount of time which they devoted to farm work. However, 17.6 percent of the farm.operators employed at the Scarriff plant reported no change in, their farm work input as a result of plant employment. It is to be expected that farm operators would probably decrease the amount of time spent at farm work as a result of obtaining plant employment. The fac"t that some reported no change requires an explanation. It is possible that these farm operators may have overlooked certain minor changes in the amount of time they devoted to farm work. It is more likely, however, that a substitution of work for leisure- time occurred in the case of those farm operators, possibly through early rising or working late into evenings on their . farms. It is also possible, of course, that the labor input of those farm operators was so low that their acceptance of plant employment largely involved utilization of what was formerly idle time. In such cases, there would be little adjustment pressure arising from loss of operator labor. In Tubbercurry, nearly three-fourths of the wives of married farm operator plant employees increased the amount . 283

Table 68. Effect of operator plant employment on farm labor and machinery use in the Tubbercurry area

Percent reporting^ Characteristic No change Increase Decrease

Amount of time spent by operator at farm work 100.0 Amount of time spegt by operator's wife at farm work 18.2 72.7 9.1 Amount of time spent by other family members at farm work 40.0 50.0 10.0 Total amount of time spent by all family members at farm work 6.7 26.6 66.7 Amount of hired labor used 40,0 46.7 13.3 Amount of time spent working at turf production by operator 53.3 46.7

Use of own machinery and equipment 73.4 26.6

Use of hired machinery and equipment 46.7 46.7 6.6

^Except where noted otherwise, percentages refer to 15 farm operators

^Percentages for this item refer to the 11 married farm operators

Percentages for this item-refer to the 10 farms having other family members 284

Table 69. Effect of operator plant employment on farm labor and machinery use in the Scarriff area

Percent reporting* Charac teristic No change Increase Decrease

Amount of time spent by operator at farm work . 17.6 82.4

Amount of time spegt by operator's wife at fam work 63.6 36.4 ———

Amount of time spent by other family ' members at farm work 71.4 28.6 —— —

Total amount of time spent by all family members at farm work 35.3 5.9 58.8

Amount of hired labor used 64.7 23.5 11.8

Amount of time spent working at turf production by operator 76.5 —- —- 23.5

Use of own machinery and equipment 70.6 17.6 11.8

Use^^of^hi^ed machinery and 58.8 4Ï.2 ----

^Except where noted otherwise, percentages refer to 17 farm operators

Percentages for this item refer to the 11 married farm operators

^Percentages for this item refer to the 14 farms haying other family members 285 of time which they devoted to farm work, about-twice as high as the proportion of wives who increased their farm work in Scarriff. Similarly, on 50 percent of the Tubbercurry farms which had more family members than the -operator and his wife the amount of farm work done by the other family members increased. Increased farm work by other family members occurred on less than one-third of the Scarriff farms where such family members were present. Part of the explanation of this difference may lie in the fact that on some of the Scarriff farms there was no reduction in the amount of time, devoted to farm work by thé' farm opera­ tor as a result of his obtaining plant employment. Hence, some of the Scarriff farms would have little need for labor or other substitution to occur. However, it is also possible that the supply elasticity of family labor on some of the Scarriff farms was lower than on the Tubbercurry farms. It will be recollected that the mean, number of family members who did some farm work on the Tubbercurry farms was greater than on the Scarriff farms. Some support for both of these possible explanations may be found in an examination of changes occuring in the total amount of time spent by all family members at farm work. . On 35 percent of the Scarriff farms, there was no change reported in this quantity, while no change occurred on only 6.7 percent of the Tubbercurry farms. Changes in the labor inputs of wives 286 and other family members would be normally expected to occur only when changes had occurred in the amount of labor input by the farm operators. It may be expected, however, that the labor services of wives and other family members would not be perfect substi­ tutes for farm operator labor. Hence, in order to effec­ tively replace a loss of operator labor, it may be expected that the increase in amount of family labor would need to be greater than the loss of operator labor. In such cases, then, the effect on the total amount of family labor used would be an increase. On about one-fourth of the Tubbercurry farms an increase occurred in the total time spent at farm work by all family members. This would indicate that family labor on those farms was not regarded as a perfect substitute for operator labor and also that the supply of this family labor was sufficiently elastic that it could be provided in greater absolute quan­ tities than involved in the loss of operator labor. On the Scarriff farms, on the other hand, only 6 percent of farms reported an increase in total time devoted to farm work by all family members. This does not mean, however, that farm output would have been reduced on those farms as a result. Depending on the nature of any farm investment effects of increased household income arising from plant em­ ployment, the value of output might remain unchanged or 287 actually increase even though the substitution effects were weak. The proportion of farm operators reporting an increase in the amount of hired labor used was about twice as high in Tubbercurry as in Scarriff, This suggests that it was less possible to replace losses of .operator labor with farm labor on the Tubbercurry farms than on the Scarriff farms, even though there were more increases reported in the use of family labor on the Tubbercurry farms than on the Scarriff farms. Further support for this view may be found in .the fact that increased use of own machinery and equipment was reported on 26,6 percent of the Tubbercurry farms, as opposed to 17.6 percent of the Scarriff farms, while the proportion of farms on which the use of hired machinery and equipment was increased was also greater in Tubbercurry than in Scarriff. The pervading feature of Tables 68 and 69 is that in the case of all characteristics, save one, the proportion of Scarriff farm operators reporting no change was larger than the proportion of Tubbercurry farm operators reporting no change. This indicates that substitution effects following the loss of farm operator labor occurred more frequently on the Tubbercurry farms than on the Scarriff farms. 288

B, Land Utilization

Data regarding the direct effects of plant employment of farm operators on the land utilization patterns of their farms are presented in Tables 70 and 71. A much higher proportion of the Tubbercurry farm operators reported that their plant employment had given rise to decreases in total area farmed, in,land rented for grazing, in land rented for crops, in acreage of grain crops and in acreage of root and green crops sown. For each of these items, the proportion of operators reporting no change was much higher in Scarriff than in Tubbercurry. In both areas, the most frequently occurring changes in land utilization involved decreases in grain crop acreage and in root and green crop acreage and increases in the acreage under hay and pasture. More increases in pasture than in hay were reported in each area. These changes are as might be expected on a priori grounds, since grain crops and root and green crops are considerably more labor intensive crop enter­ prises than are hay and pasture. Once again, however, it is noted that the frequency of decreases caused in these labor-intensive crops was greater among the Tubbercurry farm operators who had plant employment than among the Scarriff farm operator plant employees. This observation is highly, consistent with the evidence contained in the previous section which indicated that the loss of 289

Table 70. Effects of operator plant employment on land utiliza­ tion in the Tubbercurry area^

Percent Reporting^ No Characteristic Change Increase Decrease

Total area farmed 60.0 6.7 33.3 Land rented for grazing 73,3 6.7 20.0

Land rented for crops 73.3 — — — ' 26.7

Grain crops 33.3 — —— 66.7

Root and grain crops ' 46.7 —— — 53.3 Hay 73.3, 20.0 6.7 Pasture 33.3 53.4 13.3

^Percentages refer to 15 farm operators operator labor on farms where the operator had obtained plant employment had more serious implications for the farm busi­ nesses of those farms in the Tubbercurry area than in the Scarriff area. It is interesting to note that 17,6 percent of the Scarriff farm operator plant employees indicated that they had increased their total area farmed as a result of obtaining plant employment. It will be recollected that, during the dis­ cussion of expenditure effects in a previous chapter, it was noted that Scarriff farm operator plant employees devoted a relatively large portion of their increased income to the 290

Table 71, Effects of operator plant employment on land utlllza tion in the Scarriff area

Percent Reportinp^ No Charac teristic Change Increase Decrease

Total area farmed 82.4 17.6 Land rented for gra:zing 88.2 5.9 • 5.9

Land rented for crops 94.1 — —— 5.9 Grain crops 52.9 47.1 Root and grain crops 64.7 5.9 29.4 Hay 64.7 23.5 11.8 Pasture 52.9 41.2 5.9

^Percentages refer to 17 farm operators expenditure category which was labelled "land purchase or improvement". Apparently, those plant employee farm operators ' in the Scarriff area who invested in their farm businesses decided to invest at the extensive' rather than at the inten­ sive margin of production. Further evidence to support this contention is provided by the data in Table 72, which contains a quantitative assess­ ment of the direct effects of farm operator plant employment on their farm businesses. It will be noted that the total area of land farmed by the 17 plant employee farm operators in Scarriff was increased by 37 acres.as a direct effect Table 72, Estimated magnitude o,f direct effects of farm operator plant employ­ ment on land utilizations-

Characteristic Tubbercurry Scarriff (acres) Total ~ Mean Total Mean Change per farm change per farm (a = IS). (n = 17) Total area farmed 14.0 0,93 37.0 2.18 Land rented for grazing 19.0 1,27 - 4,0 -0.24 Land rented for crops — 8,0 -0.53 . —6,0 -0,35 Grain crops -21,5 1-1 A3 -12,8 -tO,75 Root and green crops ill.3 -0,75 - 9.2 -0,54 Hay 7.0 0,47 - 1.5 -0.09 Pasture 39.8 2,65 58.5 3,44

^•Positive cell entries indicate increases while negative entries indicate decreases 292

induced by their plant employment. The aggregate level of all categories of land use except pasture declined for this group. Hence, all of the decreases reported in the other land utilization categories represented land which was switched to pasture. In addition, all of the new land acquired by this group of farm operators was also devoted to pasture. Both in aggregate terms and in terms of mean per farm the decrease in the amount of land devoted to grain crops and to root and green crops was greater in Tubbercurry than in Scarriff. Corresponding to the decrease in crop acreage, both groups of farm operators reduced the amount of land which they had rented for crop production. However, in aggregate, - the Scarriff group of farm operators also reduced the amount of land rented for grazing and then purchased grazing land. On the other hand, in aggregate, the Tubbercurry group of operators rented an additional 19 acres of land for grazing. Thus, it is seen that both groups of farm operator plant employees transferred land from labor intensive to labor ex­ tensive uses, mainly grassland. In addition to this transfer, both groups acquired additional, land, the Scarriff group by purchase, the Tubbercurry group by rental, which was also devoted to pasture.

C. Livestock Enterprises ,

Direct effects of operator plant employment on livestock 293

enterprises are shown in Tables 73 and 74. As might be expected on a priori grounds and in conjunction with the already observed increase in the acreage under grassland on their farms, about 30 percent of the Scarriff farm operator plant employees increased their numbers of cattle, other than milch cows, as a result of obtaining plant employment. The forces inducing this increase may be two-fold. Since cattle-raising in association with grassland is a labor- extensive enterprise, there would be an incentive to reallo­ cate farm resources towards the production of these items on farms where the loss of operator labor following plant employment was not replaceable by other family labor. In addition, the farm investment effect arising from increased household income provided by the nonfarm employment may pro­ vide a ready means of effecting such a production 'shift. . Decreases in numbers of ewes and sows kept and in numbers of pigs and poultry reared were reported more frequently by farm operator plant employees in Tubbercurry than in Scarriff. The changes which occurred in cow numbers are quite interesting. In Scarriff, 6 percent of the farm operator plant employees reported a decrease in cow numbers, while 94 percent reported no change. However, in the Tubbercurry area, about half of the farm operator plant employees reported that a decrease had occurred. Since the keeping of milch cows is a more labor-intensive 294

Table 73o Effects of operator plant employment on livestock enterprises in the Tubbercurry area.

Characteristic No Change Increase Decrease

Cows 20.0 33.3 46.7 Other cattle 33.3 60.0 6.7

Ewes 86.7 ———— 13.3

Sows 80.0 ——— 20,0 Pigs reared 66.7 6.7 26.6 Turkeys reared 73.4 26.6

Ordinary fowl 66.7 ———— 33.3

Percentages refer to 15 farm operators

Table 74. Effects of operator plant employment on livestock enterprises in the Scarriff area

Percent Reporting^ Characteristic No Change Increase Decrease

Cows 94 »! — 5» 9 Other cattle 70.6 29.4 Swes 94.1 5» 9 ——— Sows 94*1 —— 5*9 Pigs reared 82.3 5«9. 11.8 Turkeys reared 94.1 5*9 Ordinary fowl 100.0

^Percentages refer to 17 farm operators 295 enterprise than the rearing of cattle on grassland, effects emanating from loss of operator labor through plant employ­ ment might be expected to induce decreases rather than in­ creases in cow numbers. However, in the Tubbercurry area, there has been some recent expansion in creamery milk pro­ duction. Apparently for those farm operators who increased cow numbers as a result of obtaining plant employment, the farm investment effect arising from increased household in­ come which enables them to purchase those cows outweighed any influences which might have tended to reduce cow numbers as a result of loss of operator labor. The aggregate and mean magnitude per farm of the direct effects of operator plant employment on farm livestock enter­ prises are shown in Table 75. The most striking features of Table 75 are that numbers of cattle, other than milch cows, were directly increased by 36 on farms of the Scarriff farm operator plant employees, a mean increase of 2.12 per farm and that numbers- of other cattle were. directly increased by 26 on farms of the Tubber- curry farm operator plant employees, a mean increase of 1,73 cattle per farm. Also worthy of note is that the number of pigs per annum reared to bacon weight was reduced by 3^ on the Tubbercurry group of farms, while the aggregate number of sows was reduced by 6. There were also sizeable reductions in numbers of poul­ try on the Tubbercurry farms. Table 75. Estimated magnitude of direct effects of farm operator plant employment on livestock enterprises®-

Tubbercurry Scarrlff Total Mean Total Mean Characteristic (number) Change per farm Change per farm (n = 15) (n + 17)

Cows 3.0 0.20 -2.0 .-0.12 Other cattle 26.0 1.73 36.0 2.12 Ewes — 8.0 -0.53 5.0 0.29 Sows —6.0 -0.40 —1.0 -0. o6 Pigs reared -34.0 -2.27 1.0 0.06 Turkeys reared —68 « 0 "4.53 • -10.0 -0.59

Ordinary fowl -140.0 -9,33 ------

^Positive cell entries indicate increases while megative cell entries indicate decreases 297

The aggregate net increase of 3 cows shown in Table 75 for the Tubbercurry group of farms masks the real situation, since a high proportion of these farm operators increased their cow numbers and a high proportion decreased cow numbers. The aggregate direct increase in cow numbers reported by those farm operators who increased cow numbers was 17. The aggregate direct decrease reported by those who decreased cow numbers was Hence, an aggregate net increase of 3 cows results.

D. Total Farm Output

The net effect of employment of a farm operator at an industrial plant on the total output of his farm depends on the relative importance of the substitution effects arising from loss of operator labor and the farm investment effects arising from increased household income obtained as a result of plant employment. So far during the present discussion it has been apparent that substitution effects played a prominent role in the farm businesses of farm operators who obtained plant employment. The presence of investment effects has also been noted, for example, acquisition of cows by some of the Tubbercurry group, acquisition of other cattle by both groups and purchase of land by both groups. 298

It may be helpful at this point to recall that those farm operator plant employees in Scarriff who reported on the allocation of their increased income among expenditure cate­ gories reported mean annual expenditures of on land purchase or improvement and«^106,5 on purchase of farm equip­ ment or livestock. The corresponding group of Tubbercurry em­ ployees reported mean expenditures of^56.9 on land purchase or improvement and ^77 on purchase of farm equipment or live­ stock. Since the farms of farm operator plant employees in both areas had a low inventory value of farm machinery and equipment when the study was conducted it may be concluded that most of the investment effect designated as farm equipment or livestock was devoted to purchases of livestock. As discussed in an earlier chapter, little effect on total farm output was expected on a priori grounds. There is no reason to believe that farm output would be decreased as a result of operator employment on the 17.6 percent of Scarriff farm operator plant employee farms where; as noted earlier in the present chapter, the amount of time devoted to farm work by the farm operators did not decrease. In fact, it might well have been that some farm investment effects were present which would tend to.raise output on those, farms. All of the farm operator plant employees were asked whether, in their own judgement, they would say that the value of output from their farms was increased, decreased or unchanged by the fact that they had come to work at the plant. In 299

Scarriff, 47.1 percent said that the value of their farm output had been increased as a result of their plant employ­ ment; a further 35.3 percent said that it had been unchanged, while only 17.6 percent said that the value of their farm output had fallen as a result of their plant employment. Similarly, in Tubbercurry, 40 percent of farm operator plant employees reported an increase in the value of their farm output as a result of obtaining plant employment; 33.3 percent reported no change, while only 26.7 percent reported that a decrease in the value of their farm output had been caused by their plant employment. All operators who did not report a decrease in value of farm output as a result of their plant employment were asked to explain how farm output remained unchanged or increased despite the fact that they had less time to devote to farm work following acceptance of plant employment. The explana­ tions offered by the farm operators are of considerable interest. Some of the explanations given for an increased value of farm output as a result of plant employment were: "we can live on factory income and put back farm profits into the farm", "can afford manure now with the extra money from the factory", "bought extra cattle", "more money, more manuring,' so stock has increased", "more capital to put into the farm," "more fertilizer and more dry stock" et cetera. All of the replies from the farm operators who reported an increase in 300 the value of farm output as a result of plant employment emphasize the crucial role played by the farm investment effect of increased household income obtained as a result of plant employment. Most of the reasons given by farm operators who reported that the value of farm production was unchanged by their ob­ taining plant•employment tended to emphasize the substitution effects. Some replies were; "better managed now than it was", "worked harder and earlier rising", "employ casual labour", "sister does some farm work now". However, some of the replies also involved the farm investment effect, e,£,

"can buy bag fertilizer now and carry more stock".

It may thus be concluded that strong farm inveslanent effects occurred on many of the farms of operators who obtained employment at the new plants. Where these effects occurred, they tended to give rise to an increase in the value of farm output, as a result of the operator obtaining plant employment.

On other farms where the effects were mainly substitution effects, value of output tended to remain unchanged. Only on relatively few farms was the situation such that combined substitution and farm investment effects did not balance the effects emanating from the loss of operator labor.

Increases in the value of farm output may normally be expected to give rise to increases in farm income obtained from such farms, while decreases in the value of farm output 301 may normally be expected to give rise to decreases in farm income. In cases of the latter type, one would expect that increases in nonfarm income of farm operators as a result of obtaining plant employment would be partly offset by decreases in the farm income of such operators. On the other hand, on farms where an increase in the value of farm output was report­ ed as a result of operator employment at one of the new plants, one may expect that the effects of operator plant employment on nonfarm income and- on farm income would tend to reinforce one another, thus gi-ving a greater effect on the total income— of such operators than that which might be expected in cases where the effects on nonfarm and farm income partly offset one another. In this connection, it is, therefore, of interest to note that farm operators in the Tubbercurry area who reported that the value of their farm output had been increased as a result of plant employment reported that plant employment had led to a mean increase of/38O in annual household income. Those who reported that the value of farm ou"bput had been un­ affected by plant employment reported a mean increase of /337 in annual household income, while those operators • who said that the value of their farm ouput had decreased as a result of plant employment reported a mean increase of^31? in annual household income. 302

Similar income effects were reported in the Scarriff area. Farm operators who said that the value of their farm output had increased as a result of plant employment reported a mean increase of <£329 in annual household income. Those who had indicated that plant employment had no effect on the value of their farm output reported that plant employment had led to a mean increase of-€'2^7 in annual household income. Farm operators who said that the value of their farm ouput had decreased as a result of their plant employment reported a mean increase of <^197 in household income. Thus, in each area, greater increases in annual household incomes were reported "by farm operators whose plant employment had resulted in increased farm output than by operators whose plant employment had not affected the value of their farm out­ put. Increases in household incomes of the latter group were, in turn, greater than increases in household income reported by farm operators whose plant employment had led to a reduction in the value of their farm output. 303

XIII. SELECTIVITY FACTORS

This chapter contains an examination of some selectivity factors which were expected to be of importance in the re­ cruitment of employees of the new plants. Comparisons in. respect of 4 groups are presented. In Section personal and farm business characteristics of farm operators employed at the plant are compared with those of farm operators not r employed at the plant in each area. Section B. contains com­ parisons of personal data between nonheads of farm house­ holds employed at the plants and nonheads of farm households in the working age group who were not employed in the plants. Sections C and D incorporate similar comparisons for corres­ ponding groups of heads of urban households ajid nonheads of urban households respectively.

A,'• Farm Operators •

This section contains a discussion of the selectivity factors which differentiated farm operators who obtained plant employment from other farm operators in the two areas who were not employed at the new plants. The discussion is confined to the farm operators in each area who did not change their farm work association subsequent to obtaining employ­ ment at the new plants. 304

Personal characteristics Certain personal characteristics of farm operators employed at the new plants were compared with the same characteristics of a sample of farm operators in each of the two areas who had not been employed at the new plants. As shown in Table 76, the mean age of farm operators em­ ployed in Tubbercurry was 41.00 years, while the mean age of other farm operators in the area was 52.97 years. The differ­ ence had a high statistical significance. The mean age of farm operators employed at the Scarriff plant was 36.88 years while that of other farm operators in. the Scarriff area.was 51.33 years, the difference being highly significant statistically. Thus, farm operators in both areas who were employed at the plants tended to be younger than farm operators who were not employed, the mean difference observed being about 12 years in Tubbercurry and about years in Scarriff. In each of the two areas, the proportion of farm operators not employed at the plant who had obtained some formal post­ primary education was about 5 percent. In contrast the pro­ portion of plant employee farm operators who had obtained some formal post-primary education was 46.6 percent in Tubber­ curry and 17.6 percent in Scarriff, The difference observed in Tubbercurry was significant at the 99 percent level, while the difference observed in Scarriff was not significant at the 95 percent level. Table 76. Comparison of personal characteristics of farm operator plant employees and of other farm operators in each area

Tubbercurrv Scarriff Plant Other Plant Other Characteristic employees operators employees operators

Mean age (years) 41.00** 52.97** 36.88** 51.33**

Mean post-primary education (years) 1.47 i 0.22 0.29 0.19

Percent having post-primary education 46.66** • 5.00** 17.65 5.06

Mean household size 3.80 3.04 3.82 3.96

Difference significant at 99 percent level 306

This evidence indicates that there was selectivity among farm operators in the Tubbercurry area in regard to whether or not they had obtained any formal post-primary education. Such selectivity may have been mainly due to the hiring policies of the plant, since the general level of skills required by employees in Tubbercurry was higher than that in Scarriff. Hence, the hiring policies in Tubbercurry may have tended to select out for employment those people having some post-primary education more frequently than those having primary education only. Farm operators employed in Tubbercurry had 1,25 years more post-primary education than those farm operators who were not employed. This difference was not quite significant at the 95 percent level, but was significant at the 90 percent level. It would thus appear that whether or not farm operators had had some post-primary'-education was relatively more important from a selectivity point of view than the actual amount of post-primary education obtained by farm operators employed in Scarriff (0,3 years) was greater than that had by those not employed (0,2 years), the difference was. not statistically sig­ nificant. Differences in household size between farm operators with and without plant employment in both areas were not statis­ tically significant. 307

2. Farm business characteristics Data regarding land utilization and livestock numbers on farms operated by plant employees and other farm operators are shown in Table 77. Direct effects of plant employment on land utilization and livestock numbers on farms operated by plant employees have been subtracted out from the actual values occurring on those farms, in order to estimate the degree of selectivity involved. For example, the mean number of acres farmed by the plant employees in Tubbercurry in I966 was 30.06 acres. The mean direct effect of plant employment on the acreage farmed by these operators was an increase of 0,93 acres. Subtraction of this latter figure from the actual acreage reported yields the figure of 29.13 shown in Table 77. Thus differences between the values shown in Table 77 for attri­ butes of plant employee farms and of other farms would reflect original differences between the two groups of farms, from which the incidence of selectivity may be estimated. Highly significant differences appeared In both areas in the number of acres farmed. Farm operators who had obtained plant employment had come.from smaller farms. This was as expected on a priori grounds. Since a desire for increased income is usually an important motivating force in prompting a decision to seek a nonfarm job, it may be expected that farm operators having lower farm incomes would have offered their labor services more frequently to the new plants than would Table 77. Comparison of land utilization and livestock nombers on farms operated by plant employees and on farms operated by other operators (allowing for the direct effects of plant employment on plant employees' farms)

* I Tubbercurry Scarriff Plant Other Plant Other Characteristic (mean) employees operators employees Operators

Acres farmed 29.13** 43.50** 31.94** 60.76

Acres of grain crops 2.06** 0.74** 1.58* 0.75

Acres of root and green crops 1.37* 0.62* 1.98 1.15

Number of cows 4.00 4.64 4.82** 7.41

Total number of cattle 15.60 17.60 17.53** 31.37

Number of pigs 2.46 1.33 3.20 2.80

Number of poultry 33.33 24.00 22.82 22.48

Number of sheep 2.60 1.53 4.96 5.67

Difference significant at the 99 percent level 'fc Difference significant at the 95 percent level 309 have farm operators with larger incomes. To the extent that farm income is related to the ntuaber of acres farmed, one would expect that offers of labor services to industry would come more frequently from farm operators who were farming f . smaller acreages. Afer allowing for the direct effects on grain crop acre­ age and on acreage of root and green crops on the farms oper­ ated by plant employees, significant differences in agreages devoted to these crops on the two groups of farms were found. In each area, the farm operators who obtained plant employment had had higher acreages under grain crops and under root and green crops than had fa^ operators who did not obtain plant employment. This suggests that those operators had been operating their farms more intensively in terms of cropping pattern in an effort to minimize income differences which might be expected to occur as a result of their lower farm size. Numbers of cows and of all cattle had been significantly lower on farms operated by plant employees than on other farms in the Scarriff area. Numbers of these animals had also been lower on the farms of operators employed in Tubber- curry, but not significantly so. These data suggest, there­ fore, that farms whose operators obtained employment at the new plants in both areas had been smaller and had had a relatively greater emphasis placed on crop production than 310 on cattle. It is of interest to note that the nimber of pigs on farms whose operators obtained plant employment had been somewhat higher in each area than on farms whose operators did not obtain plant employment, thus providing further evidence that farms from which operators had obtained plant employment / had been operated relatively more intensively than other farms in the two areas. The 1965/66 labor utilization and farm income data for farms whose operators had plant employment and for other farms in each area is shown in Table 78. In both areas, as might be expected, the farm labor input of plant employee farm operators was substantially less than that of other farm operators. In all .labor, machinery value and farm income character­ istics, the differences observed in I966 between farms whose operators had obtained plant employment and farms operated by people who did not obtain plant employment were much greater in the Scarriff area than in the Tubbercurry area. For example total family labor input on plant employee farms was about half of that on other farms in Scarriff, while the differences in Tubbercurry was slight. Sales of farm products tended to be less on farms operated by plant employees than on other farms in each area, the dif­ ference being greater in Scarriff, As there were little dif­ ferences in household consumption, gross • farm output was also lower on farms operated by plant employees. Differences in Table 78. Labor utilization and farm income on farms operated by plant employees and on other farms in each area during 1965/66

Tubbercurrv Scarriff Plant Other Plant Other Characteristic (mean) employees operators employees operators

Number of family members doing some farm work 2.4 2.0 2.2 2.4 ** Manhours of operator labor 930** 1,578** 922 2,051** Total manhours of family labor 2,288 2,342 1,853** 3,772** Number of days hired labor used 33 \ 30 16 21 Value of farm machinery and equipment (() 57 113 43* 122* Total sales of farm products (^) 358 428 541* 851* Household consumption of farm products Of) 86 82 80 90 Gross farm output C^) 444 • 510 621* 941* Nonlabor farm expenses Of) 213 : 242 310 302 * Family and labor income (j[) 231 1 268 311* 639 * Net family farm income («6) 190 • 240 295* 496

Difference significant at the 99 percent level * Difference significant at the 95 percent level 312 nonlabor farm expenses on plant employee farms and on other farms were slight in each area, so that family and labor income was lower on plant employee farms than on other farms. The difference in farm income was much more pronounced in Scarriff than in Tubbercurry. In Scarriff, plant employee farms had a mean family and labor income of .^311, compared to £639 on other farms, a difference.of /328 which was sig­ nificant at the 95 percent level. In Tubbercurry, plant employee farms had a mean family and labor income of 06231, which was jC37 less than the mean family and labor income on farms whose operators did not obtain plant employment. The data presented in Table 78 are the actual data per­ taining to the different groups of farms for the year imme­ diately prior to the study being conducted. As such, the data pertaining to plant employee farms relfect the combined influence of the selectivity factors and of the direct indus­ trialization effects on these farms arising from the employ­ ment of the operators of those farms at the new plants. Evidence presented in the previous chapter.suggests that substitution effects following plant employment of farm opera­ tors occurred more frequently on Tubbercurry farms than on Scarriff farms. The data in Table 78 support this viewpoint. It will be observed that the mean number of family members doing some farm work on farms operated by plant employees in Tubbercurry was slightly higher than the mean number doing 313 some farm work on other farms in the area. Such was not the case in Scarriff, As noted, the mean number of manhours of all family labor used was only slightly less on plant employee farms than on other farms in the Tubbercurry area, whereas a large difference was apparent in the Scarriff area. Thus, in Tubbercurry, other family members provided a much greater share of the farm labor on plant employee farms than on other farms in the area, while in Scarriff this was not so. Similarly, the number of days of labor hired on farms whose operators had plant employment was slightly greater than on other farms in the Tubbercurry area. Once again, the reverse was true in Scarriff, These greater substitutions on Tubbercurry farms for the loss of farm operator labor would lessen any differences which might exist between incomes on farms operated by plant employ­ ees and on other farms in the Tubbercurry area,. While the farm output and income differences observed in Tubbercurry are not statistically significant at the 95 percent level, it may be claimed that this was largely a result of the relatively small number of farm operators, employed at the plant. Since only 15 operators were employed at the plant, mean differences between a sample of this size and the population of farm operators would need to be quite large before statistical, significance at the 95 percent level would occur. 314

All of the farm output and farm income differences between plant employee farms and other farms in the Tubbercurry area, though relatively small in magnitude, are in the direction expected on a priori grounds. It was expected that farm operators who obtained plant employment would tend to have smaller farm output and farm income levels than those not ob­ taining plant employment, since it was expected that operators of lower income farms would offer their labor services to indus­ try more frequently than would other farm operators. Since all of the observed farm output and farm income differences between farm operator plant employees, and other farm operators, in the Tubbercurry area were in the expected direction, it may well be that real differences existed between the two groups of farm operators in the area. However, because of the small sample size, it is not possible to conclude at the 95 percent level that the data regarding these observed differences confirm the existence of real differences .in farm output and farm income characteristics between farm operators employed at the Tubbercurry plant and farm operators not em­ ployed at the Tubbercurry plant. The obviously high magnitude of the substitution effects on the Tubbercurry farms would tend to narrow the farm income differences. It will also be recollected that a majority of farm operators who obtained plant employment in both areas reported that the value of farm output had increased or at 315 least remained unchanged as a direct result of plant employ­ ment (through the substitution effects and the farm invest­ ment effects from„.increased household income). Hence, ori­ ginal differences in farm output and farm income between plant employee farms and other farms would be likely to be greater than the differences observed in Table 78. Finally, as the number"of farm operators employed at the new plants who did not subsequently change their farm work association was 15 in Tubbercurry and I7 in Scarriff, rela­ tively large differences in farm characteristics would need to be observed before high statistical significance in mean differences would be achieved. The evidence presented in this section, though stronger in the case of Scarriff than of Tubbercurry, suggests that farm operators who obtained plant employment were more likely to be younger than those who did not obtain plant employment, were more likely to have had some post-primary education, and were more likely to come from smaller, though more inten­ sively operated farms, havii^ lower farm sales, farm output, farm income and value of machinery and equipment than on farms whose operators did not obtain plant employment.

B. Nonheads of Farm Households

Certain personal characteristics of nonhead of farm house, holds (apart from operators) who were employed at the new 316 plants were compared with, the same characteristics of nonheads of farm households who were not employed. The comparison was made against the characteristics of those nonheads of other farm households who belonged to age group from 14 to 64 years inclusive. The mean age of the nonheads of farm households employed at the Tubbercurry plant was 20,5 years, while the mean age of nonheads of farm households who were not employed at the plant and who were in the working age group was 33.9 years. This difference was found to be significant at the 99 percent level. Similarly, the mean age of employed nonheads of farm households in Scarriff was 26.4 years, compared with a mean age of 35«5 years for those not employed at the plant, the difference being significant at the 95 percent level. In Tubbercurry, the proportion of employee nonheads of farm households who had obtained some post-primary education was 69 percent, compared with 35 percent among those who did not obtain plant employment. The difference was significant . at the 99 percent level. Similarly, the employed nonheads of farm households in Tubbercurry had a mean of 2.25 years of post-primary educa­ tion, as opposed to a mean of 0.92 years for the group not employed at the plant. This difference was also significant at the 99 percent level. 317

In Scarriff on the other hand, the proportion of employed nonheads who had received some post-primary education (^9 per­ cent) exceeded the proportion among those not employed at the plant (32 percent). Similarly, the mean number of years of post-primary education obtained by employed nonheads of farm households (1.24 years) exceeded that obtained by those not employed (0.92 years). However, these differences were not significant at the 95 percent level. This evidence suggests that in both areas there was a high degree of selectivity based on age involved in the ob­ taining of plant employment by nonheads of farm households. Post-primary education was also important in Tubbercurry in this regard, but not as important in Scarriff.

C. Heads of Urban Households

Prom data collected in the survey of the^.heads of. urban households which contained no plant employees, personal characteristics of those heads were extracted for comparison with the same characteristics of heads of urban households who had obtained plant employment. Once again, as shown in Table 79, a strong selectivity based on age was apparent. This was significant at the 99 percent level in each area. In Tubbercurry, whether or not heads of urban households had obtained post-primary education Table 79. Comparison of personal characteristics of heads of urban households employed at the new plants and heads of urban households containing no plant employees

Tubbercurrv Scarriff Plant Other Plant Other Characteristic employees heads employees heads

** ** ** *•} Mean age (years) 33.38 54.26 40.86 55.05

Mean post-primary education (years) 1.96 1.63 1.00 1.39 ** ** Percent having post-primary education 73.07 40.27 32.00 33.76 * * Mean household size 2.84 3.38 4.10 3.13

Difference significant at the 99 percent level * Difference significant at the 95 percent .level 319 was a highly significant factor though it appeared that this was, as in the case of farm operators, more important than the actual amount of post-primary education received. Post-primary education was not a factor involved in selectivity affecting the plant employment of heads of urban households in Scarriff. However, the difference in size of household between those heads of urban households employed at the plant and those heads of households which contained no plant employees was significant at the 95 percent level. Other things being equal, heads of households containing more numbers would be expected to have a greater incentive to seek plant employment than would heads of smaller house­ holds, because of greater requirements of income. However, such a selectivity factor could be easily outweighed by other selectivity factors, especially those involving the hiring policies of the new firm. It is therefore of interest to note that in the case of heads of urban households in the Scarriff area, among whom only slight post-primary educational differences were noted, a significant selectivity based on household size was evident.

D. Nonheads of Urban Households

Characteristics of nonheads of urban households who ob­ tained plant employment were compared with those of nonheads of urban households containing no plant employees. Only those nonheads of urban households in the 14-64 year working- 320 age group were considered in making the.comparison. Once again, a highly significant selectivity based on age was apparent. Urbah nonheads employed at the Tubbercurry plant had a mean age of 22.08 years; those not employed at the plant had a mean age of 30.30 years. In Scarriff, the corresponding figures were 22.0 years and 33-05 years res­ pectively. The difference in each case was significant at the 99 percent level. The comparison of nonheads of urban households based on education was quite interesting. The mean number of years of post-primary education obtained by nonheads of urban house­ holds who were not employed at the plant was higher than that obtained by those who were employed. Nonheads of urban hoxcseholds who were not employed at the plant had a mean of 3.25 years of post-primary education while those employed at the plant had a mean of 2.16 years.

The difference was significant at the 95 percent level. The corresponding figures for nonheads of urban households in. the Scarriff area were 2.16 and I.76 years respectively. These data indicate that, especially in Tubbercurry, the selectivity factors based on education tended to favor the employment of persons having about 2 years of post-primary education. It is of interest to note that this is the length of the basic vocational school course, while the secondary school course of study is of longer duration. This selectivty 321 on. the. basis of post-primary education is as might be expected on.an a priori basis, since plant managers would be more likely to.have hiring policies which favor the employment of those having vocational shcool as opposed to nontechnical secondary school, training. 322

XIV. SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS

In an attempt to generate additional employment oppor­ tunities in Western Ireland, the Irish government has assisted the establishment of many new manufacturing plants" in pre- • dominantly rural areas. The present, study was designed to in­ vestigate the impact of such industrialization on two areas in Western Ireland, one around Tubbercurry, County Sligo and the other around Scarriff, County Clare, in both of which medium sized industrial plants had been located. Hypotheses were developed regarding the likely effect of the new industrial plants on employment, population, incomes and expenditure in the two areas. It was also expected that some farm people would obtain employment at these plants and hypotheses were developed regarding the expected effects of plant employment on farm businesses in the two areas. An area was delineated around each plaint and the effects of the plant on that area investigated. In general, it was found that the plants had had a sub­ stantial direct employment effect on the two areas. It was estimated that the plants had directly increased employment in the Tubbercurry area by 133 persons and in the Scarriff area by 134 persons, relative to the level of employment which would have been obtained in these areas in the absence of the new plants. About three fourths of these Tubbercurry 323-324 employees and about half of the Scarriff employees would, in the absence of the new plants, have gone to places outside Ireland in search of employment. Nearly all of the employ­ ment effects occurred within a radius of 12 miles of the new plants. ; The direct population effect on the two areas was esti­ mated as an increase of 231 in the Tubbercurry area and an increase of 318 in the Scarriff area relative to what the population would have been in the two areas in the absence of the two plants. The employment and population effects were greater in and close to the towns in which the new plants were located. About three fourths of the plant employées reported that an increase in their household incomes had occurred as a result of their obtaining employment at the new plants. Some people had returned from abroad in order to take employment at the new plants. Most of these people had experienced a reduction in household income. Part of the increased household income was placed in savings accounts, but most of it was spent. However, not all was spent within the areas. Many respondents reported spending the major part of their increased income in towns outside the areas. These leakages would tend to reduce the indirect effects of industrialization which would be generated by a multiplier effect on employment and incomes in the two 325 areas. Within the two areas, there was some shift in shop­ ping from outlying towns to the towns in which the plants were located. Such shopping shifts tended to feature such items as groceries more frequently than durable items. Many farm residents obtained employment at the new plants. However, relatively few of these, 15 in Tubbercurry and 1? in Scarriff, were farm operators. In the majority of cases, employment of farm operators at the new plants did not lead to a reduction in their farm output. In fact, in many instances, farm operators reported an increase in farm output as a result of their plant employment. Considerable labor substitution occurred on farms whose operators had taken plant employment. Often, the operator gave up some former leisure time tin order to do farmwork. Rising earlier and working into evening time were reported in many instances. Farmers* wives and other family members usually- did more farm work than formerly on these farms, so that, in many cases, total amount of time spent by all the farm family at farm work did not decrease. Increased use was also made of the farmers* own machinery and equipment and hired machinery and equipment tended to be used more frequently as a result of the operator obtaining plant emplosrment. In addition tc these substitution effects, there were also strong farm investment effects from the increased house­ hold income obtained by farm operators who obtained•plant 326 employment. Some of these operators bought or rented extra land. Most operators bought additional livestock. Invest­ ment in fertilizers .was frequently mentioned. As a result of these substitution and investment effects, plant employ­ ment of farm operators did not, in general, result in re­ ductions in farm output. In general, in both areas, plant employment of farm operators led to a shift from labor-intensive to labor-exten­ sive enterprises on their farms. Decreases occurred in acreage of grain, root and green crops and corresponding in­ creases occurred in the acreage under grassland. In general, also, there was a reduction in numbers of pigs and an increase in the number of dry cattle kept. Evidence obtained during the study indicates that there were important selectivity factors at work in both areas which led to differences being apparent between those area residents who obtained plant employment and those who did not. Farm operators who obtained plant employment tended to come from smaller than average farms in each area, having smaller than average inventories of farm machinery and equipment. Their farms, however, tended to have been operated somewhat more intensively, in terms of cropping pattern, than other farms in the two areas. Farm output and farm income tended to have been lower on these farms than on others in the areas. Such farm operators would have had greater incentive 32? to seek plant employment in order to obtain extra income. Selectivity was also associated with personal character­ istics, Farm operators employed at the plants were more likely to be younger than average and were more likely to hav had some post-primary education. These selectivity factors applied not only to farm operators but also to nonheads of farm households, heads of urban households and nonheads of urban households. Within each of these groups, those people who obtained plant employment were more likely to be younger than those who did not. Selectivity regarding education was more pronounced in the Tubbercurry area, where the general level of skills required at the plant was higher than in the case of the Scarriff plant. This study demonstrated that in the two areas, indus­ trialization had led to increases in employment, population and incomes. Industrialization had also led to the acceptance of nonfarm employment by some farm people. When farm operators were employed, reductions in their farm output were not usually necessitated as a result of their plant employment. These." effects, arising from the location of. medium.sized industrial plants in small towns tended to pervade through an area having a radius of about 12 miles around the plants. Further research deemed desirable would involve a com­ parison of the magnitude and spatial incidence of the direct effects.of-medium sized industrial establishments located in 328 predominantly rural areas with the magnitude and spatial incidence of the direct.effects of the location of larger industrial establishments in industrial estates, such as that at Shannon Airport. Another avenue of exploration which would complement the present study would involve estimation of the indirect effects of industrialization on the two areas studied. Such indirect effects would arise from changes in the external > environment in which firms and households function. The total impact of industrialization on these areas would include the direct effects estimated in the present study and the in­ direct effects which would result via a multiplier effect. 329

LITERATURE CITED

Almon, Clooper. Origins and relation to agriculture of industrial workers in Kingsport, Tennessee. Jour­ nal of Farm Economics 38: 826-823. 1956. Andrews, Wade H. and Bauder, Ward W. The effects of industrialization on a rural county: comparison of social change in Monroe and "Noble Counties of Ohio. Ohio Agricultural Research and Development Center Agricultural Economics Department Series 407. , • and Rogers, Everett M. Benchmarks for rural area industrialization: a study of rural development in Monroe County, Ohio. Ohio Agricultural Experiment Station Research Bulletin 870. i960. Arensberg. Conrad M. The Irish countryman. New York, N.Y., The Macmillan Company. 1937. 1 and Kimball, Solon T. Family and community in Ireland, Cambridge, Mass., Harvard University Press, 1940. Attwood, E. A, and Geary, R. C. Irish county incomes in i960. Irish Economic Research Institute Paper I6. 1963. Aubrey, Henry G. Deliberate industrialization. Social Research I6; 158-182. 1949. Balough, Thomas. The economics of poverty. New York, N.Y., The Macmillan Company, 1966. Barbichon, Guy, Adaptation and training of rural workers for industrial work. Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development Labor Mobility Series No, 2, 1962. Bauer, P, T, Economic,analysis and policy in underdeveloped countries, Durham, N,C,, Duke University Press. 1957. Beijer, G. National rural manpower: adjustment to industry. Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development Labor Mobility Series No. 3. 1965; 330

12. Bellerby, J. R. Agriculture and industry; relative income. New York, N.Y., St. Martin's Press. 1956. 13. Bertrand, Alvin L. and Osborne, Harold W. Sural industrialization in a rural Louisiana community. Louisiana Agricultural Experiment Station Bulletin 524. 1959. 14. Bhagwati, Jagdish. The economics of underdeveloped countries. New York, N.Y., McGraw-Hill. Book Company. I966. .15. Black, Therel B., Fredrickson, Carmen and Maitland, Sheridan T. Rocket age industrialization of Box Elder County. Utah Agricultural Experiment Station Bulletin 420. i960. 16. Boeke, J. H. Economics and economic policy of dual societies. New York, N.Y., Institute of Pacific Relations. 1953. 17. Bonne, Alfred. Studies in economic development. London, England, Routledge and Kegan Paul. 1957. 18. Brzezinski, Zbigniew. The politics of underdevelopment. World Politics 9: 55-75. 1956. 19. Cholanovitz, Branko. Methods of industrialising under­ developed regions in Yugoslavia. In Winsemius, Albert and Pincus, John A., eds. Methods of industrial development. Pp. 153-168. Paris, France, Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development. I962. 20. Christensen, Raymond P. and Yee, Harold T. The role of agricultural productivity in economic development. Journal of Farm Economics 46: . IO5I-IO6I. 1964. 21. Christiansen, John R., Maitland, Sheridan and PajTie, John ¥. Industrialization and rural life in two central Utah counties. Utah Agricultural Experiment Station Bulletin 4l6. 1959. 22. Clawson, Marion and Held, R. Bumell. Demand for rural resources in the context of long-range national needs. Journal of Farm Economics 45: IO27-IO36. 1963. 331

23. Coale, Ansley J. and Hoover, Edgar M. Population growth and economic development in low-income countries: a case study of India's prospects. Princeton, N.J., Princeton University Press. 1958. 24. Conway, H. McKinely. Area development organizations. Atlanta, Georgia, Conway Research, Inc. 1966. 25. Currie, Lauchlin. Accelerating development: the necessity and the means. New York, N.Y., McGraw-Hill . Book Company. I966. 26. Demas, William G. The economics of development in small countries, with special reference to the Caribbean. Montreal, Canada, McGill University Press. 1965. 27. Domar, Evsey D. Essays in the theory of economic growth. New York, N.Y., Oxford University Press. 1957. 28. Donaldson, Loraine. Development planning in Ireland, New York, N.Y., Frederick A. Praeger. 1965. 29. Dovring, Folke. Unemployment in traditional agriculture. Economic Development and Cultural Change 15: 163-173. 1967. 30. Eckaus, Robert S. The factor proportions problem in underdeveloped areas. American Economic Review 55: 539-565. 1955. 31. Elkan, Walter. Uganda. In Pepelasis, Adamantios, Mears, Leon and Adelman, Irma, eds. Economic development: analysis and case studies. Pp. 215-252. New York, N.Y., Harper and Brothers. 196I. 32. Enke, Stephen. Industrialization through greater pro­ ductivity in agriculture. Review of Economics and Statistics 88-91. 1962. 33. Evans, Gordon, ed. War on want. New York, N.Y., The Macmillan Company, I962. 34. Fei, John C, H. and Ranis, Gustav. Dieveiopment of the labor surplus economy; theory and policy. Home-. wood. 111,, Richard D. Irwin,.Inc. 1964, 332

35. Pennell, Rosemary. Industrialisation and agricultural development in the Congested Districts. An Foras Taluntais Economic Research Series No. 2. 1962. 36. Prankel, H. Industrialisation of agricultural countries and the possibilities of a new international division of labour. Economic Journal 53" 188- 201. 1943. 37. Freeman, T. W. Ireland. New York, N.Y., E. P. Button, Inc. 1950. .38. Punk, Herbert J. Effects of a new manufacturing plant on business firms in an eastern Iowa community. Unpublished Ph.'D. thesis, Ames, Iowa, Library, Iowa State University of Science and Technology, 1964. 39, Purtado, Celso. Brazil. In Pepelasis, Adamantios, Mears, Leon and Adelman, Irma, eds. Economic development; analysis and case studies. Pp. 253-287. New York, N.Y., Harper and Brothers. 1961, 40, Galbraith, John K. Economic development in perspective. Cambridge, Mass., Harvard University Press, I962. 41, Hannan, Damian P. Factors involved in the migration decisions of Irish rural youth. Unpublished Ph.D. thesis. East Lansing, Michigan, Library, Michigan State University. I967. 42, Harrod, Roy P. Towards a dynamic economics. London, England, The Macmillan Company. 1948, 43, Heady, Earl 0, Research and economic development; needs, opportunities and problems. In Haroldseh, Edwin, ed. Pood; one tool in international development. Ames, Iowa, Iowa State University Press, I963, 44, and Tweeten, Luther G, Resource demand and structure in the agricultural industry, Ames, Iowa, Iowa State University Press. 1963. 45, Hirschman, Albert 0. The strategy of economic develop­ ment, New Haven, Conn,, Yale University'Press, 1958. 333

46. Htimphreys, Alexander J, New Dubliners; urbanization and the Irish family. New York, N.Y., Fordham University Press. I966 47. Ireland. Central Statistics Office. Agricultural Output for 1965. Irish Statistical Bulletin 41: 94-98. 1966. 48. . Census of population of Ireland, 1966. Volume 1. Dublin, Ireland, Stationery Office. 1962, 49. National farm survey, 1955/56 - 1957/58, final report. Dublin, Ireland, Stationery Office. 1962, 50. , Statistical abstract of Ireland, I965. Dublin, Ireland, Stationery Office. I966, 51. . Commission on Emigration and other Population Problems. Reports. Dublin, Ireland, Stationery Office. 1956. 52. . Department of Agriculture. Agriculture in the second programme for economic expansion. Dublin, Ir^and, Stationery Office. 1964. 53. . Department of Finance. Review of I966 and outlook for 1967. Dublin, Ireland, Stationery Office. 1967. 54. . An Foras Tlonscal. Statutory Report and Accounts for the Year Ended 31st March, 1956. 1956. 55. . statutory Report and Accounts for the Year Ended 31st March, I96O. I96O, 56. , Statutory Report and Accounts for the Year Ended 31st March, I96I. I96I. 57. . An Foras Tlonscal. Statutory Report and Accounts for the Year Ended 31st March, I962. I962. 58. . Statutory Report and Accounts for the Year Ended 31st March, I963. I963. 59. . Statutory Report and Accounts for the Year Ended 31st March, 1964. . 1964. 334

60. Ireland. Statutory Report and Accounts for the Year Ended 31st March, 1965. 1965. 61. . Statutory Report and Accounts for the Year Ended 31st March, 1966. 1966^ 62. Ireland, Government of. Budget, 196?. Dublin, Ireland, Stationery Office. 196?. 63. . Second programme for economic expansion. Part 1. Dublin, Ireland, Stationery Office. I963. 64. . Second Programme for economic expansion. Part 2. Dublin, Ireland, Stationery Office. 1964. 65. . Oireachtas na hSireann. Industrial Grants Act, 1959. 1959. 66. . Undeveloped Areas Act, 1952. 1952. 67. . Undeveloped Areas (Amendment) Act, 1957. 1957. 68. _. Undeveloped Areas (Amendment) Act, I963. 1963. 69. Johnson, Harry G. Economic policies towards less developed countries. Washington, .D.C., The Brookings Institution. 1967. 70. Johnston, Bruce P. and Mellor, John ¥. The role of agriculture in economic development. American Economic Review $1: 566-593. 196I. 71. Jorgensen, Dale W. The development of a dual economy. Economic Journal 71: 309-334. I96I. 72. Kaldor, Donald R., Bauder, Ward W. and Trautwein, Marvin W. Impact of new industry on an Iowa rural community. Part 1. Farming and farm living. Iowa Agricul­ tural Experiment Station Special Report 37. 1964. 73. and Saupe, William E. Estimates and projections of an income-efficient commercial farm industry in the North Central States. Journal of Farm Economics-48: 578-596. I966. 335

74. Kao, Charles H., Anschel, Kurt E. and Eicher, iCarl H. Disguised unemployment in agriculture: a survey. In Eicher, Carl L. and Witt, Lawrence, eds. Agriculture in economic development. Pp. 129-144. New York, N.Y., McGraw-Hill Book Company, Inc. 1964. 75. Kellogg, Charles E. Using agricu3.tural resources for economic development in underdeveloped countries. In Haroldsen, Edwin 0., ed. Food: one tool in international development. Pp. 148-157. Ames, Iowa, Iowa State University Press. 1962. 76. Kerr, Clark, Dunlop, John T., Harbison, Frederick H. and Myers, Charles A. Industrialism and industrial man. Cambridge, Mass., Harvard University Press, i960. 77. Keynes, John M. • The general theory of employment, interest and money. New York, N.Y., Harcourt, Brace and Company. 1937. 78. Krier, H. Rural manpower and industrial development. Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Develop­ ment Labor Mobility Series No. 1. I96I. 79. Leibenstein, Harvey. Economic backwardness and economic growth. New York, N.Y., John Wiley and Sons, Inc. 1957. 80. Leser, C. E. V. Recent demographic developments in Ireland. Social and Statistical Society of Ireland Journal 21; 179-201. 1965. 81. Lewis, John P. Quiet crisis in India. Washington, D,C., The Brookings Institution. I962. 82. Lewis, W. Arthur. Economic development with unlimited supplies of labor. Manchester School of Economic and Social Studies 22: 139-191. 1954. 83. . The principles of economic planning, London, England, Deni-s DobsOn, Limited,. 1949. 84. . The theory of economic growth. London, England, George Allen and Unwin, Limited. 1955. 85. Maitland, Sheridan T. and Friend, Heed E. Rural indus­ trialization: a summary.of five states. United States Department of Agriculture Information Bulletin 252, I96I.. 336

86. Maitland, Sheridan T. and Wilber, George L. Indus­ trialization in Chichasaw County,. Mississippi, Mississippi Agricultural Experiment Station Bulletin 566. 1958. 87. Mandelbaum, Kurt. The industrialisation of backward areas. Oxford, England, Basil Blackwell. 19^5. 88. Massacesi, Ettore. Regional economic development policies in Italy. In United States Area Hede- velopment policies, in Britain and the countries of the Common Market. Pp. 215-325. Washington, D.C., United States Government Printing Office. 1965. 89. Mount job, Alan B. Industrialization and underdeveloped countries. London, England, Hutchinson University Library. I963. 90. Myrdal, Gunnar. Economic Theory and underdeveloped regions. London, England, Gerald Duckworth and Company, Limited. 1957. 91. . An international economy. îîew York, W.Y., Harper and Brothers. 1956. 92. Nicholls, William H. "Agricultural surplus" as a factor in economic development. Journal of Political Economy 71Î 1-29. 1963. 93. . The place of agriculture in economic devel­ opment. in Eicher, Carl L. and Witt, Lawrence, eds. Agriculture in economic development. Pp. 7-^5. Hew York, N.Y., McGraw-Hill Book Company. 1964. 94. Northern Ireland. Ministry of Commerce. Produce in Northern Ireland: sell the world over. Belfast, Ireland, author. 1966. 95. Nurkse, Eagnar. Problems of capital formation in under­ developed areas. New York, N.Y., Oxford University Press. 1953. 96. O'Brien, George. The economic history of Ireland in the eighteen century. Dublin, Ireland, Maunsell and Company, Limited. 1918. 97. O'Connor, Bobert. Recent developments in the agricul­ tural economy of the Republic of Ireland. Journal of Agricultural Economics 18; 95-108. I966. 337

98. Odber, Alan J. Regional policy in Great Britain. In United States Area Redevelopment Administration, Area redevelopment policies in Britain and the countries of the Common Market, Pp, 327-^33. Washington, B.C., United States Government Printing Office, 1965. 99. Olson, Manchur. Agriculture and the depressed areas. Journal of Farm Economics 46: 984-988, 1964, 100, O'Mahony, David, The Irish economy, Cork, Ireland, Cork University Press,.1964, 101, Pepelasis, Adam A, and Panaghiostopoulos, Pan A, Surplus labor in Greek agriculture, 1953-1960, Center of Economic Research (Athens, Greece) Monograph Series No, 2, I962, 102, Quigley, Paul, The Shannon Airport development program,. In Winsemius, Albert and Pincus, John A,, eds. Methods of industrial development. Pp. 185-197. Paris, Prance, Organisation for Economic Co­ operation and Development. I962, 103. Roll, Eric, A history of. economic thought, London, England, Faber and Paber, Limited, 196I. 104, Ro s ens tein-Rodan, P. N, Problems of industrialisation of eastern and south-eastern Europe, Economic Journal 53: 202-211, 1943, 105. Rostov, ¥, ¥, The stages of. economic growth. Cambridge, England, Cambridge University Press, i960. 106. Ruttan, Vernon ¥. Agricultural policy in an affluent society. Journal of Farm Economics 48: 1100- 1120, 1966. 107. Ryan, W, J, L, and O'Donoghue, M, The Republic of Ireland, In Wilson, Thomas, Ed, Papers on regional development. Pp. 88-101. Oxford, England, Basil Blackwell. I965. 108, Schultz, Theodore W, The role of government in pro­ moting economic growth. In "White, Leonard D,, ed. The state of the social sciences, Pp, 372-383. Chicago, 111,, University of Chicago Press, 1956, 109. , Transforming traditional agriculture. New Haven, Conn,, Yale University Press, 1964,

\ 338

110. Smith, Adam. An inquiry into the nature and causes of the wealth of nations. New York, N.Y., Modern Library. 1937. 111. Smith, Eldon D. Restrictions on policy alternatives relating to underdeveloped regions of developed countries. Journal of Farm Economics 48: 1227- 1231. 1966. . 112. Solli, Helge. A preliminary investigation of the effects of industrialization on agriculture in Sana, Northern Norway.• Mimeographed, Vollebekk, Norway, Institute of Agricultural Economics and Farm Management, The Agricultural College of Norway. 1958. 113, Solow, Robert, A contribution to the theory of econo­ mic growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics 70: 65-94. 1956, 114, Spengler, Joseph J. Mercantilist and physiocratic growth theories. In Hoselitz, Bert F,, ed. Theories of economic growth. Pp. 3-64. Glencoe, 111., The Free Press, i960. 115, Staley, Eugene and Morse, Richard, Modern small industry for developing countries. New York, N.Y., McGraw-Hill Book Company, I965. ' 116, 8tames, George T., Wilkins, William M. and Wisman, Paul P. The labor force of two rural industrial plants. Charlottesville, Virginia, Bureau of Population and Economic Research, University of Virginia. 1951. 117, Stepp, J. M, and Plaxico, J. S. The labor supply of a rural industry: a case study of the McCormick (S.C.) Spinning Mill. South Carolina Agricul­ tural Experiment Station Bulletin 376. 1948. 118. Stevens, J, B, and Wallace, L, T, Impact of industrial development on Howard.County, Indiana: 1947- 1960, Indiana Agricultural Experiment Station Research Bulletin 784. 1964. 119. Trautwein, Marvin W. Effects of industrialization on the agriculture of an eastern Iowa community. Unpublished Ph.D. Thesis. Ames, Iowa,;Library, Iowa State University of Science and Technology, 1961. 339

120. United Nations. Department of Economic and Social Affairs. Establishment of industrial estates in underdeveloped countries. New York, N.Y., author. I961. 121. U. S. Bureau of Labor Statistics. Labor supply and mobility in a newly industrialized area. U.S. Department of Labor Bulletin 1261. I96O. 122. Vercruijsse, Emile V, W. Shannon hinterland survey, 1961. Preliminary Report. Mimeographed. Leyden, Netherlands, Leyden University Sociological Institute, ca. 1964. 123. Viner, Jacob, Some reflections on the concept of dis­ guised unemployment, Indian Journal of Economics 38: 17-23. 1957. 124. Wadsworth, H. A, and Conrad, J. M, Impact of new industry on a rural community. Indiana Agricul­ tural Experiment Station Research Bulletin 811. 1966. 125. and . Leakages reducing employment and income multipliers in labor-surplus rural areas. Journal of Farm Economics 47: 1197-1202. I965." 126. Wharton, Clifton R. Modernizing subsistence agriculture. In Weiner, Myron, ed. Modernization: the dynamics of growth. Pp. 258-269. New York, N.Y., Basic Books, Inc, i960, 127. Whitaker, T, K, Economic development, . Dublin, Ireland, Stationery Office, 1958. 128. Young, Arthur, A tour in Ireland with general observa­ tions on the present state of that kingdom. London, England, T, Cadell and J, Dodsley, 1780, 340

XVI. ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS

Professor Donald R. Kaldor is deserving of the author*s deepest gratitude for the guidance, direction, encouragement and intellectual stimulation which he has given the author v during his graduate study. Professor Kaldor has freely given of his time and energy when thè author was in need of counsel or advice on matters academic or nonacademic. His many help­ ful suggestions have enhanced considerably the final form of this dissertation. The author would also like to thank the other members of his graduate committee. Professors Earl 0, Heady, Eugene A. Brady, Wayne A, Fuller and Frank F. Eiecken, for their guidance of his graduate study. Considerable financial assistance in carrying out the present study was given to the author by the Central Statistics Office, Dublin and the Economic Research Institute, Dublin. The author would like to express his deep appreciation to these two organizations and to their then directors. Dr. M. D. McCarthy and Dr. R. C, Geary. A substantial grant was also received from the Agricultural Development Council. Without this support the study could not have been conducted. In Ireland, the author benefitted from helpful discussions with Professor Robert 0 * Connor, Reverend Professor James Kavanagh, Reverend Dr. Conor Ward and Dr. Louis P. F. Smith-. 3^1

Professor Kavanagh and Dr. Ward assisted the author in the recruitment of field staff and generously loaned some of their own interviewing staff. The author would like to thank all of the interviewers who worked on this study. In particular, Miss Ethel Laughlin deserves special mention. The author is particularly grateful to the management personnel of the plants in Tuhbercurry and Scarriff for their co-operation in the study. The author was facilitated in every way and would like to express his deep gratitude for all the facilities given to_.him at the plants. Special thanks are due to the many respondents who took time and pains to dili­ gently answer all the questions asked them. Mrs. Sue Klasi deserves deep thanks for typing this dis­ sertation under rushed conditions and at short notice. The author*s parents, Michael and Joan Lucey, have made many sacrifices to provide the author with an education. The author is deeply grateful to them both and hopes that this dissertation, the culmination of his formal training, will provide satisfaction for them. The author*8 wife. Sheila, has provided the author with "many nameless unremembered acts of kindness and of love". Her devotion, encouragement and assistance during the course of this study cannot be adequately described here. Last of all, and least in size, the author's baby daughter Mary Catherine, by her arrival during the course of the present study, had added a new dimension to life. 3^2

XVII. APPENDIX A

This appendix contains a listing of the Rural Districts and District Electoral Divisions included in the study areas.

A. The Tubbercurry Area

The Tubbercurry area comprised the Rural District of Tubbercurry, County Sligo, together with the District Electoral Divisions of Kilfree, Kilshalvey No. 1 and Kilshalvey No. 2 in Boyle No. 2 Rural District, County Sligo, the District Electoral Divisions of Ballymote and Carrickbanagher in Sligo Rural District, County Sligo and the District Electoral Divi­ sions of Cloonmore, Doocastle, Kilbeagh, Sonnagh and Tungesh in Swlnford Rural District, County Mayo.

B. The Scarriff Area

The Scarriff area comprised the Rural District of Scarriff, County Clare, together with the District Electoral Divisions of Fahsrmore, Eillokennedy, Kilseily and Lackareagh in Meelick Rural District, County Clare and the District Electoral Divisions of Ballinahinch, Glandree, Killaneena, and Loughea in Tulla Rural District, County Clare. 3^3

XVIII. APPENDIX B 344

FOR OFFICE USE.

Countjr R .D. D.E.D. Household

Interviewer Date Time started

STUDY OF EFFECTS OF INDUSTRIAL DEVELOPMENT ON SELECTED AREAS OF RURAL IRELAND

(Department of Economics and Sociology, Iowa State University, U.S.A., in cooperation with Central Statistics Office and The Economic Research Institute, Dublin, Ireland).

Schedule I - All Plant Employees

A. GENERAL INFORMATION 1. Name

2. Postal Address (street or townland)

(town)

(county)

3. Has anybody else in your house worked at this factory during 1966?^

Wife Husband sons (number)

daughter (number) others (state relation and number ) 4, Now I would like to ask some general questions about yourself, and the other members of your family living with you. Relation Sex Married (m) Years Main Occupation Name to M Single (s) schooling durring You or Widowed (w) p s. V u Most of 1966 Last Week P a b 0 d e f g h i j

Insert Code 1, Operate farm. 7o Look for work. 2, Unpaid worker of family farm, 8. Go to school. 3o Farm work for wages, 9. Keep house. 4, Non-farm wage work, 10. Retired, 5* Operate non-farm business 11. Unable to work. or profession. 12. Not working 6, Unpaid worker in family (unemployed). Non-farm business. 13. Other (specify) B. RESIDENCE AND MIGRATION - OBTAIN INFORMATION ON ALL MOVES SINCE I966, Please tell me about the places you have lived, starting with your present home.

5. Period 6» Location 7. Was this house 8, . If Yes What was your (a) a farm (b) Rural How far from main reason from to P.O. County house non-farm nearest for moving to house town? this house (code)

Code for 9< 1. More comfortable0 6. Closer to job. 2. Seeking work in 7. Got married. that Community. 8. Cheaper. 3. Needed more room. 9. Wanted own home 4. Moved in with relations. 10. Other (specify) 5» Closer to relations. C. WORK HISTORY - LIST DATES OP EMPLOYMENT TO NEAREST MONTH AND YEAR. ASK FOR IN- INFORMATION ON ALL WORK SINCE 1956, STARTING WITH RESPONDENT'S PRESENT JOB. Now I would like to ask some questions about the work you are doing now and other work you have done since 1956. 100 Period of 12, What 13. What 1^U Employ­ 15. If (yes in l4, Employment Place kind of kind of ment how did you hap From To of work did business or Status pen to get this Employment you do? industry (code) job? (code) was it?

Code for 4, OB, Working for yourself, UP, Helping without pay in family business, WS, Working for wage or salary. Code for 5« 1. Newspaper advert, 5. Through Private Employment Agency, 2, Just applied at 6c Through Trade Union. plant office, 7, Contacted by employer, 3, Heard of job from friend» 8, Other (specify) 4, Through Labour Exchange, 348

D. WORK-RADIUS AND TRAVEL 16. How far from the factory do you live? 17o How do you normally travel to and from work? walk bus cycle • get lift motor cycle company etc. transport own car other (state h.p.) (specify) 18, How long have you travelled this way? Yr. Mo. 19. (For those not walking or cycling). How much a week does travelling to and from work cost you?

20. Have you any plans to change your way of travelling to work in the future? Yes No IP NO, SKIP TO 22 IP YES, ASK 21. 21. (a) What change will you make? (b) When?

JOB ATTITUDE 22. Do you expect the work at this factory to be fairly steady in the future? Yes • No D.K. IP YES OR NO, ASK 23. OTHERWISE SKIP TO 24. 23. Why do you think so?

24. What would you do if you were laid off from your pre­ sent job? look for another operate a factory job locally farm ' 349

look for other non-far work on a non-farm job locally farm • draw Unemployment go to England Assistance don't know other (specify)

IP ANSWER IS LOOK FOR SOME WAGE WORK LOCALLY, ASK 25. OTHERWISE SKIP TO 2?. 25. If you did not get a job locally which would you prefer? Work in Dublin. Work in England. Work in Galway. ^ No preference. IF NO PREFERENCE, SKIP TO 28. IP PREFERENCE EXPRESSED ASK 27. 26. Why?

27, Which of the following job conditions do you consider as first, second, third etc. in importance to you? (HAND CARD TO RESPONDENT). Rank a. Good working hours b. Safe and clean place to work c. Pay high enough d. Good prospects for getting ahead e. A pension plan f. Good supervision go Steady work h. A good community to live in 350

27. (cont'd.) i. Other (specify) j.

INCOME AND EXPENDITUEE EFFECTS 28. How many weeks did you work at the factory during the past 12 months weeks. 29. How much per week did you earn on average during that time? 30. How much per week would you be able to earn now in (INSERT NAME OP TOWN) if this factory were not here? 31. Would you have stayed on working locally for that wage? Yes No D.K IP YES, SKIP TO 34. IP NO, ASK 32. 32. Where would you have gone . 33 0 How much per week would you be earning there now? SKIP TO 35. 34. Why so?

35» About how much per week were you earning during the year before you took your present job? ' 36. What was the main reason for deciding that you would take this job? Earn extra money Other (specify)

37. What was the main reason for wanting extra income Get out of debt Purchase car Purchase clothes Buy farm eqpt. 351

37. (cont'd.) Buy household eqpt. Other (specify) 38. After allowing for any expenses involved in your pre­ sent job, did this job increase your family income? YES NO D.K. IP YES, ASK 39. IF NO, SKIP TO 42. 39. Approximately how much per year would you estimate this added income to be? ASK RESPONDENT TO CHOOSE INCREMENT' LEVEL ON CARD. BE SURE THAT THE ANSWER REFERS TO THE INCREASE AND NOT TOTAL INCOME. 1 - 49 200 - 249 ' 400 - #9 50 - 99 250 - 299 450 - 499 100 - 149 300 - 349 500 - 549 150 - 199 350 - 399 550 or more 4b. How did you use, or how do you plan to use the extra income? (^) or ( ) or (RANK) Purchase farm equipment Purchase household equipment Purchase car Purchase clothing Educational expenses ^ P.O. Sav. Bank or Sav. Certs. Other savings Other (specify) 41. In what town was the extra income mainly spent? 42. As a result of working in (INSERT NAME OF TOWN), have you or other members of your household done more shopping in (INSERT NAME OP TOWN) than you did before? YES NO IP YES, ASK 43. IP NO, SKIP TO 46, 352

43. Have you done less shopping in other towns? YES WO IF YES, ASK 44.- IP NO, SKIP TO 46. 44. Which towns? (LIST). 45. Ifhat kinds of goods and services have been involved in this shift- in your shopping pattern? (Check one or more). Groceries ; Clothing Hardware ; Drugs and cosmetics Doctor and dental services Entertainment services Petrol, oil and car repair ^ Newspapers and magazines Furniture and household appliances Other (specify)

46. If all your moving expenses were paid how much per week would you need to get in (Limerick) (Sligo) before you would go to live and work there? 47. What would be the biggest advantage of living and working in (Limerick) (Sligo)? 48« What would be the biggest disadvantage' of living and working in (Limerick) (Sligo)?

TRAINING IP FEMALE, SKIP TO 50. IF MALE, ,ASK 49. 49, Did you get any training, in farming through the following? 353

Period of trainin;? (months) a» Vocational School "b. Secondary School c. Winter Farm School d. Agricultural College e« Instructor's Might Classes' f. Other (specify)

50. Did you have any training for non-farm jobs? Uo For what Period of training occupation (monthsT a. Vocational School b. Secondary School c. Night classes d. Commercial School e. On-the-job Training f. Other (specify)

51. Do you intend to undergo any training in the next two years? YES NO ' DON'T KNOW

IF NO OR D.K., SKIP TO 53. IF YES, ASK 52. 52, What training do you intend to get?

H. LEVEL OF LIVING 53. Which of the following items, do you own (or have the use of) in your home? 35^

IP YES. did IP NO, do you you get this plan to pur­ as a result chase in the Yes No of having next two years? your present iob? Yes Wo a. Cold running water — b. Hot running water c. Plush toilet d. Bath

e. Badio ' f. Television set g. Telephone ho Washing machine i. Electric cooker j. Car ko

5^. How many rooms in the house? • (Do not include hallways, bathrooms, toilets, porches etc.) 55. Does your house have a separate sitting room? YES NO IF NO, SKIP TO 57. IP YES, ASK 56. 56. What floor-covering is in the sitting room? carpet. linoleum. other (specify) 355

57. What king of lighting do you have in the house? electricity. gas. oil lamps, other (specify) . 58. (a) When was the house built (approximately)? . (b) What was it built with? stone and mortar. concrete. brick. other (specify) . (c) What type of roof is on it? slate. tiles. galvanised iron or asbestos, thatch. other (specify) . 59. (a) Is a daily newspaper bought in your home?

YES NO . (b) How many local papers do you get? . 60. Would you like to see more expansion of manufacturing activity here or in other local towns in the future?

YES NO D.K. .

61. Why? 356

K. CLASSIFICATION 62, Do you live on a farm now? Yes ' No IF YES, ASK 63. IF NO, SKIP TO 66. 63. On how many days did you do some work (apart from upkeep) on this farm during the past Ï2 months? days. IF RESPONDENT WORKED ON THE FARM, ASK 64. OTHER­ WISE SKIP TO 66. 6-^h, Were you paid a fixed wage for this? YES NO 65» Who decides what crops are grown and what livestock are kept on the farm? NOTE; A PERSON IS A FARM OPERATOR IF (1) HE IS NOT PAID A FIXED WAGE (2) HE DID SOME WORK (APART FROM UPKEEP) ON THE FARM FOR 70 OR MORE DAYS DURING THE PREVIOUS YEAR AND (3) HE PERFORMS DECISION MAKING FUNCTIONS ON THE FARM. IF RESPONDENT IS A FARM OPERATOR COMPLETE FAEÎM OPERATOR SCHEDULE. IF RESPONDENT IS A NONOPERATOR FARM WORKER, COMPLETE FARM WORKER (NON OPERATOR) SCHEDULE AND ASCERTAIN WHO IS THE FAEiM OPERATOR. IF NEITHER, ASK 66. 66. Did you live on a farm just before taking your pre­ sent job? Yes No IP YES, ASK 67. IP NO, TERMINATE INTERVIEW. 67. On how many days per year used you do some work (apart from upkeep) on the farm then? days. IF RESPONDENT WORKED ON THE FARM ASK 68. OTHERWISE TERMINATE INTERVIEW. 680 Were you paid a fixed wage for this? Yes No 357

69. Who decided what crops were grown and what livestock were kept on the farm? IP RESPONDENT WAS A FARM OPERATOR, COMPLETE FARM OPERATOR SCHEDULE. IF RESPONDENT A NONOPERATOR FARM WORKER, COMPLETE FARM WORKER (NONOPERATOR) SCHEDULE AND ASCERTAIN NAME AND ADDRESS OF OPERATOR. IF NEITHER, TERMINATE INTERVIEW.

Time completed