ILLEGAL IMMIGRATION IN AMERICA A Reference Handbook

Edited by David W. Haines and Karen E. Rosenblum

GreenwoodPress Westport, Connecticut •London Contents

Preface xi

1. Introduction: Problematic Labels. Volatile Iss�s 1 David W. Haines andKaren E. Rosenblum

PART L CONCEPTS, POUCJFS,AND NUMBERS

2. Labor Migration, Family Integration, and the New 'America 13 Karen A. Woodrow-Lafield

3. Undocumented Immigration to the : Num�. Trends, and Characteristics 27 Jeffrey S. Passel

4. Mexico and U.S. Policy on : A Fifty-Year Retrospective 112 KatharineM. Donato andRebecca S. Carter

PART ll. THE l\11GRANTS ANDTHEWORK

5. Unauthori7.ed Workers in U.S. Agriculture: Old versus New Migrations 133 PhiUp L. Martin 470 lliegal Immigration in Perspective

Vasta, Ellie 1993 Rights and Racism inaNew CountryImmigration: of TheItalian Case. Racism In andMigration in Western Europe. Edited byI. Wrench and I. Solornos. Oxford: Berg Press. Pp. 83-98. Werner, Heim 1994 Regional Economic Integration and Migration: A European Case. Annals of the American AcademyPolitical of and Social Science 534: 147-164. Wrench, John, and John Solomos, F.ditors 20 1993 Racism andMigration in Western Europe. Oxford: Berg Press.

Illegal Immigrationin Asia: Regional Patterns and a Case Study of Nepalese Workers in Japan Keiko Yamanaka

By the early 1990s Asia had become one of the most active sites of international labor migration in the world. This was primarily due to its rapidly developing economy and the increasing regional integration that resulted in growing eco­ nomic disparity between a few rich countries and the many poor neighbors in their region. illegal immigration, a significant contributor to regional economic development, has emerged as a volatile political issue since the late 1980s. The five developed countries with mature economies-Japan, Korea, Taiwan, , and Singapore-currently import labor, whereas the two recent devel­ opers, and , import labor and simultaneously export surplus labor.1 Most neighbors of these seven labor importers in East, Southeast,and South Asia suffer from stagnant economies and large populations and therefore export abundant surplus labor to the former. By 1998, the dynamics of regional labor exchange were rapidly changing as the recent economic crisis hit most Asian countries. In many countries, such as Korea, Thailand, and , much wealth that had been accumulated as a result of people's hard work during the period of prosperity was reduced over­ night to a fraction of its former magnirude, and the once-plentiful employment opportunities abruptly disappeared. As a result, immigrant worlrers who were once welcomed in the labor-importing countries became scapegoats for their frustrated citizens. Conversely, emigration as an alternative means for economic survival appealed even more than before to desperate citirens in the poor, labor­ exporting countries. Here I focus on illegal immigration in Asia up to 1997, when the economic crisis began to take a heavy toll of Asia's immigrants. Although the crisis hasalready exerted enormous impact on regional labor mi- lliegal Immigrationin Asia 475 1.' '"" N-,..._ N �=II") ;,;�:g��=�����a:� labor-importing andexporting (Thailand andMalaysia); and (3) labor-exporting 1) (, Philippines, Indonesia, Vietnam, , Cambodia,anmar, My , -,! , Nepal, Sri Lanka, Pakistan, and ). During the decade 1985-1995, the average annual growth rate in grossdo- 00"".,.. OI - r- r- r- ·§ _.,.. ��;;;������2��� mestic product (GDP) of each of the five labor-importing countries in Asia i�II ranged from 6.5 percent for Hong Kong to 8.8 percent for Korea. Japan's eco- . ' nomic growth was comparatively small, 3 percent, during this period. but the t country's GDP accounted for56 percentof the totalGDPs of thecountries listed - 0 I() in Table 20.1. As a result of such rapid growth, average annual growth rates in :? ����� ...... ��;:,;��������.� V GDP percapita of these countriesranged from 2.6 to 7 .8 percent, which doubled � ,: individual incomes for thedecade 1985-1995. Thenation withthe highest GDP per capita in 1995 was Japan, with U.S. $25,101, followed by Singapore, Hong t- 4 "":C? I �CIC! .,...,.. ff'\�ooNOONO--"""-r,.... Kong, Taiwan, and Korea, in that order, with Korea the lowest atU.S. $8,087. o- -- ...:.N ..;N•Ntf'if:f'i�NNN..;Cf'\N Demographic indices of these countriesshown in Table 20. l furtherdemonstrate =� 1�;0 .... ! low population growth, rapidly aging populations, urban concentration, and im- l-. a: g proved quality of life (measured by the low infant mortality rate). Malaysia and Thailand, the two countries in the midst of their migrati6n -: 0) "i 'I!;"i �o. I'-; ,,a; <'l -:t"i� r-: <'i 'Ci r-: � "l 'Otn-\OC"'I �""::sf:"'""-'COINNoor-r- t"- ...... � .,; transition. also showed impressive annual grow!.� rates in GDP, 7.7 percent and I"' I<� C"ol"'lt'l"',I �;::; t!�- N � � � - !.::: l,i;, ., .! ·t: ,::- 9.4 percent, respectively, between 1985 and 1995. The GDP per capita shot up Ill g, � j £ - accordingly in each country during the decade, yielding an average annual rate - I:� ".. � 5 'i,.Q � of increase of percent for Malaysia and 8 percent for Thailand. The actual � .. D, - l()OOOO<'IN NNO.ID"" - <'!"l"':q"!q� .g figure for the 1995 GDP per capita was U.S. $3,212 for Malaysia and U.S . 6 {3 111 «-ii..:,o.,;,o q00 C! "' oo..:�, ..... § -� .,, g per !Ii � ;::- rate of nearly seven percent during the decade. As aresult, durin this pros - i 0 pe cap y ]� ; ous riod bothChina and Indonesia increased theGDP per ita annuall by 0 8.2 percent and 4.9 percent, respectively. Despite their rapid growth rates in J a � � � .,:, api :;'.l GDP per ap c ita, the actual figure for China's 1995 GDP per c ta was U.S. :a cap "1 C,l 1 • 'E $549, and forIndonesia it was U.S. $755, a mere fraction of the GDPper ita ·:! � I.• j; ::,= � J J> g r �a I � ,� i "i ] ::.. 1 "i ].§ a received by citizens of the five labor-importing countries. � i '; ·-1 I Other countries in Table 20.1, the Philippines, Vietnam, Laos, Cambodia, !IJl� j t!! §� f :i;;3S rt l}Ji�s � � ��J � � 478 lliegalImmigration in Perspective lliegal Immigration in Asia 479

the d within its , althou l v heavily on Malaysian labor force across an _ � presence of these emp oyees is often percei ed as threatening harm to the host on f le of ­ political and social power resides in the dominant � � �� _ � country's economy. Immigrant workers, by replacing domestic worlrers in low­ th nese descent (Wong 1997). Malaysia shares close ethnic and linguiSti.cti es wi skilled and low-paidjobs, raise the possibility that unemployment rates willrise , its large, bu t poor, neighbor, Indonesia, whose citiuns once freely crossed the ineffective industries will be preserved, and exploitative work conditions will d e t andthe Java Sea to Malaysia for settlement an mployme� prevail. The growing number of low-paid foreign workers may be thought to (Hugo 1993). Similarly, Hong Kong bas been an integral part of southern�­ contribute to ethnic conflict, rising crime, and disruption of the social fabric of nese culture and society, receiving hundreds ofthousands of at times the nation. Their presence is often used by politicians to arouse exaggerated of political upheaval on the mainland despite the fact that the border had been fears not only of negative economic consequences but of threat to national se­ closed since the 1949 communist revolution (Lui Ting 1987). Korea faces the curity and sovereignty. problem of an estimated 2 million people of Korean descen t whose ancestors Policymakers, caught in the dilemma between the need to import labor and fled the aftermath of the 1951-1953 Korean War to northeastern China, now the consequences of doing so, typically respond in ad hoc fashion. That is, they seekingbetter econom ic opportunities inKorea-their � tly wealthy� first permit. entry of a small number of unskilled workers to ameliorate an acute r homeland-often as illegal immigrants (Park 1995). Thailand shares, with poo labor shortage. Then, as demand for labor increases,they allow greaternumbers neighbors , Laos, and Cambodia. a long � bo� cu� across to enter. Asiano g vernments have, in this process, repeated exactly what their densejungl es andrugged hills, which presents them with the nnpossible taskof American and European counterparts did in the 1950s and 1960s. By the mid- x controlling widespread illegal immigration (Stern I�). � �� of these � ­ 1990s, however, each of the seven Asian labor-importing countries had arrived g amples, geographic proximity reinforces cultural and linguistic ties connectm at policy decisions regarding principles, legal codes, and contract labor schemes people across national . with which to d�-!ll with unskilled Immigrants. Tnemetaphor of a door is often . . . . d r ve found that these mternattonal histoncal, cultural. an pe - used in international migration literature in describing a country's immigration Past studies ha 7 th sonal ties play critical roles in international migration because �y �y fa­ policy as symbolic of the permeability of the country's borders to foreigners. d cilitate entry, employment, an d settlement in the host country (Kritz, Lim,� The policy decisions of these labor-importing nations reflect the historical ex­ n Ziotnilc. 1992). Such "a complex web of social roles and inte�o� relati� ­ perience, political ideology, and population composition of the host country. ships" (Boyd 1989: 639) leads to a rapiddev elopment of extensive info_rmatto� They can be classified into three distinctive models of principles and mecha­ th th and w th th rr networks linking migrants at their destination wi one ano er � � nisms for control of immigrants. Employing the door metaphor, these can be th o es ed m n d kinsmen at their place of origin. Once e migrants' n etw �ks are ta1?� . described as (1) the "fro t oor" policy adopted by Singapore, Hong Kong, d communities w th d d the host country, they ten to grow into small-scale ethnic . ! and Taiwan; (2) the "loose oor" policy maintainedby Malaysia and Thailan ; e ve their own institutions and enterprises (Castles an d Miller 1993: 25). R stncti and (3) the "back door" policy employed by Japan and Korea. immigration policies, fluctuating business cycles, and public opinion hostile �o Here, a country is regarded as having a ''front door policy'' when it officially ne vely affecte th deve pment of e c v l th immigrantsand ethnic minorities can gati . �� � makes contract labor programsa ailab e to unskilledforeigner s who are ereby communities. However, ethnic communities tend to remam resilient and flexible permitted to enter the country for lawful employment under closely monitored e because family and community ties sustain the flow of immigrants intoth host controls. A country bas a "loose door policy" when it makes available contract e country, while growing ethnic enterprises absorb incoming ��ants into � programs for unskilled foreigners but is unable to control its borders (forgeo­ r tnes workforce. Untilrecently, illegal immigration in Asianl abo -nnportmgco � graphic, cultural, and/or political reasons), with the result that manyimmigrants l el e e ethnic and rarely became a serious political prob em �recis y beca� clo� are able to enter unnoticed. Fmally, a country bas a "back door policy" when cultural ties absorbed migrants into the social and economic fabrics of the re- it officiallyprohibits all unskilledforeigners frombein g employed andmaintains ceiving country (Hugo I 993, 1995). effective enforcement mechanisms but in practice admits them under artificial "contract labor programs" designed to allow their entry when needed. In the ''front door policy'' countries, illegal immigration has been sharply curtailed. Immigration Policy andControl In the "loose door" and "back door" countries, however, large numbers of Host governments have tolerated illegal immigration for other impo t eco­ illegalimmigrants enter, posingserious politicaland socialproblems (see Table � 8 nomic reasons as well. Unchecked flows of unskilled foreigners alleviate � 20.2). shortages andfuel economic growth in eth shortrun (Pillai I995). The� !1rovide Front Door Policy. Singapore, Hong Kong, and Taiwan, the three major inexpensive, tractable labor much needed by industry to createcompebbve �o­ Asian countries that follow a "front door policy," import unskilled labor nomic advantage in the global market. In the long run, however, the growmg through a number of state-run programs for labor-short industries, inclµding 482 Illegal Immigration in Perspective IllegalImmigration in Asia 483 manufacturing, construction, marine, and retail and domestic and personal ser­ Thailand, whose labor importation began only in the early 1990s,has not yet vices. By the1990s all three countries had moved theirlabor-intensive produc­ developed contract labor programs for unskilled foreigners. The lack of legal tion to other countries with low labor costs, while upgrading the domestic procedures, together with ineffective bordercontrol, has leftthe country largely economy from manufacturing-based to service- and information-based. This in­ defenseless against illegalimmigration. TheThai government estimated 525,000 dustrial restructuring reduced significantly the dependence on foreign labor in illegal workers in 1994. Two-thirds of the immigrants were Burmese, manyof manufacturing industries. Foreign workers, mostly from neighboring Asian whom were ethnicminorities fleeing persecution by the militaryregime in their countries, are stillin strongdemand by employersin largec onstructionp rojects, homeland. In Thailand's southwestern, northern, and eastern border provinces, small-scale manufacturing, nursing institutions, and private homes. Because a illegal immigrantsarriv e on foot or by boat in search of employment in farming, high proportion of female immigrants w ork as domestic helpers in the three fishing, construction, textile and footwearmanufacturing, domestic service, and countries,gender plays an important role in determiningpatterns of immigration prostitution (Stem 1996; Human Rights Watch 1993). officers and their employment. Domestic service providers are predominantly from the oftenextort bribes fromilleg alentrants. Moreover, the lackof effective enforce­ Philippines but increasingly include those from Thailand and Sri Lanka (Cheng ment, together with thelow wages required, encourages Thai employers to hire 1996; Constable 1997). illegal foreigners. The Thai government has failed to establish a contract labor illegal immigration occurs, albeit small in volume, in these ''front door pol­ programfor unskill ed foreignerssuc h as those found inSingapore and M alaysia. icy" countries, despite stringent enforcement of controls. It most commonly In order to deal with the large, but unknown, number of undocumented immi­ talres the form of overstaying a valid work or tourist visa beyond its expiration grants in its country, the government introduced, between September and No­ (Sullivan, Gunasekaran, and Sununta 1992; Tsay 1992). A legal immigrantcan vember 1996, an amnesty forillegal immigrants, of whom 372,000reported and also become illegal by changing an employer v.lithcut autho1ization.Employers t.1Jere granted t\Vo-ye�-:1.r \Vork permits. This numbe.r is believe.d to representabout may violateimmigration and labor laws by failing toregister their foreign w ork­ halfof the total estimated to have been-and still remain-in the country. ers in order to evade the payment of expensive levies, security bonds, and other Back Door Policy. Japan and Korea, bothwealthy Far Ea.stem countries with fees required by law. They may also ignore the ceilings set for the maximum relatively homogeneous populations, permit foreigners to work only in selected proportion of foreignwork ers allowableby law in each industry("dependenc y skilled occupations. Despite this restrictive rule shutting the door against un­ ceilings"),the purpose of which is to maintain abalancebetween the immigr ant skilledforeigners, bothcountries are home to hundreds of thousandsof unskilled pool and the domestic labor force. Each stateim poses criminal penalties on all immigrants who have entered as legal residents, workers, and tourists. In 1990 violators-immigrants, employers, and their intermediaries. Penalties include Japan opened its doors to South Americans of Japanese descent up to the third steep fines, imprisonment, and, in the case of Singapore, three strokes of the generation, most of whom lived in Brazil. As a result more than 200,000 such cane. people were in Japan in 1996 to enter its unskilled labor market, working on Loose Door Policy. Malaysia and Thailand, with their porous borders, are assembly linesin manufacturing industries (Yamanaka 1996). Japan alsogran ts home to a large number of illegal immigrants, mostly from culturally similar limited-term visas to company "trainees," mostly from other Asian countries, and geographically adjacent neighbors of Indonesia, in the case of Malaysia, to work in similarjobs in order to learnnew skills. In 1996, there were 21,000 and Myanmar, in the caseof Thailand. TheMalaysian gov ernmentpermits mor e trainees in Japan.9 In addition, foreign students are allowed to work for twenty than 700,000 contract workers to labor in plantation agriculture, construction hours per week while pursuing their studies. Finally, female entertainers enter sites, manufacturing factories, and private homes. In the remote plantations of and work legally as singers and dancersin bars and cabaretsfor limitedperiods both peninsular and eastMalaysia, however, illegal immigrationis widespread. (Piquero-Ballescas 1992). Adding to the 300,000 such legal immigrant workers, Whileaccurate statistics areunavailable, it is estimatedthat they numberat least an estimated 284,000 illegal immigrants, mostly tourist visa-overstayers from a million. Thissignificantly weakensthe Mala ysian government's abilityto man­ other Asian countries, were working in Japan in construction, manufacturing, age its economy. Therefore, the "loose door policy" is actually less a policy and servicejo bs, long shunned by the majority middle-class Japanese. than a de facto consequence of the failure of the government to control its Korea's immigration policy resembles Japan's in its restrictions on unskilled borders. Despite considerablemonetary and physical risks,Indonesian migran ts labor but for reasons of national security gives no exemption to Chinese of employ clandestinebrokers to arrangeillegal entry andemployment in Malaysia Korean descent to worklegally in the country, as Japan does to South Americans and Singapore (and the Middle East) (Hugo 1993; Spaan 1994). Small-scale of Japanese descent to work in Japan. Like Japan, Korea manages "company Malaysian employers areinclined to hire illegalimmigrants rather thancontract trainee" programs. In 1996, 66,000Asians of diverse nationalities werein such workers, because abiding by the law entails going through a bureaucratic quag­ programs. 10 Outside of this narrow legal channel, 130,000illegal workers (twice mire and waiting several months for workers to arrive. as many as the numberof company trainees) inthecountryhad oversta yedtheir 486 IllegalImmigration in Perspective illegal Immigrationin Asia 487

Table 20.3 ilege of visa-exempted free entry into Japan. Nevertheless, despite all govern­ NepaleseEntry into, and Exitfrom, Japan: 1986-1995 mental efforts to control their entry, Nepalese have sustained a steady flow of arrivals and an increasing visa-overstayer population since 1989. This suggests Emies Exits Excess: the importance of migrants' cuJtural values, antecedent information networks, All I Short- Sex iofMales Volumary Involuntary Enlries Year tenn Visa Ratio 1S-29Yrs Exits Exits Over Ex.its and strategiesto circumvent immigration laws blockingentry to the targetcoun­ [l] [2]* {31- [4)- (SJ {6] m-- tryand to enable such migration patterns to endure over time. 1986 986 69.2 457 38.4 867 0 119 1987 1,.292 69.4 S9S 40.4 1.089 1 202 1988 1.671 76.3 S93 47.2 1.311 11 349 The Gurkha Connection 1989 2.964 83.0 818 S2.9 2,020 37 907 1990 1,671 65.2 S33 41.6 1,145 394 132 Nepal is made up of many ethnic groups, each with distinctive history, lan­ 1991 2,154 66.4 492 42.3 1.121 93 934 guage, and religion (Berreman 1963; Bista 1996). The 1991 Nepalese national 1992 1,982 60.1 44S 33.S 1,136 127 719 census listssixty ethnic andcaste groups within Ne pal's 18.5 millionpopulation 1993 1,837 S9.4 420 28.8 1,178 209 4S0 (Nepalese Central Bureau of Statistics 1996). Despitethis extraordinaryethni c 244 90 1994 2,174 S8.8 394 27.3 1,840 heterogeneity, the country's economic resources and political power have been 1995 2,686 S8.3 3SS 26.7 2.025 269 392 19,417 �-4 342 JU ll.�s IJss 4� historically monopolized by upper-caste, Nepali (i.e., Indo-Aryan)-speaking Tiiaf" Hinduelites (Brahmans and Cbbetris), accountingfor 29 percentof Nepal's 18.5 S011TCe: Japanese Ministry of Justice (1987-1996). millionpopulation. As ethnicminorities lacking political clout in nationalpolitics, * [2) and [6) show percentages of short-term visas among all entries and exits for the year, respec- Tibeto--B�ryn:m-sper,king, multiethnic, multiliugual, Buddhisti"animisC groups, !ivcly. making up 35 percent of the total population, have relied forsome 180 years •• [3) shows the numbers of males per 100 females each year. .5 ••• [4] shows the proportion of males, fifteen totwenty-nine years of age. to the total number of on recruitment into "Gurkha Brigades" of the British and Indian armies for male entrants each year. economic survival. •••• [7] = [l] - [5) - [6]. The British were mightily impressed by the skill and gallantry of their de­ feated adversaries in the Anglo-Nepalese War of 1814-1816. As a result, they tion records also reveal a gradually shifting sex ratio of men to women among were convinced that Gurkha recruitment to their own armies was essential to theNepalese entrantsbetween 1989 and 1995, from 8 to 1 in 1989, to 3.6 to 1 maintenance of their military supremacy in South Asia. Since then, Gurldias in 1995. have fought numerous wars and battles for the British in every comer of the The estimated total of 3,000 Nepalese visa-overstayers is a mere drop in the world, as early as the 1817 Pindari and Maratba Wars in India and including ocean of the estimated total of 284,000 visa-overstayers in Japan in 1996 and the two world wars, the 1982 Falkland Island War with Argentina, and as re­ thereforeposes little threat Japan's to immigration control. Significant,however, cently as the 1991 GulfWar (Cross 1985; Des Chene 1993; Pahari 1991). After is the fact that the population of Nepalese overstayers grew rapidly in the ten Indianindependen ce in 1947, most Glllkbabattalions were incorporated into the years following 1986. This pattern of Nepalese immigration growth contrasts Indian army, but some moved to with the British, where ..in­ sharply withBangladeshi andPakistani immigration. BothBangladesh and Pak­ surgents'' hadbecome increasingly active in Malaysia, Singapore, Brnnei,and istan had established mutual visa exemption agreements with Japan, enabling Indonesia. In 1970 the British moved their Gurkha Brigades to Hong Kong, their nationals to clear immigration checkpoints without difficulty. Many of where its 8,000 soldiers were deployed primarily in Border Patrols to block these arrivals proceeded to overstay their visas and engage inunauthorized em­ illegal immigrants' entrancefrom mainland China (Pahari 1991: 12). Morethan ployment(Morita and Sassen 1994; Mahmood 1994).The Japanese government 180 years of transnational experience bas established the extensive social net­ reactedhnJJIC'Aliately, canceling thevisa exem ption agreements withBangladesh works of Gurkbas, often called the "Gurkha Connection," linking soldiersand and Pakistan in January 1989. Whereas in 1988 there were 14,500Bangladeshi their families across national boundaries throughoutthe world (e.g., Banskota and 20,000 Pakistani arrivals in Japan, in 1990 entries dropped drastically to 1994). 3,400 for Bangladesh and 7,100 forPakistan andremained at thesame, or even Between November 1995 and February 1998, I conducted a study among lower, level thereafter. In 1996, 6,500 Bangladeshi and 5,500 Pakistani visa­ Nepalese immigrants currently working in Hamamatsu andToyobashi, centr.¥ overstayers were reported in Japan, representing a significant degreeof attrition Japan, and Nepalese return migrants fromJapan in Katbma:odu and Pokbara in in those populations between 1988 and 1996. centraland westernNepal, respectively. 11 Systematicinterviews and survey data Unlike theirSouth Asian predecessors, Nepalesehave never enjoyed thepriv- were collected from 159 men and thirtywomen, supplementedby informalin- illegal Immigration inPerspective illegalImmigration in Asia 491

490struction industries. Hamamatsu, a city of .5 million in western Shizuoka Pre­ areworking in construction industries, building private homes and public roads. fecture, is a center for Japan's lifeline automobile and motorcycle industries. It More half are employed by establishments with fewer thirty employ­ harborsthe headquartersof several major companies, including Suzuki,Yamaha, ees. Those who report being employed by larger establishments are hired by and Honda. Near Toyohashi, a city of 350,000 in eastern Aichi Prefecture ad­ labor contractorsthan who, in dispatch them to their jobsthan in large factories. jacent to Hamamatsu, isToyota City, home of another giant automaker, Toyota. Despite employment in such peripheral sectorsof theindustries, Nepalese work­ Altogether, Hamamatsu and Toyohashi are home to tens of thousands of ers report wages comparableturn, to those of Nikkeijin and even of Japanese c� small- to large-scale subcontractorssupplying theparts assembledby automobile workers. On the average, Nepalese men earn 1,125 yen per hour (roughly U.S. manufacturing companies ("automakers") to become vehicles. The industrial $11.25), and women earn 835 yen (U.S. $8.35). In Kathmandu, the average structure connecting an automaker with its numerous parts suppliers has histor­ monthly income for a government official or university professor is about 5,000 icallycomprised a pyramidalhierarchy of dependency.Automakers-a few very Nepal rupees (roughly U.S. $100). 15 In Tokai, an illegal, unskilled male makes large corporations that assemble automobiles-are at the top of the hierarchy. that amount in a single day. They obtain thecomponents to be assembled from large, "first-order" contrac­ A breakdown of their hourly wage data (unreported here) further revealsthat, tors who, in obtain constituent parts of the components from numerous while workers' age, education, and ethnicity/castehave little relationship to their "second-order" contractors. The process continues down to third- and even wage levels, the type of industry in which they are employed, the years spent fourth-order contractors.turn, In one instance, a single automaker drew upon 47,308 in Japan, and the number of job changes allmake small, but systematic,statis­ contractors in a three-level hierarchy (Ito 1993: 86). Statistics on Hamamatsu's tically significant differences in their earnings. This means that regardless of manufacturing establishments confirm these unequal hierarchical relationships. company size, workers' wages are higher in constructionindustries than in man­ "A._n ovenvhelming eighty seven percent nf the es!ablistunent� in the automobile industry there have fewer thirty employees, which suggests that most es­ work experience and Japanese cultural competence increase over time. More­ tablishments are small, third-order or even "fourth"-order subcontractors (Ha­ ufacturingover, comparisons or service of averageemployment monthly and wagesthat they (not tend reported to increase here) among as worke,rs' illegal mamatsu City 1991). than Nepalese, legal Nikkeijin, and Japanese workers in the manufacturing industry Immigrant workers, both legal and illegal, find this area (referred to later as demonstrate an important finding: differences in national,ethnic, or legal status the Tokai region) attractive because of its chronic labor shortage among small­ do not appear to contribute to significant wage differences. This suggests that scale subcontractors. In 1997 more 8,000 Brazilians of Japanese descent Japanese small-scale employers place a high value on Nepalese workers' will­ (called Nikkeijin. literally, people of Japanese descent) registered as long-term ingness and physical capacity for intensive labor in construction and manufac­ residents in Hamamatsu alone. Thethan number of illegal immigrants in Tokai is turing. It should be noted, however, that research clearly shows that regardless difficult to estimate, but there are substantial numbers, mostly from in­ of nationality, ethnicity, or legal status, gender divides and ranks workers in cluding an estimated 500 Nepalese.14 Following the 1990 immigration reform Japan according to well-established patterns of wage and social discrimination establishing the illegality of hiring unskilled foreigners, many JapaneseAsia, com­ against women (cf., Brinton 1993). panies, threatened by criminal penalties,replaced illegal workers with legal Nik­ keijin workers. An important question arising from the newly emerging availability of foreign workers concerns the structure of the low-skilled labor Roles of lliegal Workers force as it is stratified according to workers' collectivecharacteristics: nationality Japanese employers, although willing to pay theNepalese hourly wages nearly (whether Japanese or not), ethnicity (whether of Japanese descent or not), and equivalent to thoseof otherworkers, save significant labor costs by not granting legality (whether legal resident or not). Therelationships betweenthese workers' them the numerous expensive benefits, entitlements, and job security that are characteristics and employers' characteristics (i.e., the industry in which the granted to Japanese and (to a limited degree) legal Nikkeijin workers. Clearly, employer is engaged and the relative size of the employers' organizations) are the relatively inexpensive and flexible labor thatillegal workers offer to periph­ the subject of the next section. eral employers motivates them to employ illegals at standard wages. For them, hiring illegal workers increases profits while costing little. Although criminal penalties for hiring illegal workers have existed since 1990, the Japanese gov­ Employment and Wages ernment has rarely enforced them. This is a manifestation of the ''back door might be expected from the existing hierarchical industrial structure, 75 policy.''It suggests that the aim of the penalty codeis to discourage einployme�t percent of 150 Nepalese men and 77 percent of twenty six women work in of illegals rather to eradicate the practice. The following statement from factoriesAs manufacturing automobile parts of plastic and metal. Most of the rest an interview with the president of a manufacturing factory with twenty-seven than 494 lliegal Immigration inPerspective lliegal Immigrationin Asia 495 duelion and is therefoie largely irrelevant and unrelated to quality of life for subsistence REFERENCES farmers andpeasants in countries whose agricultural production is not directly linked to the national economy (see Nader and Beckerman 1978). Abella, Manolo I. 6. In September 1985 financial representatives of the Group of Five-the United 1994 Introduction. Asian and Pacific Migration Journal 3 (1): 1--6. States, Japan, West , France, and the -convened in the Plaza 1998 Emigration Pressures in Selected Asian Countries: Some Preliminary Fmdings. Hotel, New York City, where they issued the "Plaza Agreement," devaluing the U.S. In MigraJion and Regional Economic Integration in Asia. OECD Proceedings. dollar in relation to other major currencies (Schaeffer 1997: 48). As a result, the con­ Paris: OECD. Pp. 53-70. version rate for Japanese yen, for example, rose from 254 to the dollar in 1985 to 185 Aryal, Manisha in 1986, to 151 in 1987, and to 127 in 1988, having thus doubled in value overthese 1991 To Marry a Lahuray. Himal (July/August): 18-19. three years (Japanese Statistical Bureau 1998: 430). 1997 Gurkhas in the People's Republic. Himal South Asia (July/August): 28-29. 7. An example is David M. Reimers' Still the Golden Door (New York: Columbia Banskota, Purushottam University Press, 1992), referring to the United Statesas a destination attractive to Third 1994 The Gurkha Connection: A History of the Gurkha Recruitment in the British World immigrants in the post-1965 Immigration Act era. Anny. Jaipur, India: Nirala 8. Information in Table 20.2 is drawn from many sources: for Singapore, Soon-Beng Berreman, Gerald D. and Cliew (1995), Wong (1997), Hui (1998); for Hong Kong, Skeldon (1995) and Levin 1963 Peoples and Cultures of the Himalayas. Asian Survey 3 (6): 289-304. and Chiu (1998); for Taiwan, Tsay (1995); for Malaysia, Pillai (1995) and Pillai and Bista, Dor Bahadur People ofNepal. Yusof (1998); for Thailand, Sussangkam (1995) and Chalamwong (1998); for Japan, 1996 Kathmandu: Bhotahity. Okunishi (1995), lguchi (1998) and Japan Immigration Association (1997); for Korea, Borjas, George J. 1990 Friends or Strangers: The Impact of Immigration on the U.S. Economy. New Pad (1995. 1998). York: Basic Books. 9. Trainees are recroited through four channels: (1) governmental agencies and in­ Boyd, Monica ternational organizations; (2) private corporations; (3) intermediary organizations; and (4) 1989 Family and Personal Networks in International Migration: Recent Developments the Japan International Training Cooperation Organization. In many cases of private and New Agendas. International Migration Review 23 (3): 638-680. recruitment of trainees for subsidiaries or joint-venture companies overseas, Japanese Brinton, Mary C. employers treat trainees as substitute labor on the assembly line (Oishi 1995). 1993 Women and the Economic Miracle: Gender and Work in Postwar Japan. Berke- 10. Foreign trainees in Korea come from fourteen selectedcountries through two chan­ ley: University of California Press. nels: (1) foreign affiliates of Korean fums and (2) the Foreign Training Cooperation Caplan, Lionel Corps (FTCO) under auspices of the Korea Federation of Small Business (Park 1998). 1967 Land and Social Change in East Nepal. Berkeley: University of CalifomiaPress. 1be majority of foreign trainees arrive through the second channel and work as unskilled Castles, Stephen, and Mark J. Miller laborers in labor-short companies in the manufacturing industries. 1993 TheAge ofMigration: InternationalPopulation Movementsin the Modem World. 11. For research methods employed in this study and.findings from analyses of the New York: Guilford Press. Nepalese data, see Yamanaka(1998). Chalamwong, Yongyuth 12. Information on the current numbers of Gurkha soldiers and ex-soldiers was 1998 Dilemmas of Rapid Growth: International Migration and Cross-Border Flows in obtained in interviews with Major Dipak Bahadur Gurung (December 17, 1997, Kath­ Thailand. In Migration and Regional Economic Integration in Asia. OECD Pro­ mandu) and the Singapore Gurlcha Pensioners' Association (December 18, 1997, Kath­ ceedings. Paris: OECD. Pp. 167-173. mandu). See also Aryal (1997). Cheng, Shu-Ju Ada 13. This finding was derived from comparison of the two groups of Nepalesemigrants 1996 MigrantWomen DomesticWorkers in Hong Kong, Singapore andTaiwan.Asian to Japan: (1) the. "Gurlcha group" (N = 131), comprising members of eight nonelite, and Pacific Migration Journal 5 (1): 139-152. Tibeto-Burman language-speaking peoples; and (2) the ''non-Ourlcha group'' (N = 58), Constable, Nicole including three power elite groups: two Indo-Aryan (Nepali)-speaking castes, Brahmans 1997 Maid to Order in Hong Kong: Stories of Filipina Workers. Ithaca, New Yorlc: and Cbhetris,ne ando Tibeto-Burman-speaking group, New&IS. Cornell University Press. 14. The remaining Nepalese work�rs are mostly in the Greater Tokyo Metropolitan Cornelius, Wayne A. Area laboring in restaurants, laundries, printing shops, and meat-processing centers. 1994 Japan: The lliusion of Immigration Control. In Controlling Immigration:A Global 15. Japanese yen were valued at 107 per U.S. dollar in 1994, 93 in 1995, and 106 in Perspective. Edited by Wayne A. Cornelius,Philip L. Martin, and James F. Hol­ 1996 (Japanese Statistical Bureau 1998). The figure of 100 yen per dollar is used here lifield. Stanfonl: Stanford University Press. Pp. 375-410. for convenience. During this period the Nepalese rupee was valued at about fifty per Cross, J.P. U.S. dollar. 1985 Introduction. In Gurkhas. Sandro Tucci. London: Hamish Hamilton. Pp. 8-34. 498 IllegalImmigration in Perspective Illegal Immigration in Asia 499

Okunishi, Yoshio Soon-Beng, Chew, and Roslind Chew Japan. 12 (2): 139-162. 1995 ASEAN Economic Bulletin 1995 Immigration andForeign Labour in Singapore.ASEAN &onomic Bulletin 12 (2): Pahari, Anup 191-200. 1991 Ties That Bind: Gurkhas in History. Himal (July/August): 6-12. Spaan, Ernst Park, Young-bum 1994 Taikong's and Calo's: The Role of Middlemen and Brokers in Javanese Inter- 1994 The Turning Point in International LaborMigration and EconomicDevelopment national Migration. International Migration Review 28 (1): 93-113. in Korea.Asian and Pacific Migration Journal 3 (1): 149-174. Spotlight 1995 Korea 12 (2): 163-174. ASEAN Economic Bulletin 1996 Unemployment: Time-BombIs Ticking. Spotlight (January 5): 16-20. 1998 The Republic of Korea: Trends and Recent Developments in International Mi­ Stahl, Charles W., and ReginaldT. Appleyard gration. In OECD Pro­ Migration and Regional Economic Integration in Asia. 1992 International Manpower Flows in Asia: An Overview. Asian and Pacific Migra- ceedings. Paris: OECD. Pp. 121-132. tion Journal 1 (3--4): 417--476. Pignede, Bernard Stem, Aaron 1966 The Gurungs: A Himalayan Population ofNepal. First English edition in 1993; 1996 Thailand's illegal Labor Migrants.Asian Migrant 9 (4): 100-103. translated by Sarah Harrison,and Alan Macfarlane. Kathmandu: Ratna Pustak Sullivan, Gerald, S. Gunasekaran, and Siengthai Sununta Bhandar. 1992 Labour Migration and Policy Formation in a Newly Industrialized Countty: A Pillai. Patrick Case of illegal Thai Workers in Singapore. ASEAN Economic Bulletin 9 (1): � 1995 Malaysia.ASEAN Economic Bulletin 12 (2): 221-236. 84. Pillai, Patrick, andZainal AznamYusof Sussangk.aro, Chalongphob Trends !!!ld Recent Developments in International Migration. In !9Q8 Malaysia: Mi­ 1995 LaborMarket Adjustments and Migration in Thailand.ASEAN &onomic Bulletin gration and Regional Economic Integration in Asia. OECD Proceedings. Paris: 12 (2): 237-254. OECD. Pp. 133-143. Tsay, Ching-lung Piquero-Ballescas, Ma. Rosario gra 1992 Clandestine LabourMi tionto Taiwan. Asian and Pacific Migration Journal 1 1992 Filipino Entertainers in Japan: An Introduction. Quezon City: Foundation for (3--4): 637-655. NationalistStudies. 1995 Taiwan. ASEAN Economic Bulletin 12 (2): 175-190. Population Reference Bureau UN (United Nations) 1997 World Population Sheet. Washington, D.C.: Population ReferenceBureau. 1997 Statistical Yearbookfor Asia and the Pacific I996. Bangkok: Economicand So- Portes, Alejandro cialCommission for Asia and the Pacific. 1978 Migration and Underdevelopment. Politics and Society 8 (1): 1--48. UNIDO (United Nations Industrial DevelopmentOrganization) Portes, Alejandro, and Borocz, J6zsef 1997 Iruiustrial Development: Global Report 1997. Oxford: Oxford University Press� 1989 Contemporary Immigration: Theoretical Perspectives on Its Determinants and Vasuprasat, Pracha Modes of Incorporation. International Migration Review 23 (3): 606-630. 1994 TurningPomts in International LaborMigration: A Case Studyof Thailand.Asian Sassen, Saskia and Pacific Migration Journal 3 (1): 175-202. 1988 The Mobility ofLabou r and Capital. London: CambridgeUnivers ity Press. Watanabe, Susu.mu Schaeffer, Robert K. 1994 The Lewisian Turning Point and International Migration: The Case of Japan. 1997 Understanding Globalization: The Social Consequences of Political, Economic, Asian and Pacific Migration Journal 3 (1): 119-147. and Environmental Change. Lanham, Maryland: Rowman and Littlefield. Wong, Diana Shah, Nasra M. 1997 Transience and Settlement Singapore'S'Foreign Labor Policy.Asian andPacific 1994 An Overview of Present and Future Emigration Dynamics in South Asia. Inter­ Migration Journal 6 (2): 135-167. national Migration 32 (2): 217-268. World Bank Shah, Nasra M., Sulayman S. Al-Qudsi, and Makhdoom A. Shah 1993 The EastAsian Miracle: Economic Growth andPub licPolicy. New York: Oxford 1991 Asian Women Workers in Kuwait International Migration Review 25 (3): 464- University Press. 486. Yamanaka,· Keiko Skeldon, Ronald 1996 Return Migration of Japanese-Brazilians to Japan: The Nikkeijin as Ethnic Mi­ 1992 International Migration within and fromthe East and Southeast AsianRegion: A nority and Political Construct Diaspora 5 ( 1): 65-S)7. Review Essay. Asian and Pacific Migration Journal 1 (1): 19-63. 1998 Nepalese Labor Migration to Japan: From Global Warriors to Global Workers. 1994 Turning Pointsin Labour Migration: TheCase of Hong Kong. Asian andPacific Paper presented at the 1998 Annual Meeting of the Pacific Sociological Associ­ Migration Journal 3 (1):93-118. ation, San Francisco, April 16-19. 1995 MigrationLabour to Hong Kong. ASEAN Economic Bulletin 12 (2): 201-218.