Nrr196-05 Economies of Scale and Vertical Integration In
Total Page:16
File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb
Load more
Recommended publications
-
Economics of Competition in the U.S. Livestock Industry Clement E. Ward
Economics of Competition in the U.S. Livestock Industry Clement E. Ward, Professor Emeritus Department of Agricultural Economics Oklahoma State University January 2010 Paper Background and Objectives Questions of market structure changes, their causes, and impacts for pricing and competition have been focus areas for the author over his entire 35-year career (1974-2009). Pricing and competition are highly emotional issues to many and focusing on factual, objective economic analyses is critical. This paper is the author’s contribution to that effort. The objectives of this paper are to: (1) put meatpacking competition issues in historical perspective, (2) highlight market structure changes in meatpacking, (3) note some key lawsuits and court rulings that contribute to the historical perspective and regulatory environment, and (4) summarize the body of research related to concentration and competition issues. These were the same objectives I stated in a presentation made at a conference in December 2009, The Economics of Structural Change and Competition in the Food System, sponsored by the Farm Foundation and other professional agricultural economics organizations. The basis for my conference presentation and this paper is an article I published, “A Review of Causes for and Consequences of Economic Concentration in the U.S. Meatpacking Industry,” in an online journal, Current Agriculture, Food & Resource Issues in 2002, http://caes.usask.ca/cafri/search/archive/2002-ward3-1.pdf. This paper is an updated, modified version of the review article though the author cannot claim it is an exhaustive, comprehensive review of the relevant literature. Issue Background Nearly 20 years ago, the author ran across a statement which provides a perspective for the issues of concentration, consolidation, pricing, and competition in meatpacking. -
Urban Concentration: the Role of Increasing Returns and Transport Costs
i'445o Urban Concentration: The Role of Increasing Retums and Transport Costs Public Disclosure Authorized Paul Krugman Very largeurban centersare a conspicuousfeature of many developingeconomies, yet the subject of the size distribution of cities (as opposed to such issuesas rural-urban migration) has been neglected by development economists. This article argues that some important insights into urban concentration, especially the tendency of some developing countris to have very large primate cdties, can be derived from recent approachesto economic geography.Three approachesare comparedrthe well-estab- Public Disclosure Authorized lished neoclassica urban systems theory, which emphasizes the tradeoff between agglomerationeconomies and diseconomies of city size; the new economic geogra- phy, which attempts to derive agglomeration effects from the interactions among market size, transportation costs, and increasingreturns at the firm level; and a nihilistic view that cities emerge owt of a randon processin which there are roughly constant returns to city size. The arttcle suggeststhat Washingtonconsensus policies of reducedgovernment intervention and trade opening may tend to reducethe size of primate cties or at least slow their relativegrowth. Over the past severalyears there has been a broad revivalof interestin issues Public Disclosure Authorized of regional and urban development. This revivalhas taken two main direc- dions. T'he first has focused on theoretical models of urbanization and uneven regional growth, many of them grounded in the approaches to imperfect competition and increasing returns originally developed in the "new trade" and anew growth" theories. The second, a new wave of empirical work, explores urban and regional growth patterns for clues to the nature of external economies, macro- economic adjustment, and other aspects of the aggregate economy. -
Analyzing Cost Efficient Production Behavior Under Economies of Scope: a Nonparametric Methodology
A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Cherchye, Laurens; de Rock, Bram; Vermeulen, Frederic Working Paper Analyzing cost efficient production behavior under economies of scope: a nonparametric methodology IZA Discussion Papers, No. 2319 Provided in Cooperation with: IZA – Institute of Labor Economics Suggested Citation: Cherchye, Laurens; de Rock, Bram; Vermeulen, Frederic (2006) : Analyzing cost efficient production behavior under economies of scope: a nonparametric methodology, IZA Discussion Papers, No. 2319, Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA), Bonn This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/34010 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten -
Resource Issues a Journal of the Canadian Agricultural Economics Society
Number 3/2002/p.1-28 www.CAFRI.org Agriculture, Food ß Current & Resource Issues A Journal of the Canadian Agricultural Economics Society A Review of Causes for and Consequences of Economic Concentration in the U.S. Meatpacking Industry Clement E. Ward Professor and Extension Economist, Oklahoma State University This paper was prepared for presentation at the conference The Economics of Concentration in the Agri-Food Sector, sponsored by the Canadian Agricultural Economics Society, Toronto, Ontario, April 27-28, 2001 The Issue This squall between the packers and the producers of this country ought to have blown over forty years ago, but we still have it on our hands .... Senator John B. Kendrick of Wyoming, 1919 lear and continuing changes in the structure of the U.S. meatpacking industry have Csignificantly increased economic concentration since the mid-1970s. Concentration levels are among the highest of any industry in the United States, and well above levels generally considered to elicit non-competitive behavior and result in adverse economic performance, thereby triggering antitrust investigations and subsequent regulatory actions. Many agricultural economists and others deem this development paradoxical. While several civil antitrust lawsuits have been filed against the largest meatpacking firms, there have been no major antitrust decisions against those firms and there have been no significant federal government antitrust cases brought against the largest meatpacking firms over the period coincident with the period of major structural changes. The structural changes in the U.S. meatpacking industry raise a number of questions. What is the nature of the changes and what economic factors caused them? What evidence is ß 1 Current Agriculture, Food & Resource Issues C. -
TRANSACTION COST LIMITS to ECONOMIES of SCALE Cotton M
DO RATE AND VOLUME MATTER? TRANSACTION COST LIMITS TO ECONOMIES OF SCALE Cotton M. Lindsay & Michael T. Maloney Department of Economics Clemson University In the traditional treatment, economies of scale are attributed to a hodgepodge of sources. A typical list might include Adam Smith's famous "division of labour," economies of large machines, the integration of processes, massed reserves, and standardization. The list can be partly systematized because, when considered in detail, these various economies are themselves the result of various other more basic and occasionally overlapping principles. For example, both economies of massed reserves and economies of standardi- zation are to a certain extent the product of the statistical “law of large numbers.” However, even this analysis fails to strike to the heart of the matter because the technological factors however described that reduce costs with scale do not in themselves imply that large firms can produce at lower cost than small firms. The possible presence of such technological scale economies does not give us adequate knowledge to predict the structure of industry. These forces of nature may combine to make it cheaper to get things done in big chunks. However, this potential will be economically important only in the presence of transactions costs. Firms can specialize their production processes and hire out the jobs that require large scale. Realistically all firms hire out some portion of the production process regard- less of their size. General Motors ships many of its automobiles by rail, but does not own a railroad for this purpose. Anaconda uses a great deal of fuel oil in its production of copper, but it does not own oil wells or refineries. -
Scope Economies: Fixed Costs, Cgmplementarity, and Functional Form
Working Paper Series This paper can be downloaded without charge from: http://www.richmondfed.org/publications/ Working Paper 91-3 Scope Economies: Fixed Costs, Cgmplementarity, and Functional Form Lawrence B. Pulley** and David B. Humphrey*** February, 1991 This is a preprint of an article published in the Journal of Business Ó, July 1993, v. 66, iss.3, pp. 437-62 *The opinions expressed are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond or the Federal Reserve System. The authors thank John Boschen for his comments on an earlier version of this paper. Support for Lawrence Pulley was received from the Summer Research Grant Program at the College of William and Mary. *School of Business Administration, College of William and Mary, Williamsburg, Virginia, 23187. ***FederalReserve Bank of Richmond, Richmond, Virginia, 23261. Abstract. Bank scope economies have been derived from either the standard or generalized (Box-Cox) multiproduct translog (or other logarithmic) functional form. Reported results have ranged from strong economies to diseconomies and are far from conclusive. The problem is functional form. An alternative composite form is shown to yield stable SCOPE results both at the usual point of evaluation and for points associated with quasi-specialized production (QSCOPE). Unstable results are obtained for the other forms. Scope economies are shown to exist for large U.S. banks in 1988 and to depend on the number of banking outputs specified. The scope estimates are also separated into their two sources--fixed-cost and cost-complementarity effects. Scope Economies: Fixed Costs, Complementarity, and Functional Form 1. -
The Role of Industrial and Post-Industrial Cities in Economic Development
Joint Center for Housing Studies Harvard University The Role of Industrial and Post-Industrial Cities in Economic Development John R. Meyer W00-1 April 2000 John R. Meyer is James W. Harpel Professor of Capital Formation and Economic Growth, Emeritus and chairman of the faculty committee of the Joint Center for Housing Studies. by John R. Meyer. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including notice, is given to the source. Draft paper prepared for the World Bank Urban Development Division's research project entitled "Revisiting Development - Urban Perspectives." Any opinions expressed are those of the author and not those of the Joint Center for Housing Studies of Harvard University or of any of the persons or organizations providing support to the Joint Center for Housing Studies, nor of the World Bank Urban Development Division. The Role of Industrial and Post-Industrial Cities in Economic Development by John R. Meyer Once upon a time the location of towns and cities, at least superficially, seemed to be largely determined by the preferences of kings, princes, bishops, generals and other political and military leaders of society. A site’s defensibility or its capabilities for imposing military or administrative control over surrounding countryside were often of paramount importance. As one historian summed up the conventional wisdom: “Cities...were to be found...wherever agriculture produced sufficient surplus to sustain a population of rulers, soldiers, craftsmen and other nonfood producers.”1 The key to successful urbanization, in short, wasn’t so much what the city could do for the countryside as what the countryside could do for the city.2 This traditional view of early cities, while perhaps correct in its essentials, is also almost surely too limited.3 Cities were never just parasitic; most have always added at least some economic value. -
Estimating Economies of Scale and Scope with Flexible Technology
Ifo Institute – Leibniz Institute for Economic Research at the University of Munich Estimating Economies of Scale and Scope with Flexible Technology Thomas P. Triebs David S. Saal Pablo Arocena Subal C. Kumbhakar Ifo Working Paper No. 142 October 2012 An electronic version of the paper may be downloaded from the Ifo website www.cesifo-group.de. Ifo Working Paper No. 142 Estimating Economies of Scale and Scope with Flexible Technology Abstract Economies of scale and scope are typically modelled and estimated using cost functions that are common to all firms in an industry irrespective of whether they specialize in a single output or produce multiple outputs. We suggest an alternative flexible technology model that does not make this assumption and show how it can be estimated using standard parametric functions including the translog. The assumption of common technology is a special case of our model and is testable econometrically. Our application is for publicly owned US electric utilities. In our sample, we find evidence of economies of scale and vertical economies of scope. But the results do not support a common technology for integrated and specialized firms. In particular, our empirical results suggest that restricting the technology might result in biased estimates of economies of scale and scope. JEL Code: D24, L25, L94, C51. Keywords: Economies of scale and scope, flexible technology, electric utilities, vertical integration, translog cost function. Thomas P. Triebs David S. Saal Ifo Institute – Leibniz Institute for Aston University Economic Research Aston Triangle at the University of Munich B$ 7ET Poschingerstr. 5 Birminghamton, UK 81679 Munich, Germany Phone: +44(0)121/204-3220 Phone: +49(0)89/9224-1258 [email protected] [email protected] Pablo Arocena Subal C. -
Cost Concepts the Cost Function
(Largely) Review: Cost concepts The Cost Function • Cost function C(q): minimum cost of producing a given quantity q • C(q) = F + V C(q), where { Fixed costs F : cost incurred regardless of output amount. Avoidable vs. sunk: crucial for determining shut-down decisions for the firm. { Variable costs V C(q); vary with the amount produced. C(q) { Average cost AC(q) = q @C(q) { Marginal cost MC(q) = @q V C(q) F { AV C(q) = q ; AF C(q) = q ; AC(q) = AV C(q) + AF C(q). Example • C(q) = 125 + 5q + 5q2 • AC(q) = • MC(q) = • AF C(q) = 125=q • AV C(q) = 5 + 5q q AC(q) MC(q) 1 135 15 • 3 61.67 35 5 55 55 7 57.86 75 9 63.89 95 • AC rises if MC exceeds it, and falls if MC is below it. Implies that MC intersects AC at the minimum of AC. Short-run vs. long-run costs: • Short run: production technology given • Long run: can adapt production technology to market conditions • Long-run AC curve cannot exceed short-run AC curve: its the lower envelope Example: \The division of labor is limited by the extent of the market" (Adam Smith) • Division of labor requires high fixed costs (for example, assembly line requires high setup costs). • Firm adopts division of labor only when scale of production (market demand) is high enough. • Graph: Price-taking firm has \choice" between two production technologies. Opportunity cost The opportunity cost of a product is the value of the best forgone alternative use of the resources employed in making it. -
Report No. 2020-06 Economies of Scale in Community Banks
Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation Staff Studies Report No. 2020-06 Economies of Scale in Community Banks December 2020 Staff Studies Staff www.fdic.gov/cfr • @FDICgov • #FDICCFR • #FDICResearch Economies of Scale in Community Banks Stefan Jacewitz, Troy Kravitz, and George Shoukry December 2020 Abstract: Using financial and supervisory data from the past 20 years, we show that scale economies in community banks with less than $10 billion in assets emerged during the run-up to the 2008 financial crisis due to declines in interest expenses and provisions for losses on loans and leases at larger banks. The financial crisis temporarily interrupted this trend and costs increased industry-wide, but a generally more cost-efficient industry re-emerged, returning in recent years to pre-crisis trends. We estimate that from 2000 to 2019, the cost-minimizing size of a bank’s loan portfolio rose from approximately $350 million to $3.3 billion. Though descriptive, our results suggest efficiency gains accrue early as a bank grows from $10 million in loans to $3.3 billion, with 90 percent of the potential efficiency gains occurring by $300 million. JEL classification: G21, G28, L00. The views expressed are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the official positions of the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation or the United States. FDIC Staff Studies can be cited without additional permission. The authors wish to thank Noam Weintraub for research assistance and seminar participants for helpful comments. Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, [email protected], 550 17th St. NW, Washington, DC 20429 Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, [email protected], 550 17th St. -
Assessing the Role of Scale Economies and Imperfect Competition in the Context of Agricultural Trade Liberalisation: a Canadian Case Study
ASSESSING THE ROLE OF SCALE ECONOMIES AND IMPERFECT COMPETITION IN THE CONTEXT OF AGRICULTURAL TRADE LIBERALISATION: A CANADIAN CASE STUDY Franqois Delorme and Dominique van der Mensbrugghe CONTENTS Introduction .............................................. 206 I. The implementation of scale economies in WALRAS ............ 207 A. Scale-economy parameters ............................ 209 B. Pricing strategies ................................... 21 1 II. Empirical results ....................................... 218 A. Perfect competition ................................. 220 B. Scale economies and oligopolistic behaviour ............... 222 111. Concluding remarks.. ................................... 225 Technical Annex ........................................... 230 Bibliography .............................................. 233 FranCois Delorme is an Administrator with the Growth Studies Division and Dominique van der Mensbrugghe was a Trainee with the Growth Studies Division. The authors are grateful to John P. Martin, Val Koromzay and Peter Sturm for many perceptive suggestions and substantial comments on an earlier draft. They are also indebted to Kym Anderson, Jean-Marc Burniaux, Avinash Dixit, Robert Ford, Richard Harris, lan Lienert, James Markusen, Victor Norman, J. David Richardson, Benoit Robidoux, Jeff Shafer and Anthony J. Venables for valuable discussions and comments during the course of this work. 205 INTRODUCTION One of the key characteristics of the WALRAS model [as described in Burniaux et a/. (1989)l is that it assumes that all markets are perfectly competi- tive and production takes place under constant returns to scale. In this case, supply curves are flat', although they shift as input prices change. Until recently, this modelling strategy was adopted by most applied general equilibrium (AGE) modellers, since such models are relatively easy to build and their properties are well understood. Simulations of trade liberalisation with such models tend to show rather "small" welfare gains, typically of the order of 1 per cent of GNP or less. -
Excess Capacity.Pdf
A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Todorova, Tamara Preprint Is There Excess Capacity Really? Theoretical and Practical Research in Economic Fields Suggested Citation: Todorova, Tamara (2015) : Is There Excess Capacity Really?, Theoretical and Practical Research in Economic Fields, ISSN 2068–7710, ASERS Publishing, s.l., Vol. 6, Iss. 2 (12) (Winter), pp. 127-143 This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/157217 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu Is There Excess Capacity Really? Tamara Todorova American University in Bulgaria Excess capacity is viewed as a distinctive feature and an essential inefficiency of monopolistic competition as the large-group case of imperfect competition.